Skip to main content

What Are the Conditions for Interest Group Influence?

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Lobbying in the European Parliament

Part of the book series: Palgrave Studies in European Union Politics ((PSEUP))

  • 1133 Accesses

Abstract

Why are even ostensibly strong interests, such as “big business”, sometimes less influential in shaping policy outcomes than weak interests, such as labour unions and non-governmental organisations? In this chapter, I develop a theoretical framework for studying interest group influence in the European Parliament. I do so by focusing on a number of key factors that may further, or limit, the ability of interest groups to shape policy outcomes. These relate to interest group factors (the ability to stand united), issue factors (the complexity and saliency of issues) and institutional factors (decision-makers’ receptiveness to certain arguments and interests). Together, these factors explain why interest groups with a high potential for influence often see their powers curtailed.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 109.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 139.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 139.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Bibliography

  • Baumgartner, F. R., & Jones, B. D. (1993). Agendas and instability in American politics. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Burns, C. and Carter, N. (2010). Is Co-decision Good for the Environment? An Analysis of the European Parliament's Green Credentials. Political Studies, 58(1), 123-142.

    Google Scholar 

  • Burns, C., & Carter, N. (2010). Is co-decision good for the environment? An analysis of the European parliament’s green credentials. Political Studies, 58(1), 123–142.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coen, D., & Katsaitism, A. (2013). Chameleon pluralism in the EU: An empirical study of the European Commission interest group density and diversity across policy domains. Journal of European Public Policy, 20(8), 1104–1119.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Costello, R. (2011). Does bicameralism promote stability? Inter-institutional relations and coalition formation in the European Parliament. West European Politics, 34(1), 122–144.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Culpepper, P. D. (2008). Business power, policy salience, and the study of politics. European Studies Forum, 38(2), 5–11.

    Google Scholar 

  • Culpepper, P. D. (2011). Quiet politics and business power: Corporate control in Europe and Japan. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dahl, R. A. (1958). A critique of the ruling Elite model. The American Political Science Review, 58(2), 463–469.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Daugbjerg, C., & Svendesen, G. T. (2001). Green taxation in question. Basingstoke: Palgrave.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Downs, A. (1972). Up and down with ecology: The ‘issue-attention cycle’. The Public Interest, 28, 38–50.

    Google Scholar 

  • European Parliament. (2010i). Second report on the proposal for a directive of the European Parliament and of the Council amending Council Directive 92/85/EEC on the introduction of measures to encourage improvements in the safety and health at work of pregnant workers and workers who have recently given birth or are breastfeeding (COM(2008)0637 – C6-0340/2008 – 2008/0193(COD)) Committee on women’s rights and gender equality.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gray, V., & Lowery, D. (1996). A Niche theory of interest representation. The Journal of Politic, 58(1), 91–111.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jones, B. D., & Baumgarther, F. R. (2005). The politics of attention: How government prioritizes problems. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jupille, J. (2004). Procedural politics: Issues, influence, and institutional choice in the European Union. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Kerwin, C. M. (2003). Rulemaking: How government agencies write law and make policy. Washington, DC: Congressional Quarterly Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hacker, J. S., & Pierson, P. (2010). Winner-take all politics: Public policy, political organization, and the precipitous rise of top incomes in the United States. Politics & Society, 38(2), 152–204.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kingdon, J. W. (1984). Agendas, alternatives, and public policies. Boston: Little, Brown.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lindblom, C. (1977). Politics and markets. New York: Basic Books. Ch. 3.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lowi, T. (1964). American business, public policy, case studies and political theory. World Politics, 16(4), 677–715.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McElroy, G. (2006). Committee representation in the European Parliament. European Union Politics, 7(1), 5–29.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Olson, M. (1965). The logic of collective action: Public goods and the theory of groups. Boston: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Riker, W. (1986). The art of political manipulation. Binghamton: Yale University.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ripoll Servent, A. (2011). Playing the co-decision game? Rules’ changes and institutional adaptation at the LIBE committee. Journal of European Integration, 34(1), 55–73.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ripoll Servent, A. (2015). Institutional and policy change in the European Parliament. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schattschneider, E. E. (1960). The semisovereign people. A realist’s view of democracy in America. New York: Holt.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shackleton, M., & Raunio, T. (2003). Codecision since Amsterdam: A laboratory for institutional innovation and change. Journal of European Public Policy, 10(2), 171–188.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Smith, R. A. (1984). Advocacy, interpretation, and influence in the US Congress. The American Political Science Review, 78(1), 44–63.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Smith, M. A. (2000). American business and political power: Political opinion, elections and democracy. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Stigler, G. (1971). The theory of economic regulation. Bell Journal of Economics and Management, 2(1), 3–21.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Truman, D. (1951). The governmental process: Political interests and public opinion. New York: Knopf Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Vogel, D. (1987). Political science and the study or corporate power: A dissent from the new conventional wisdom. British Journal of Political Science, 17(4), 358–408.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wilson, J. Q. (1980). The politics of regulation. New York: Basic Books.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2017 The Author(s)

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Dionigi, M.K. (2017). What Are the Conditions for Interest Group Influence?. In: Lobbying in the European Parliament. Palgrave Studies in European Union Politics. Palgrave Macmillan, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-42688-4_3

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics