Skip to main content

Let’s Play: Bribery Games in the US and Germany

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Corruption and Norms

Part of the book series: Political Corruption and Governance ((PCG))

  • 965 Accesses

Abstract

This chapter focuses on behavioral differences across cultures in an experimental bribery game that contributes to cross-country comparisons. To answer the question, what affects an individual’s propensity to engage in and punish corrupt actions?, bribery games have been run with over 700 students, comparing individual decision-making in the US and Germany. Contrary to the assumptions, almost 70% of the Californian participants offered and accepted a bribe. In Germany, almost 50% took the opportunity to offer a bribe and 40% accepted one. In the US, 52% of the participants punished corrupt acts, compared to 80% in Germany. The results can be explained by differences in the level of individualism and by “a cultural transmission of corruption”. This explanation should also imply a society’s ability to build anti-corruption norms.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    This situation describes one form of corruption. There are also individual forms of corruption where a power holder individually abuses power (e.g. see Azfar and Nelson 2007; Abbink and Ellman 2005; Barr et al. 2009).

  2. 2.

    In this chapter, I consider punishment as an endogenous factor that takes place if the victim decides to incur the cost associated with punishment. Thus, I am able to examine both the incentives to engage in corruption and the incentives to punish corrupt behavior (Cameron et al. 2009).

  3. 3.

    Moreover, in contrast to our study, Banuri and Eckel’s experiment is more focused on the mechanisms of punishment and is designed as a repetition game.

  4. 4.

    Furthermore, there are subnational variations of corruption measures in both countries. For instance, in the US, New York is very infamous for its corrupt government culture as is the city of Chicago and many other states (see the Center for Advancement of Public Integrity at Columbia Law School).

  5. 5.

    Formal institutions are particularly considered by new institutional approaches that are often used by sociologists to analyze corruption by stressing the role of institutions actors operate in. Thus, it is assumed that the relationship between institutions and actors are reciprocal and cyclical (Groenendijk 1997).

  6. 6.

    The other dimensions include: (1) Power distance; (2) Uncertainty avoidance; (3) Masculinity vs. femininity; (4) Long-term vs. short-term orientation and (5) Indulgence vs. restraint.

  7. 7.

    For instance, the firms can select between the following answers if they have bribed: “payoff maximization”, “for the social/economic good of the country (e.g. reduce unemployment etc.)”, “to see the response of the official/citizen” or “other reasons”. If they have not bribed they can choose between “morality”, “to reduce corruption (social cost)”, “profit-maximization (in the long run it is bad for the firm)”, it is “not necessary for firms to bribe”, “equity” or “other reasons”.

    If the officials have accepted the bribe they can decide between the options “necessary for firms to bribe/will be able to help the firm”, “necessary because salaries are low”, “payoff maximization”, “equity”, “game will continue” or “other reasons”. If they have not accepted the bribe they can select between the reasons “morality”, “to reduce corruption (social cost)”, “scared of implications/risk”, “payoff maximization”, “fairness”, “bribe too small” or “other reasons”.

  8. 8.

    If the citizens punish the bribery, they have the opportunity to choose between the following response options: “morality”, “reduce corruption”, “fairness”, “negative reciprocity” or “other reasons”. If the citizen has not punished the other actors, he or she can select an answer between “payoff maximization”, “difficult to change the system”, “ineffective punishment system”, “bribe may be for a good purpose or may be necessary” or “other reasons”.

  9. 9.

    I have not included an individual’s age because of missing variance in the data.

  10. 10.

    Work experience includes any type of job and any period of time.

  11. 11.

    For this question, I have five dimensions (personally in your workplace, personally at university, via friends/family, via mass media, no contact). I also ask them to provide us relevant examples.

  12. 12.

    I define bribery as an activity that involves a payment in money, services or other valuables to make things pass smoothly, swiftly or more favorable through private, public or government bureaucracies. It describes a behavioral exchange that involves a person that seeks a public service and a person that delivers a public service.

  13. 13.

    Abbink (2002) makes a similar assumption in his study. As in his paper, this multiplier also has the additional advantage of helping us prevent negative total payoffs.

  14. 14.

    Cooper and Kagel (2003) consider the role of loaded language in signaling games and suggest that the use of a meaningful context might better capture behavior in field settings than the use of neutral language. However, Abbink and Hennig-Schmidt (2006) suggest that neutrally framed experiment s are not necessarily less interpretable in terms of a real-life situation than those presented in a context. They find that the use of words like “bribe” do not make a difference in corruption games they have conducted.

  15. 15.

    Comparing my results with the findings of Banuri and Eckel (2011), at the University of Texas, where bribes were sent in 60 percent of decisions in the no-punishment treatment and 42 percent of decisions with punishment, we can show that the propensity to engage in corrupt actions is even higher in California with the punishment treatment.

  16. 16.

    An alternative way of designing a more effective punishment system would be to increase the multiplier on the punishment level chosen by the citizen. However, I chose to increase the punishment options available to the citizens since I am also interested in examining “choice set” effects.

References

  • Abbink, Klaus. 2002. An Experimental Bribery Game. Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization 18 (2): 428–454.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Abbink, Klaus, and Matthew Ellman. 2005. The Donor Problem. 15. CeDEx Discussion Paper, Nottingham, UK.

    Google Scholar 

  • Abbink, Klaus, and Heike Hennig-Schmidt. 2006. Neutral versus Loaded Instructions in a Bribery Experiment. Experimental Economics 9 (2): 103–121.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alatas, Vivi, Lisa Cameron, Ananish Chaudhuri, Nisvan Erkal, and Lata Gangadharan. 2009. Gender and Corruption: Insights from an Experimental Analysis. Southern Economic Journal 75 (3): 663–680.

    Google Scholar 

  • Andvig, Jens Chr, and Karl Ove Moene. 1990. How Corruption May Corrupt. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization 13 (1): 63–76.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Armantier, Olivier, and Amdaou Boly. 2008. Can Corruption Be Studied in the Lab? Comparing a Field and a Lab Experiment. CIRANO Scientific Series Working Paper 100 (4): CIRANO, Montreal.

    Google Scholar 

  • Azfar, Omar, and William Robert Nelson. 2007. Transparency, Wages, and the Separation of Powers: An Experimental Analysis of Corruption. Public Choice 130 (1): 471–493.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Banerjee, Ritwik. 2016. On the Interpretation of Bribery in a Laboratory Corruption Game: Moral Frames and Social Norms. Experimental Economics 19 (1): 240–267.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Banuri, Sheherya, and Catherine Eckel. 2011. The Effects of Sanctions on Bribery: US versus Pakistan. http://siteresources.worldbank.org/INTMACRO/Resources/BanuriBriberyWBJan2011.pdf. Accessed 18 June 2017.

  • Banuri, Sheheryar, and Catherine Eckel. 2012. Chapter 3: Experiments in Culture and Corruption: A Review. In New Advances in Experimental Research on Corruption (Research in Experimental Economics, Volume 15), ed. Danila Serra and Leonard Wantchekon, 51–76. Bingley: Emerald Group.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Barr, Abigail, and Danila Serra. 2010. Corruption and Culture: An Experimental Analysis. Journal of Public Economics 94 (11–12): 862–869.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barr, Abigail, Magnus Lindelow, and Pieter Serneels. 2009. Corruption in Public Service Delivery: An Experimental Analysis. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization 72 (October): 225–239.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bersoff, David M. 1999. Why Good People Sometimes Do Bad Things: Motivated Reasoning and Unethical Behavior. Personality and Social Psychology Bulletin 25 (1): 28–39.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bertrand, Marianne, Simeon Djankov, Rema Hanna, and Sendhil Mullainathan. 2007. Obtaining a Driver’s License in India: An Experimental Approach to Studying Corruption. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 122 (4): 1639–1676.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bolton, Gary E., and Axel Ockenfels. 2000. ERC: A Theory of Equity, Reciprocity, and Competition. The American Economic Review 90 (1): 166–193.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bowles, Samuel, and Herbert Gintis. 2004. The Evolution of Strong Reciprocity: Cooperation in Heterogeneous Populations. Theoretical Population Biology 65 (1): 17–28.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brunetti, Aymo, and Beatrice Weder. 2003. A Free Press Is Bad News for Corruption. Journal of Public Economics 87 (7–8): 1801–1824.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cameron, Lisa, Ananish Chaudhuri, Nisvan Erkal, and Lata Gangadharan. 2009. Propensities to Engage in and Punish Corrupt Behavior: Experimental Evidence from Australia, India, Indonesia and Singapore. Journal of Public Economics 93 (7–8): 843–851.

    Google Scholar 

  • Carpenter, Jeffrey, and Erika Seki. 2011. Do social preferences increase productivity? Field experimental evidence from Fishermen in Toyama Bay. Economic Inquiry 49 (2): 612–630.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cooper, David J., and John H. Kagel. 2003. The Impact of Meaningful Context on Strategic Play in Signaling Games. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization 50 (3): 311–337.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Corruption Perceptions Index. 2017. https://www.transparency.org/research/cpi/overview. Accessed 20 June 2017.

  • Croson, Rachel, and Uri Gneezy. 2009. Gender Differences in Preferences. Journal of Economic Literature 47 (2): 448–474.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dreher, Axel, Christos Kotsogiannis, and Steve McCorriston. 2007. Corruption Around the World: Evidence from a Structural Model. Journal of Comparative Economics 35 (3): 443–466.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Elster, Jon. 2000. Social Norms and Economic Theory. In Culture and Politics, ed. Lane Crothers and Charles Lockhart, 363–380. New York: Palgrave Macmillan US.

    Google Scholar 

  • Esarey, Justin, and Gina Chirillo. 2013. Fairer Sex or Purity Myth? Corruption, Gender, and Institutional Context. Politics & Gender 9 (04): 361–389.

    Google Scholar 

  • Esarey, Justin, and Schwindt-Bayer, Leslie. 2017. Women’s Representation, Accountability and Corruption in Democracies. British Journal of Political Science: 1–32.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fehr, Ernst, and Klaus M. Schmidt. 1999. A Theory of Fairness, Competition, and Cooperation. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 114 (3): 817–868.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ferraz, Claudio, and Frederico Finan. 2008. Exposing Corrupt Politicians: The Effects of Brazil’s Publicly Released Audits on Electoral Outcomes. Quarterly Journal of Economics 123 (2): 703–745.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fisman, Raymond, and Edward Miguel. 2007. Corruption, Norms, and Legal Enforcement: Evidence from Diplomatic Parking Tickets. Journal of Political Economy 115 (6): 1020–1048.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frank, Björn, and Günther G. Schulze. 2000. Does Economics Make Citizens Corrupt? Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization 43 (1): 101–113.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frank, Björn, Johan Graf Lambsdorff, and Frédéric Boehm. 2011. Gender and Corruption: Lessons from Laboratory Corruption Experiments. The European Journal of Development Research 23 (1): 59–71.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Geertz, Clifford. 2006. The Interpretation of Cultures: Selected Essays. Nachdr. Basic Book-S. New York: Basic Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gentzkow, M., E.L. Glaeser, and C. Goldin. 2004. The Rise of the Fourth Estate: How Newspapers Became Informative and Why It Mattered. In Corruption and Reform: Lessons from America’s Economic History, ed. E.L. Glaeser and C. Goldin, 187–230. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gottfredson, Michael R., and Travis Hirschi. 2004. A General Theory of Crime. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press. Reprint.

    Google Scholar 

  • Green, Donald P., and Ian Shapiro. 1994. Pathologies of Rational Choice Theory: A Critique of Applications in Political Science. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Groenendijk, Nico. 1997. A Principal-Agent Model of Corruption. Crime, Law and Social Change 27 (3): 207–229.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Haidt, Jonathan. 2001. The Emotional Dog and Its Rational Tail: A Social Intuitionist Approach to Moral Judgment. Psychological Review 108: 814–834.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Harrison, Lawrence E., and Samuel P. Huntington. 2001. Culture Matters: How Values Shape Human Progress. New York: Basic Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hauk, Esther, and Maria Saez-Marti. 2002. On the Cultural Transmission of Corruption. Journal of Economic Theory 107 (2): 311–335.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hofstede, G.H. 2016. The Hofstede Centre. https://geert-hofstede.com/united-states.html. Accessed 20 June 2017.

  • Hofstede, Geert H., Gert Jan Hofstede, and Michael Minkov. 2010. Cultures and Organizations: Software of the Mind; Intercultural Cooperation and Its Importance for Survival. Rev. and expanded 3rd ed. New York: McGraw-Hill.

    Google Scholar 

  • Husted, Bryan W. 1999. Wealth, Culture, and Corruption. Journal of International Business Studies 30 (2): 339–359.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Klitgaard, Robert. 2009. Controlling Corruption. Nachdr. Berkeley: University of California Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • March, J.G., and J.P. Olsen. 2006. Elaborating the “New Institutionalism”. In The Oxford Handbook of Political Institutions, ed. R.A.W. Rhodes, S.A. Binder, and B.A. Rockman, 3–20. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mazar, Nina, On Amir, and Dan Ariely. 2008. The Dishonesty of Honest People: A Theory of Self-Concept Maintenance. Journal of Marketing Research 45 (6): 633–644.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Myrdal, Gunnar. 1968. Asian Drama: An Enquiry into the Poverty of Nations. New York: Twentieth Century Fund.

    Google Scholar 

  • Posner, Eric A. 2002. Law and Social Norms. 2., Print., 1. Harvard University Press paperback ed. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rivas, M. Fernanda. 2013. An Experiment on Corruption and Gender. Bulletin of Economic Research 65 (1): 10–42.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rose-Ackerman, Susan, and Bonnie J. Palifka. 2016. Corruption and Government: Causes, Consequences, and Reform. 2nd ed. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Rothstein, Bo, and Daniel Eek. 2009. Political Corruption and Social Trust: An Experimental Approach. Rationality and Society 21 (1): 81–112.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rothstein, Bo, and Davide Torsello. 2013. Is Corruption Understood Differently in Different Cultures? Anthropology Meets Political Science. Quality of Government Institute. Working Paper Series, 5.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sandholtz, Wayne, and Rein Taagepera. 2005. Corruption, Culture, and Communism. International Review of Sociology 15 (1): 109–131.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schulze, Günther G., and Björn Frank. 2003. Deterrence versus Intrinsic Motivation: Experimental Evidence on the Determinants of Corruptibility. Economics of Governance 4 (2): 143–160.

    Google Scholar 

  • Serra, Danila, and Leonard Wantchekon. 2012. New Advances in Experimental Research on Corruption, Research in Experimental Economics. Vol. 15. Bingley: Emerald.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sundström, Aksel, and Lena Wängnerud. 2016. Corruption as an Obstacle to Women’s Political Representation: Evidence from Local Councils in 18 European Countries. Party Politics 22 (3): 354–369.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Thelen, Kathleen. 1999. Historical Institutionalism in Comparative Politics. Annual Review of Political Science 2 (1): 369–404.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tirole, Jean. 1996. A Theory of Collective Reputations (with Applications to the Persistence of Corruption and to Firm Quality). The Review of Economic Studies 63 (1): 1–22.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Transparency International. 2017. Definition of Corruption. https://www.transparency.org/what-is-corruption/. Accessed 19 June 2017.

  • Treisman, Daniel. 2000. The Causes of Corruption: A Cross-National Study. Journal of Public Economics 76 (3): 399–457.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Van Veldhuizen, R. 2011. Bribery and the Fair Salary Hypothesis in the Lab. http://www.creedexperiment.nl/creed/people/veldhuizen/JobMarketPaper.pdf. Accessed 20 June 2017.

  • Watson, John, and Mark McNaughton. 2007. Gender Differences in Risk Aversion and Expected Retirement Benefits. Financial Analysts Journal 63 (4): 52–62.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Welzel, Christian. 2013. Freedom Rising: Human Empowerment and the Quest for Emancipation. World Values Surveys Books. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

The author acknowledges financial support from the Center for the Study of Democracy at the University of California, Irvine and the DFG (German Research Foundation, grant agreement number KU 3235/1-1).

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2018 The Author(s)

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Kubbe, I. (2018). Let’s Play: Bribery Games in the US and Germany. In: Kubbe, I., Engelbert, A. (eds) Corruption and Norms. Political Corruption and Governance. Palgrave Macmillan, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-66254-1_9

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics