Skip to main content

Regulating SIFIs in the European Union: A Primer from an Economic Point of View

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Regulating and Supervising European Financial Markets
  • 1056 Accesses

Abstract

Global financial markets have experienced an unprecedented succession of crises affecting the processes, structures, and rules of said markets. As well as the underlying crises, innovative concepts to regulate and supervise financial institutions are still unfolding, leading to new organizations as well as new rules. While many of the institutional responses are of a general nature, specific institutional change is directed at selected financial intermediaries. While small in number, Systemically Important Financial Institutions (SIFIs) are, by their very nature, of seminal importance. First of all, this analysis puts SIFI regulation into perspective, before identifying two critical pillars of any SIFI rulebook. Based thereon, it is shown that the current European approach seems rather ill-conceived, as it lacks thorough justification, reasoning, and structure, and is thus prone to causing undesirable market processes in the future. This segues into the discussion of alternative approaches to the regulatory treatment of SIFIs that could lead upcoming institutional change in a reasonable direction.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 129.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 169.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 169.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    This distinction is according to the seminal work of Nobel laureate Douglass C. North, who defines institutions as the “rules of the game” and distinguishes them from organizations, see North (1990), pp. 3–6. However, “institutional change” encompasses the evolution of rules and organizations alike.

  2. 2.

    The elaboration of the distinction between spontaneous and designed rules belongs to the seminal achievements of Nobel laureate Friedrich August von Hayek, see extensively v Hayek (1989). See also v Hayek (1963), and, of his earlier works, v Hayek (1933), especially p. 129 on “spontaneous institutions”.

  3. 3.

    Obviously, “financial institutions” goes beyond banks. Regardless of non-banks—like AIG—being treated as SIFIs during or prior to the financial crises, the discussion of systemic importance traditionally focuses on banks, see e.g. Herring (2009), especially p. 178. This primer proceeds analogously. In particular on systemically important insurance institutions, see Harrington (2009). More in general on various financial institutions of systemic relevance, see Billio et al. (2012). Skeptically on the existence of SIFIs that are neither banks nor life insurers, see Elliott (2012).

  4. 4.

    Representing a global view, not going into European details, see Moshirian (2012).

  5. 5.

    As discussed in several contributions to this compilation. As an overview, see also Schoenmaker (2013), especially pp. 365–368.

  6. 6.

    See Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act, Pub. L. No. 111–203, §§ 931–939H, 124 Stat. 1376 (2010). Of the numerous comments on Dodd-Frank in general, see extensively Murdock (2011). With respect to the impact of Dodd-Frank on financial regulation, see also Cooley and Walter (2011).

  7. 7.

    Coffee Jr (2012), p. 342.

  8. 8.

    See the extensive discussion by Schwarcz (2008), especially pp. 196–198.

  9. 9.

    For an overview of different definitions, see Prokopczuk (2009), pp. 2–4.

  10. 10.

    One of the shortest definitions of systemic risk (the “possibility of system wide failures”) has been provided by Kaufman (1996), p. 17. The European Central Bank defines systemic risk as a risk of financial instability “so widespread that it impairs the functioning of a financial system to the point where economic growth and welfare suffer materially”, see European Central Bank (2010), p. 147. During his extensive discussion, Schwarcz (2008), especially p. 204, suggests a rather detailed “working definition of systemic risk: the risk that (1) an economic shock such as market or institutional failure triggers (through a panic or otherwise) either (X) the failure of a chain of markets or institutions or (Y) a chain of significant losses to financial institutions, (2) resulting in increases in the cost of capital or decreases in its availability, often evidenced by substantial financial-market price volatility”. On the ambiguity of the definitions of systemic risk, see Cerutti et al. (2012), with further references.

  11. 11.

    For an empirical study of systemic risk drivers among European banks that shows size to be a minor determinant of SIFIs, see Kleinow and Nell (2015).

  12. 12.

    Adams and Brock (1987), p. 61. Nevertheless, the economic history of the US in particular shows a long tradition of concern about big banks, see Goldstein and Véron (2011), p. 5.

  13. 13.

    See, e.g., Moosa (2010), pp. 319–320.

  14. 14.

    Among the most (in)famous examples are the insolvencies of the railroad company Penn Central, and car manufacturer Chrysler in the 1970s. On the Penn Central case, see Weston (1971), especially p. 311, and the further contributions in that issue, pp. 327–362. On (the loan guarantee programme for) Chrysler, see e.g. Reich and Donahue (1985). On the meaning of Continental Illinois for the TBTF concept, see Goldstein and Véron (2011), pp. 5–6. Besides the subsequent analysis, see also, more briefly, Kleinow et al. (2014), especially pp. 1586–1587.

  15. 15.

    The US (office of the) comptroller of the currency (OCC) is an independent agency of the Department of the Treasury that “charters, regulates, and supervises national banks and federal savings associations (collectively, banks) and licenses and supervises the federal branches and agencies of foreign banks. The OCC’s mission is to ensure that these institutions operate in a safe and sound manner, provide fair access to financial services, treat customers fairly, and comply with applicable laws and regulations”, see OCC (2014), p. 1. As he shows characteristics of a central banking as well as of a supervisory agency, an equivalent to the OCC might not be found in different regulatory architectures.

  16. 16.

    See US Congress—House of Representatives (1984), pp. 194–276. Prior to its failure, Continental Illinois had been the eighth-biggest bank in the US in terms of total deposits.

  17. 17.

    See US Congress – House of Representatives (1984) passim, esp. pp. 220, 278, 299–300.

  18. 18.

    See US Congress – House of Representatives (1984), p. 300.

  19. 19.

    Morgan (2002), p. 880. On the critical reception of the bail-out of Continental Illinois, see Macey and Garrett (1988).

  20. 20.

    See Athavale (2000), especially pp. 124–126.

  21. 21.

    Dowd (1999), p. 10. See also Moosa (2010), especially pp. 320–321, 331–332. Extensively on the LTCM case in general, see Dunbar (2000).

  22. 22.

    Financial institutions that are overtly or covertly categorized as being TBTF gain an additional safety net against insolvency—probably producing distorting effects for several of their stakeholder groups. See O’Hara and Shaw (1990), pp. 1588–1590 and passim. See also Kane (2000). See also, very pointedly, Cochrane (2009), especially p. 34: “As long as some firms are considered too big to fail, those firms will take outsized risks.”

  23. 23.

    See Morrison (2011), pp. 500–501, with further references.

  24. 24.

    See again, very pointedly, Cochrane (2009), especially p. 34: “After the Bear Stearns bailout earlier in the year, markets came to the conclusion that investment banks and bank holding companies were “too big to fail” and would be bailed out. But when the government did not bail out Lehman, and in fact said it lacked the legal authority to do so, everyone reassessed that expectation.”

  25. 25.

    On the seminal importance of the Lehman case, see, very pointedly, Mollenkamp et al. (2008). More extensively, see the economic analysis of Brunnermeier (2009), especially pp. 88–90. For a detailed review, see Estrada (2011), especially pp. 1113–1125.

  26. 26.

    Herring (2009), p. 176.

  27. 27.

    Bernanke (2009) (contains all the citations of this paragraph).

  28. 28.

    The earliest references to SIFIs date back to the early 2000s, see Soussa (2000); Bank for International Settlements (2001); Belaisch et al. (2001); and Worrell (2004). In connection to the recent financial crisis, SIFIs were first mentioned in the Global Financial Stability Report of April 2007, see International Monetary Fund (2007).

  29. 29.

    See Jenkins and Davies (2009).

  30. 30.

    See Financial Stability Board (2011), p. 4. Previously, parts of the assessment methodology and the regulatory measures had been mentioned in a (preliminary) Basel document, see Basel Committee on Banking Supervision (2011). Shortly thereafter, the credit rating firm Moody’s listed 28 banks following a comparable methodology, and published this as part of the Weekly Credit Outlook of 25 Jul 2011, pp. 18–19 (accessible via www.moodys.com).

  31. 31.

    See Financial Stability Board (2012).

  32. 32.

    See Financial Stability Board (2013).

  33. 33.

    See Financial Stability Board (2014); in connection with Basel Committee on Banking Supervision (2014).

  34. 34.

    The ECB supervises about 120 “significant banks” and identifies them based on size, importance for the economy (EU, member state), cross-border activities, and further qualitative criteria; see Council Regulation (EU) No 1024/2013 of 15 October 2013 conferring specific tasks on the European Central Bank concerning policies relating to the prudential supervision of credit institutions. Official Journal of the European Union 56:63–89 (L 287/63, 29.10.2013), especially pp. 75–76. National systemically important banks (N-SIBs) in Germany are identified by a comparable selection of quantitative variables, e.g. the balance sheet total, the intensity of interbank connections and cross-border connections, see Deutscher Bundestag (2012); and Deutsche Bundesbank/Bundesanstalt für Finanzdienstleistungsaufsicht (2009), pp. 17–18.

  35. 35.

    Stern and Feldman (2004), p. 12. On the problem of this financial contagion in general, see Kaufman (1994). See also the modeling approach of Allen and Gale (2000).

  36. 36.

    See, extensively, Benston (1998), pp. 27–85 passim. See also, more briefly, Hanson et al. (2011), especially pp. 4–7.

  37. 37.

    Elliot and Litan (2011), p. 6.

  38. 38.

    See Rudolph (2014), especially pp. 76–77.

  39. 39.

    See also the discussion of “over-inclusion” vs. “under-inclusion” of Elliot and Litan (2011), pp. 10–14. Briefly on “over-designation” vs. “under-designation”, see Elliott (2012).

  40. 40.

    As with the shadow banking system that had evolved prior to the recent crises, see e.g. de la Torre and Ize (2010), especially pp. 122–124.

  41. 41.

    See Kleinow et al. (2014), p. 1585–1586.

  42. 42.

    For a study of implicit funding subsidies of large banks, see Kleinow and Horsch (2014).

  43. 43.

    See Kleinow et al. (2014), especially pp. 1585–1588 and passim. See also later Bongini et al. (2015).

  44. 44.

    For a seminal work on selective perception, see Dearborn and Simon (1958). In a general management context, see Beyer et al. (1997), with further references. In a behavioural finance context, see, extensively, Oehler (1992).

  45. 45.

    On the absence of “straightforward quantitative methods to find the answers here”, see Elliott (2012).

  46. 46.

    See the revised version of the Basel Committee’s G-SIB surcharge proposal, i.e. Basel Committee on Banking Supervision (2013); and the SIFI article (Art. 131) of the CRD IV, i.e. Directive 2013/36/EU of the European Parliament and of the Council of 26 June 2013, on access to the activity of credit institutions and the prudential supervision of credit institutions and investment firms, amending Directive 2002/87/EC and repealing Directives 2006/48/EC and 2006/49/EC. Official Journal of the European Union 56:338–436 (L 176/338, 27.06.2013).

  47. 47.

    Commenting on an earlier, quite similar list, the NY Times wrote of “the usual suspects”, see Cox and Larsen (2011).

  48. 48.

    For example, the significance of the Lehman insolvency has been attached to the institution’s 158-year-long history. Based thereon, Judge J M Peck in presiding over Lehman’s filing for Chap. 11 coined the oft-cited declaration of Lehman Brothers as being “the only true icon to fall” during the crisis processes of 2008, see e.g. Denman (2012), p. 271. On this “death of a titan of America’s financial system”, see also Estrada (2011), p. 1113.

  49. 49.

    The problem of (non)subadditivity is a vital part of the discussion of Value-at-Risk measures: A combination of risk positions would represent a total risk that is equal to or smaller than the sum of the single risk positions it consists of. As a seminal contribution, see Artzner et al. (1999), especially pp. 209, 216–217.

  50. 50.

    See Basel Committee on Banking Supervision (2012), subsequently elaborating higher loss absorbency (HLA) as a principal countermeasure.

  51. 51.

    In detail, see Adrian and Brunnermeier (2011); International Monetary Fund (2009); Billio et al. (2012); Acharya et al. (2010); Brownlees and Engle (2012); Jobst and Gray (2013); Weiß et al. (2014). For a comprehensive synopsis, see Bisias et al. (2012).

  52. 52.

    See, e.g., Financial Stability Board (2010).

  53. 53.

    See Avgouleas et al. (2013), especially pp. 210–211; see also Rudolph (2014), especially pp. 79–81.

  54. 54.

    For a general overview on EL calculation, see Bluhm et al. (2010), pp. 2–21.

  55. 55.

    The LGD can be mitigated by collateral, as in the following example: If an outstanding loan (EAD = initial loan minus repayments) amounts to 150, and the lender benefits from a mortgage of 120, the recovery rate would be 120/150 = 0.8, while the LGD would be 1–120/150 = 0.2. For a detailed discussion of the problem of LGD, see Schuermann (2004).

  56. 56.

    See Basel Committee on Banking Supervision (2013), pp. 12, 16–19.

  57. 57.

    For a rather positive evaluation, see Hanson et al. (2011), especially pp. 24–25.

  58. 58.

    Unsurprisingly, rule makers support this correlation, see e.g. Basel Committee on Banking Supervision (2010); however, economic analysis leads to mixed results at best—see e.g. Blum (1999).

  59. 59.

    In comparison to the above-cited study of the Basel Committee, see e.g. Macroeconomic Assessment Group (2010).

  60. 60.

    See the in-depth analysis of Maes and Schoutens (2012), especially p. 63: “Conceptually, contingent capital instruments are debt instruments in ‘good’ states of the world, but convert into common equity at prespecified trigger levels in ‘bad’ states of the world. In principle, the triggers can be tied to the deterioration in the condition of the specific banking institution and/or to the banking system as a whole. Contingent capital is a form of catastrophe insurance subscribed to by the bank. In general, contingent capital is a type of facility or instrument that automatically converts into equity when a certain stress-related trigger is breached, meaning that (typically) private investors provide an automatic boost to loss-absorbing capital at the time when it is most needed.”

  61. 61.

    Consequently, contingent capital could be called bail-in-able debt, see Kleinow (2015), in this compilation of papers. The concept is not a result of the recent crises, but goes back to suggestions such as Culp (2002).

  62. 62.

    Extensively, see Lehmann and Manger-Nestler (2014).

  63. 63.

    See European Commission (2014a).

  64. 64.

    See European Commission (2014b). With respect to the original US approach, see Kwan and Laderman (1999).

  65. 65.

    The concept of complementarity was elaborated by several authors dealing with different economic problems. As a seminal contribution, see Milgrom and Roberts (1995). On the complementarity of financial systems, see Hackethal and Tyrell (1998).

  66. 66.

    For a comprehensive study, see Lang and Schröder (2013).

  67. 67.

    See Financial Stability Board (2013).

  68. 68.

    See Directive 2014/59/EU of the European Parliament and of the Council of 15 May 2014 establishing a framework for the recovery and resolution of credit institutions and investment firms and amending Council Directive 82/891/EEC, and Directives 2001/24/EC, 2002/47/EC, 2004/25/EC, 2005/56/EC, 2007/36/EC, 2011/35/EU, 2012/30/EU and 2013/36/EU, and Regulations (EU) No 1093/2010 and (EU) No 648/2012, of the European Parliament and of the Council. Official Journal of the European Union 57:190–348 (L 173/190, 12.06.2014).

  69. 69.

    Regulation (EU) No 806/2014 of the European Parliament and of the Council of 15 July 2014 establishing uniform rules and a uniform procedure for the resolution of credit institutions and certain investment firms in the framework of a Single Resolution Mechanism and a Single Resolution Fund and amending Regulation (EU) No 1093/2010. Official Journal of the European Union 57:1–90 (L 225/1, 30.07.2014).

  70. 70.

    Herring (2009), especially p. 180.

  71. 71.

    Pointedly, see Avgouleas et al. (2013), especially p. 216.

  72. 72.

    Supportively, see Doluca et al. (2010).

  73. 73.

    See Rudolph (2014), especially pp. 85–86.

  74. 74.

    See, e.g., Krishnamurthy (2014).

  75. 75.

    Herring (2009), p. 171.

References

  • Acharya V, Pedersen L, Philippon T, Richardson M (2010) Measuring systemic risk. FRB Cleveland Working Paper 10/02

    Google Scholar 

  • Adams W, Brock JW (1987) Corporate size and the bailout factor. J Econ Issues 21(1):61–85

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Adrian T, Brunnermeier M (2011) CoVaR. NBER Working Paper No. 17454

    Google Scholar 

  • Allen F, Gale D (2000) Financial contagion. J Polit Econ 108:1–33. doi:10.1086/262109

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Artzner P, Delbaen F, Eber JM, Heath D (1999) Coherent measures or risk. Math Finance 9(3):203–228. doi:10.1111/1467-9965.00068

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Athavale M (2000) Uninsured deposits and the too-big-to-fail policy in 1984 and 1991. Am Bus Rev 18(2):123–128

    Google Scholar 

  • Avgouleas E, Goodhart C, Schoenmaker D (2013) Bank resolution plans as a catalyst for global financial reform. J Financ Stab 9:210–218. doi:10.1016/j.jfs.2011.12.002

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bank for International Settlements (2001) Core principles for systemically important payment systems. Basel

    Google Scholar 

  • Basel Committee on Banking Supervision (2010) An assessment of the long-term economic impact of stronger capital and liquidity requirements. Basel

    Google Scholar 

  • Basel Committee on Banking Supervision (2011) Global systemically important banks: assessment methodology and the additional loss absorbency requirement. Consultative Document. Basel

    Google Scholar 

  • Basel Committee on Banking Supervision (2012) A framework for dealing with domestic systemically important banks. Basel

    Google Scholar 

  • Basel Committee on Banking Supervision (2013) Global systemically important banks: updated assessment methodology and the higher loss absorbency requirement. Basel

    Google Scholar 

  • Basel Committee on Banking Supervision (2014) The G-SIB assessment methodology—score calculation. Basel

    Google Scholar 

  • Belaisch A, Kodres L, Levy J, Ubide A (2001) Euro-Area banking at the crossroads. IMF Working Paper WP/01/28, Washington

    Google Scholar 

  • Benston GJ (1998) Regulating financial markets: a critique and some proposals. Hobart Papers, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Bernanke BS (2009) Financial reform to address systemic risk. Speech at the council on foreign relations. Washington. 10 Mar 2009. Available via http://federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/bernanke20090310a.htm. Accessed 07 Apr 2015

  • Beyer JM, Chattopadhyay P, George E, Glick WH, ogilvie dt, Pugliese D (1997) The selective perception of managers revisited. Acad Manage J 40(3):716–737

    Google Scholar 

  • Billio M, Getmansky M, Lo A, Pelizzon L (2012) Econometric measures of connectedness and systemic risk in the finance and insurance sectors. J Financ Econ 104:535–559

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bisias D, Flood M, Lo AW, Stavros V (2012) A survey of systemic risk analytics. Annu Rev Financ Econ 4:255–296

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bluhm C, Overbeck L, Wagner C (2010) An introduction to credit risk modeling, 2nd edn. Taylor & Francis, Boca Raton

    Google Scholar 

  • Blum J (1999) Do capital adequacy requirements reduce risks in banking? J Bank Finance 23:755–771

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bongini P, Nieri L, Pelagatti M (2015) The importance of being systemically important financial institutions. J Bank Financ 50:562–574

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brownlees C, Engle R (2012) Volatility, correlation and tails for systemic risk measurement. Working Paper. Available via SSRN: http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=1611229. Accessed 07 Apr 2015

  • Brunnermeier MK (2009) Deciphering the liquidity and credit crunch 2007–2008. J Econ Perspect 23(1):77–100. doi:10.1257/jep.23.1.77

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carrington T (1984) U.S. won’t let 11 biggest banks in nation fail. Wall Street J 20 Sep 1984:A2

    Google Scholar 

  • Cerutti E, Claessens S, McGuire P (2012) Systemic risks in global banking: what available data can tell us and what more data are needed? NBER Working Paper No. 18531

    Google Scholar 

  • Cochrane JH (2009) Lessons from the financial crisis. Regulation 32(4):34–37

    Google Scholar 

  • Coffee JC Jr (2012) The political economy of Dodd-Frank: why financial reform tends to be frustrated and systemic risk perpetuated. In: Ferran E, Moloney N, Hill JG, Coffee JC Jr (eds) The regulatory aftermath of the financial crisis. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, pp 301–371

    Google Scholar 

  • Cooley TF, Walter I (2011) The architecture of financial regulation. In: Acharya VV, Cooley TF, Richardson M, Walter I (eds) Regulating wall street: the Dodd-Frank act and the new architecture of global finance. Wiley, Hoboken, pp 35–50

    Google Scholar 

  • Cox R, Larsen PT (2011) Putting a positive spin on too-big-to-fail. New York Times, 20 Dec 2011. Available via http://www.nytimes.com/2011/12/21/business/putting-a-positive-spin-on-too-big-to-fail.html?_r=0. Accessed 07 Apr 2015

  • Culp CL (2002) Contingent capital: integrating corporate financing and risk management decisions. J Appl Corp Finance 15(1):46–56. doi:10.1111/j.1745-6622.2002.tb00340.x

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • de la Torre A, Ize A (2010) Regulatory reform: integrating paradigms. Int Finance 13(1):109–139. doi:10.1111/j.1468-2362.2010.01254.x

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dearborn DC, Simon HA (1958) Selective perception: a note on the departmental identifications of executives. Sociometry 21(2):140–144

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Denman HL (2012) Tale of two debtors: Lehman Brothers and the availability of equitable subordination in the dueling debtor context. NYU J Law Bus 9:269–294

    Google Scholar 

  • Deutsche Bundesbank/Bundesanstalt für Finanzdienstleistungsaufsicht (2009) Risikoorientierte Aufsicht nach Umsetzung der zweiten Säule von Basel II. Veröffentlichung im Rahmen von CEBS’ supervisory disclosure. Frankfurt/Main

    Google Scholar 

  • Deutscher Bundestag (2012) Antwort der Bundesregierung […]. BT-Drucksache 17/10931, 05 Oct 2012, Berlin

    Google Scholar 

  • Doluca H, Klüh U, Wagner M, Weder di Mauro B (2010) Reducing systemic relevance: a proposal. Working Paper, Sachverständigenrat zur Begutachtung der Gesamtwirtschaftlichen Entwicklung, No. 04/2010. Available via http://www.econstor.eu/bitstream/10419/74735/1/749370688.pdf. Accessed 07 Apr 2015

  • Dowd K (1999) Too big to fail? Long-term capital management and the federal reserve. Cato Institute Briefing Papers No. 52. Cato Institute, Washington

    Google Scholar 

  • Dunbar N (ed) (2000) Inventing money: the story of Long-Term Capital Management and the legends behind it. Wiley, Chichester

    Google Scholar 

  • Elliott DJ (2012) Designating systemically important financial institutions: balancing costs and benefits, testimony before the house financial services subcommittee on financial institutions and consumer credit. Brookings Institution, Washington. Available via http://www.brookings.edu/~/media/research/files/testimony/2012/5/16%20sifis%20elliott/16_sifis_elliott.pdf. Accessed 31 Jan 2015

  • Elliot DJ, Litan RE (2011) Identifying and regulating systemically important financial institutions: the risks of under and over identification and regulation. Policy Brief Paper, 16 Jan 2011. Brookings Institution, Washington

    Google Scholar 

  • Estrada EJ (2011) The immediate and lasting impacts of the 2008 economic collapse—Lehman brothers, General Motors, and the secured credit markets. Univ Richmond Law Rev 45:1111–1142

    Google Scholar 

  • European Central Bank (2010) Financial Stability Review. Frankfurt/Main

    Google Scholar 

  • European Commission (2014a) Proposal for a regulation of the European Parliament and of the Council on structural measures improving the resilience of EU credit institutions. COM (2014) 43 final, 29 Jan 2014, Brussels

    Google Scholar 

  • European Commission (2014b) Structural reform of the EU banking sector. Press release, 29 Jan 2014, Brussels

    Google Scholar 

  • Financial Stability Board (2010) Intensity and effectiveness of SIFI supervision—recommendations for enhanced supervision. Basel, 2 Nov 2010

    Google Scholar 

  • Financial Stability Board (2011) Policy measures to address systemically important financial institutions. Basel, 4 Nov 2011. Available via http://www.financialstabilityboard.org/wp-content/uploads/r_111104bb.pdf?page_moved=1. Accessed 07 Apr 2015

  • Financial Stability Board (2012) Update of group of global systemically important banks (G-SIBs). Basel, 1 Nov 2012. Available via http://www.financialstabilityboard.org/wp-content/uploads/r_121031ac.pdf. Accessed 07 Apr 2015

  • Financial Stability Board (2013) 2013 update of group of global systemically important banks (G-SIBs). Basel, 11 Nov 2013. Available via http://www.financialstabilityboard.org/wp-content/uploads/r_131111.pdf. Accessed 07 Apr 2015

  • Financial Stability Board (2014) 2014 update of list of global systemically important banks (G-SIBs). Basel, 6 Nov 2014. Available via http://www.financialstabilityboard.org/wp-content/uploads/r_141106b.pdf. Accessed 07 Apr 2015

  • Goldstein M, Véron N (2011) Too big to fail: the transatlantic debate. Bruegel Working Paper No. 2011/03, Brussels

    Google Scholar 

  • Hackethal AR, Tyrell M (1998) Complementarity and financial systems—a theoretical approach. Working Paper No. 11, Wilhelm Merton Professur für Ökonomie des Welthandels, Johann Wolfgang Goethe-Universität Frankfurt

    Google Scholar 

  • Hanson SG, Kashyap AK, Stein JC (2011) A macroprudential approach to financial regulation. J Econ Perspect 25(1):3–28. doi:10.1257/jep.25.1.3

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Harrington SE (2009) The financial crisis, systemic risk, and the future of insurance regulation. J Risk Insur 76:785–819

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Herring R (2009) Why and how resolution policy must be improved. In: Ciorciari JD, Taylor JB (eds) The road ahead for the fed. Hoover Institution Press, Stanford, pp 171–187

    Google Scholar 

  • International Monetary Fund (2007) Global Financial Stability Report. Washington

    Google Scholar 

  • International Monetary Fund (2009) Global Financial Stability Report. Washington

    Google Scholar 

  • Jenkins P, Davies PJ (2009) Thirty financial groups on systemic risk list. Financial Times, 30 Nov 2009: 30

    Google Scholar 

  • Jobst A, Gray D (2013) Systemic contingent claims analysis—estimating market-implied systemic risk. IMF Working Paper 13/54, Washington

    Google Scholar 

  • Kane EJ (2000) Incentives for banking megamergers: what motives might regulators infer from event-study evidence? J Money Credit Bank 32:671–701

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kaufman GG (1994) Bank contagion: a review of the theory and evidence. J Financ Serv 8:123–150

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kaufman GG (1996) Bank failures, systemic risk, and bank regulation. Cato J 16(5):17–45

    Google Scholar 

  • Kleinow J (2015) Loss-absorbing capacity: the last remedy for European SIFI regulation? In this compilation of papers

    Google Scholar 

  • Kleinow J, Horsch A (2014) The impact of state guarantees on banks’ ratings and risk behavior. J Gov Regul 3(1):42–57. doi:10.2139/ssrn.2392750

    Google Scholar 

  • Kleinow J, Nell T (2015) Determinants of systemically important banks: the case of Europe. Working Paper. Available via SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=2531326. Accessed 07 Apr 2015

  • Kleinow J, Nell T, Rogler S, Horsch A (2014) The value of being systemically important: event study on regulatory announcement for banks. Appl Financ Econ 24:1585–1604

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krishnamurthy P (2014) Benefit-cost analysis of financial regulation. J Leg Stud 43(S2):S273–S296

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kwan SH, Laderman ES (1999) On the portfolio effects of financial convergence — a review of the literature. FRB San Franc Econ Rev 2:18–31

    Google Scholar 

  • Lang G, Schröder M (2013) Do we need a separate banking system?—an assessment. ZEW Discussion Paper No. 13–011, Mannheim

    Google Scholar 

  • Lehmann M, Manger-Nestler C (2014) Einheitlicher Europäischer Aufsichtsmechanismus: Bankenaufsicht durch die EZB. J Bank Law Bank 26:2–21

    Google Scholar 

  • Macey JR, Garrett EH (1988) Market discipline by depositors: a summary of the theoretical and empirical arguments. Yale J Regul 5:215–239

    Google Scholar 

  • Macroeconomic Assessment Group (2010) Assessing the macroeconomic impact of the transition to stronger capital and liquidity requirements. Final Report, Basel

    Google Scholar 

  • Maes S, Schoutens W (2012) Contingent capital: an in-depth discussion. Economic Notes by Banca Monte dei Paschi di Siena SpA 41(1/2):59–79

    Google Scholar 

  • Milbradt K (2012) Level 3 assets: booking profits and concealing losses. Rev Financ Stud 25(1):55–95

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Milgrom P, Roberts J (1995) Complementarities and fit: strategy, structure, and organizational change in manufacturing. J Account Econ 19:179–208

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mollenkamp C, Whitehouse M, Hilsenrath J, Dugan IJ (2008) Lehman’s demise triggered cash crunch around globe. Wall Street J 29 Sep 2008. Available via http://utminers.utep.edu/jtbrannon/articles/lehman.pdf. Accessed 07 Apr 2015

  • Moosa I (2010) The myth of too big to fail. J Bank Regul 11:319–333. doi:10.1057/jbr.2010.15

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Morgan DP (2002) Rating banks: risk and uncertainty in an opaque industry. Am Econ Rev 92:874–880

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Morgan DP, Stiroh KJ (2005) Too big to fail after all these years. Staff Report No. 220, FRB of New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Morrison AD (2011) Systemic risks and the ‘too-big-to-fail’ problem. Oxf Rev Econ Policy 27(3):498–516

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Moshirian F (2012) The future and dynamics of global systemically important banks. J Bank Finance 36:2675–2679. doi:10.1016/j.jbankfin.2012.04.008

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Murdock CW (2011) The Dodd-Frank wall street reform and consumer protection act: what caused the financial crisis and will Dodd-Frank succeed in preventing future crises? SMU Law Rev 64:1243–1328

    Google Scholar 

  • North DC (1990) Institutions, institutional change and economic performance. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • OCC – Office of the Comptroller of the Currency (2014) Annual Report—Fiscal Year 2014. Publ. No. AR-2014, Washington

    Google Scholar 

  • O’Hara M, Shaw W (1990) Deposit insurance and wealth effects: the value of being “Too Big to Fail”. J Finance 45:1587–1600. doi:10.1111/j.1540-6261.1990.tb03729.x

    Google Scholar 

  • Oehler A (1992) “Anomalien”, “Irrationalitäten” oder “Biases” der Erwartungsnutzentheorie und ihre Relevanz für Finanzmärkte. J Bank Law Bank 4:97–124

    Google Scholar 

  • Prokopczuk M (2009) Essays on systemic risk. Dissertation, University of Mannheim

    Google Scholar 

  • Reich RB, Donahue JD (1985) Lessons from the Chrysler bailout. Calif Manage Rev 27(4):157–183

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rudolph B (2014) Bankregulierung zur Lösung des “too big to fail”-Problems. Die Unternehmung 68:72–91

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schoenmaker D (2013) Financial supervision in the EU. In: Caprio G (ed) Handbook of safeguarding global financial stability: political, social, cultural, and economic theories and models, vol 2. Elsevier, Oxford, pp 355–369

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Schuermann T (2004) What do we know about loss given default? Working Paper 04/01, The Wharton Financial Institutions Center

    Google Scholar 

  • Schwarcz SL (2008) Systemic risk. Georgetown Law J 97:193–249

    Google Scholar 

  • Soussa F (2000) Too big to fail: moral hazard and unfair competition? In: Halme L, Hawkesby C, Healey J, Saapar I, Soussa F (eds) Financial stability and central banks—selected issues for financial safety nets and market discipline. Bank of England, London, pp 5–31

    Google Scholar 

  • Stern G, Feldman R (2004) Too big to fail: the hazards of bank bailouts. Brookings Institution Press, Washington

    Google Scholar 

  • US Congress—House of Representatives (1984) Inquiry into Continental Illinois Corp. and Continental Illinois National Bank: Hearings before the Subcommittee on Financial Institutions Supervision, Regulation, and Insurance of the Committee on Banking, Finance, and Urban Affairs. House of Representatives, Ninety-Eighth Congress, Second Session, September 18/19 and October 4 1984, Serial-Nr. 98–111, Washington

    Google Scholar 

  • v Hayek FA (1933) The trend of economic thinking. Economica 13:121–137

    Google Scholar 

  • v Hayek FA (1963) Arten der Ordnung. Ordo 14:3–20

    Google Scholar 

  • v Hayek FA (1989) Spontaneous (‘grown’) order and organized (‘made’) order. In: Modlovsky N (ed) Order: with or without design. Centre for Research into Communist Economies, London, pp 101–123

    Google Scholar 

  • Weiß G, Neumann S, Bostandzic D (2014) Systemic risk and bank consolidation: international evidence. J Bank Finance 40:165–181. doi:10.1016/j.jbankfin.2013.11.032

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weistroffer C (2011) Identifying systemically important financial institutions (SIFIs). Deutsche Bank Research, Frankfurt/Main

    Google Scholar 

  • Weston JF (1971) The industrial economics background of the Penn Central Bankruptcy. J Finance 26(2):311–326. doi:10.1111/j.1540-6261.1971.tb00899.x

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Worrell D (2004) Quantitative assessment of the financial sector: an integrated approach. IMF Working Paper WP/04/153, Washington

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgment

This paper was originally prepared for, and presented at, the HTW Berlin/University of Oslo Research Seminar on “The European Institutional Responses to the Challenges of Supervising Financial Markets” in Berlin, Germany, in December 2014. I would like to thank the seminar participants, the reviewers, and in particular Gudula Deipenbrock, Mads Andenas, and Jacob Kleinow for their valuable comments and suggestions that greatly improved the paper.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Andreas Horsch .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2016 Springer International Publishing Switzerland

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Horsch, A. (2016). Regulating SIFIs in the European Union: A Primer from an Economic Point of View. In: Andenas, M., Deipenbrock, G. (eds) Regulating and Supervising European Financial Markets. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-32174-5_16

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-32174-5_16

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Springer, Cham

  • Print ISBN: 978-3-319-32172-1

  • Online ISBN: 978-3-319-32174-5

  • eBook Packages: Law and CriminologyLaw and Criminology (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics