Skip to main content

Religiosity and Economic Performance: The Role of Personal Liberties

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Advances in the Economics of Religion

Part of the book series: International Economic Association Series ((IEA))

Abstract

What is the effect of religion on economic outcomes? Religion is a complex social phenomenon affecting individual choice and behavior through numerous channels. This contribution summarizes some of these effects. We focus on the causality direction from religiosity to economic performance, therefore skipping the potential influence that the economic environment and personal realizations can have on religious beliefs.

Laura Mayoral and Joan Esteban gratefully acknowledge the financial support from the Spanish Ministry of Economy and Competitiveness Grant, through the Severo Ochoa Programme for Centres of Excellence in R&D (SEV-2015-0563) and grant number ECO2015-66883-P, Generalitat de Catalunya project number 2017SGR1359, and the National Science Foundation Grant SES-1629370.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 39.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 49.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 159.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    This direction of causality has been the focus of numerous theories. Of particular relevance is the secularization hypothesis that states that economic growth decreases religious beliefs and participation in religious services and reduces the influence of religious institutions on politics and governance. Marx (1843, 1976) viewed religion as resulting from poverty, the opiate of the have-nots. Solt et al. (2011) have obtained empirical evidence supporting Marx’s view: inequality breeds religiosity.

  2. 2.

    This hypothesis has been examined in numerous papers (see Grier 1997, Ekelund et al. 2006, and Delacroix and Nielsen 2001) obtaining mixed results. More recently, Cantoni (2015) has used a “natural experiment”—the forced imposition of religious denominations as a consequence of the Peace of Augsburg (1555)—to investigate the differences in growth patterns across the Protestant and Catholic parts of the Holy Roman Empire, finding no positive effect of Protestantism on economic growth over the very long run (1300–1900).

  3. 3.

    The findings by Barro and McCleary are based on cross-country regressions and they are subject to numerous criticisms. See Durlauf et al. (2012) for a critique.

  4. 4.

    The mechanism explored in the literature is typically based on the assumption that religious individuals value relatively more religious than economic activities. This takes different specifications. Iannaccone (1992) initiated a stream of papers in which this lower relative valuation of material benefits is introduced by assuming that the utility from consumption of material goods is subject to some sort of “psychological tax”. This makes individuals to devote more time and effort to religious activities. A complementary explanation, also due to Iannaccone (1992, 1998), follows from the view of religious practice as a problem of demand for a “club good”. In this case, members of a religious club experience an externality because their individual enjoyment depends on the intensity of commitment of the other members. Hence, it may be in the interest of the club members to impose highly restrictive rules of behavior in order to leave out the individuals with lower levels of religiosity. These restrictions would be geared toward making more attractive the allocation of time to religious activities, at the expense of productive activities. Besides Iannaccone, Berman (2000) and Carvalho and Koyama (2016), among others, also argue that religions strategically induce individuals to participate in costly rituals and hence reduce their material productivity.

  5. 5.

    The partial lifting of the legal caps often finds an active opposition of religious and conservative groups. In many countries religious organizations advocate the tightening of laws regulating such personal liberties. In some cases violence is being used toward those that exercise such liberties, as, for example, in what is now defined as “anti-abortion terrorism”. See the statistics for the US gathered by the National Abortion Federation (NAF).

  6. 6.

    The analysis is robust to the externality arising instead from the actual practice of wider liberties by some individuals in society. It is also robust to considering different values for religious and secular individuals.

  7. 7.

    ELMa assume the standard properties on u(⋅, ⋅, ⋅): the utility increases in all arguments, satisfies concavity with respect to each argument, and has non-negative cross derivatives.

  8. 8.

    If the opposite holds, then the implications are reversed.

  9. 9.

    Data from rounds 2002, 2004, 2006, 2008, 2010, and 2012 are employed for all countries available (at most 34, including Turkey and Israel).

  10. 10.

    Notice, however, that hoursworked is an imperfect measure of the willingness to work, as it reflects attitudes toward effort as well as the characteristics of the environment (i.e., rigidity of the labor market). To address this issue, ELMa also consider a variable that reports the number of hours that the respondent would like to work (desiredhours ).

  11. 11.

    Religious intensity is computed as the average of three variables: (1) the respondent’s monthly frequency of praying, (2) the self-reported degree of religiosity, and (3) the respondent’s monthly frequency of attendance of religious services.

  12. 12.

    These additional controls are: whether the respondent lives with a partner (cohab), years of completed education (eduyrs), a subjective measure of own’s health ( health), whether there are children in the household (children), the size of the household (hhsize), and a measure of partner’s education (edu-ptnr).

  13. 13.

    We define three age brackets: from 18 to 35, from 36 to 60, and from 60 onwards. The results are robust to changes in the definition of the brackets.

  14. 14.

    We construct the instrument for the interaction term of religious intensity and liberties simply by replacing rel INT by rel \(_{\text{INT}}^{\text{IV}}\) in the product.

References

  • Barro, Robert, and Rachel McCleary. 2003. Religion and Economic Growth across Countries. American Sociological Review 68: 760–81.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker, Gary. 1996. Norms and the Formation of Preferences. In Accounting for Tastes, ed. G. Becker. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Becker, Sascha O., and Ludger Woessmann. 2009. Was Weber Wrong? A Human Capital Theory of Protestant Economic History. Quarterly Journal of Economics 124: 531–596.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bénabou, Roland, Davide Ticchi, and Andrea Vindigni. 2015a. Forbidden Fruits: The Political Economy of Science, Religion, and Growth. NBER Working Paper 21105.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2015b. Religion and Innovation. American Economic Review, P&P 105 (5): 346–351.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bénabou, Roland, and Jean Tirole. 2006. Belief in a Just World and Redistributive Politics. Quarterly Journal of Economics 12: 699–746.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2011. Identity, Morals and Taboos: Beliefs as Assets. Quarterly Journal of Economics 126: 805–855.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Berman, Eli. 2000. Sect, Subsidy and Sacrifice: An Economist’s View of Ultra-Orthodox Jews. Quarterly Journal of Economics 115: 905–953.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Botticini, Maristella, and Zvi Eckstein. 2012. The Chosen Few: How Education Shaped Jewish History, 70–1492. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Campante, Filipe, and David Yanagizawa-Drott. 2015. Does Religion Affect Economic Growth and Happiness? Evidence from Ramadan. Quarterly Journal of Economics 130: 615–658.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cantoni, Davide. 2015. The Economic Effects of Protestant Reformation: Testing the Weber Hypothesis in the German Lands. Journal of the European Economic Association 13: 561–598.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carvalho, Jean-Paul, and Mark Koyama. 2016. Development and Religious Polarisation: The Emergence of Reform and Ultra-Orthodox Judaism. Journal of Comparative Economics 44: 562–584.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ceyhun, Elgin, Turkmen Goksel, Mehmet Gurdal, and Cuneyt Orman. 2013. Religion, Income Inequality, and the Size of the Government. Economic Modelling 30: 225–234.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chen, Daniel L., and Jo Thori Lind. 2016. The Political Economy of Beliefs: Why Fiscal and Social Conservatives/Liberals (Sometimes) Come Hand-in-Hand? TSE Working Paper, n. 16–722.

    Google Scholar 

  • Clark, A., and O. Lelkes. 2005. Deliver Us From Evil: Religion as Insurance. Paris: Mimeo, DELTA.

    Google Scholar 

  • Darnell, Alfred, and Darren E. Sherkat. 1997. The Impact of Protestant Fundamentalism on Educational Attainment. American Sociological Review 62: 306–316.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Delacroix, J., and F. Nielsen. 2001. The Beloved Myth: Protestantism and the Rise of Industrial Capitalism in Nineteenth-Century Europe. Social Forces 80: 509–553.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Durlauf, S., A. Kourtellos, and C.M. Tan. 2012. Is God in the Details? A Reexamination of the Role of Religion in Economic Growth. Journal of Applied Econometrics 27: 1059–1075.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ekelund, R.B.Jr., R.F. Hébert, and R.D. Tollison. 2006. The Market for Christianity. Cambridge: MIT Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Esteban, Joan, Gilat Levy, and Laura Mayoral. 2018a. Personal Liberties, Religiosity, and Effort. Unpublished Working Paper.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2018b. Liberté, Égalité, et … Religiosité. Journal of Public Economics 164: 241–253.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gill, Anthony, and Erik Lundsgaarde. 2004. State Welfare Spending and Religiosity. A Cross-National Analysis. Rationality and Society 16: 399–436.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grier, Robin. 1997. The Effect of Religion on Economic Development: A Cross National Study of 63 Former Colonies. Kyklos 50: 47–62.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Guiso, Luigi, Paola Sapienza, and Luigi Zingales. 2003. People’s Opium? Religion and Economic Attitudes. Journal of Monetary Economics 50: 225–282.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2006. Does Culture Affect Economic Outcomes? Journal of Economic Perspectives 20: 23–48.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hitchcock, William, Akira Iriye, and Petra Goedde. 2012. The Human Rights Revolution: An International History. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Huber, John, and Piero Stanig. 2009. Individual Income and Voting for Redistribution Across Democracies. Unpublished Working Paper.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2011. Church-State Separation and Redistribution. Journal of Public Economics 95: 828–836.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Iannaccone, Laurence R. 1992. Sacrifice and Stigma: Reducing Free-Riding in Cults, Communes and Other Collectives. Journal of Political Economy 100: 271–291.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • ———. 1998. Introduction to the Economics of Religion. Journal of Economic Literature 36: 1465–1496.

    Google Scholar 

  • Levy, Gilat, and Ronny Razin. 2012. Religious Beliefs, Religious Participation and Cooperation. American Economic Journals: Micoreconomics 4: 121–151.

    Google Scholar 

  • Marx, Karl. 1843, 1976. Introduction to A Contribution to the Critique of Hegel’s Philosophy of Right, vol. 3. Collected Works. New York.

    Google Scholar 

  • McCleary, Rachel M., and Robert J. Barro. 2006. Religion and Economy. Journal of Economic Perspectives 20: 49–72.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nunn, Nathan. 2010. Religious Conversion in Colonial Africa. American Economic Review 100: 147–152.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2014. Gender and Missionary Influence in Colonial Africa. In Africa’s Development in Historical Perspective, ed. E. Akyeampong , R. Bates , N. Nunn, J.A. Robinson, 489–512. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Roemer, John E. 1998. Why the Poor Do Not Expropriate the Rich: An Old Argument in New Garb. Journal of Public Economics 70: 399–424.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Scheve, Keneth, and David Stasavage. 2006. The Political Economy of Religion and Social Insurance in the United States, 1910–1939. Studies in American Political Development 20: 132–159.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sherkat, D.E., and A. Darnell. 1999. The Effects of Parents’ Fundamentalism on Children’s Educational Attainment. Journal for the Scientific Study of Religion 38: 23–35.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Solt, Frederick, Philip Habel, and J. Tobin Grant. 2011. Economic Inequality, Relative Power, and Religiosity. Social Science Quarterly 92: 447–465.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Valencia Caicedo, Felipe. 2018. The Mission: Human Capital Transmission, Economic Persistence, and Culture in South America. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, qjy024. https://doi.org/10.1093/qje/qjy024.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weber, Max. 1904. The Protestant Ethic and the Spirit of Capitalism. New York: Scribners.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Joan Esteban .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2019 The Author(s)

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Mayoral, L., Esteban, J. (2019). Religiosity and Economic Performance: The Role of Personal Liberties. In: Carvalho, JP., Iyer, S., Rubin, J. (eds) Advances in the Economics of Religion. International Economic Association Series. Palgrave Macmillan, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-98848-1_25

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-98848-1_25

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Palgrave Macmillan, Cham

  • Print ISBN: 978-3-319-99336-2

  • Online ISBN: 978-3-319-98848-1

  • eBook Packages: Economics and FinanceEconomics and Finance (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics