Skip to main content

Investigating the Impact of Small Versus Large Firms on Economic Performance of Countries and Industries

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Contemporary Entrepreneurship

Abstract

Following earlier work by Audretsch et al. (2002), we assume that an optimal size-class structure exists, in terms of achieving maximal economic growth rates. Such an optimal structure is likely to exist, as economies need a balance between the core competences of large firms (such as exploitation of economies of scale) and those of smaller firms (such as flexibility and exploration of new ideas). Accordingly, changes in size-class structure (i.e., changes in the relative shares in economic activity accounted for by micro, small, medium-sized and large firms) may affect macro-economic growth. Using a unique database of the EU-27 countries for the period 2002–2008 for five broad sectors of economic activity and four size-classes, we find empirical support which suggests that, on average for these countries over this period, the share of micro and large firms may have been ‘above optimum’ (particularly in lower income EU countries), whereas the share of medium-sized firms may have been ‘below optimum’ (particularly in higher income EU countries). This evidence suggests that the transition from a ‘managed’ to an ‘entrepreneurial’ economy (Audretsch and Thurik 2001) has not yet been completed in all countries of the EU-27.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 129.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 169.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 169.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    Of course, not all firms are involved in innovation. Moreover, the extent to which small and large firms explore and exploit innovative ideas will differ by sector.

  2. 2.

    For instance, a positive net growth rate of the share of SMEs may go together with positive but also with negative growth of GNP.

  3. 3.

    It may be argued that the optimal industry structure, in terms of the optimal share of economic activity by small and medium-sized firms (SMEs) in an economy, may have increased over the last four decades or so, due to the emergence and diffusion of new information and communication technologies. This lowered minimum efficient scale and improved the importance of flexibility and the ability to adjust quickly to changing market circumstances, things which small firms are typically good at. However, as explained in Appendix 1, as we are considering only a short period of time in this study (2002–2008), we assume that the optimal share of SME activity remains constant over this short period.

  4. 4.

    The data for a more recent version of the database are publicly available from the following link: http://ec.europa.eu/enterprise/policies/sme/facts-figures-analysis/performance-review/index_en.htm (under ‘Database for the Annual report’). However, crucially, for these more recent data it is not possible to construct deflator series at the level of sector times size-class, which hampers correct approximation of changes in size-class structure.

  5. 5.

    For more recent years the data required to construct deflator series at the level of sector times size-class are not available.

  6. 6.

    In other parts of economy (e.g., mining; electricity), interplay between small and large firms is less likely to occur.

  7. 7.

    Sector classification is based on Nace Revision 1.1.

  8. 8.

    In this paper, ‘the economy’ refers to the non-financial private sector, i.e., the aggregate of sectors D, F, G, H and I, as listed in Sect. 3.1.

  9. 9.

    Classifications by economic development level are in Appendix 2. For the ‘lower’ developed countries estimation sample we use the ‘relatively lower developed countries’ and ‘medium developed countries’ from Table 3. For the ‘higher’ developed countries estimation sample we use the ‘relatively higher developed countries’ and ‘medium developed countries’ from Table 3. As there is no obvious reason to (exclusively) include the medium developed countries with either the lower developed country sample or the higher developed country sample, we include this middle group in both estimation samples.

  10. 10.

    Standard errors are calculated using the pseudovalues approach described in Street et al. (1988).

  11. 11.

    Estimation results for each separate sector are available from the authors upon request.

References

  • Acs, Z. J., & Audretsch, D. B. (Eds.). (1993). Small firms and entrepreneurship; an East-West perspective. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Audretsch, D. B. (1995). Innovation and industry evolution. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Audretsch, D. B., Carree, M. A., Van Stel, A. J., & Thurik, A. R. (2002). Impeded industrial restructuring: The growth penalty. Kyklos, 55(1), 81–98.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Audretsch, D. B., & Keilbach, M. (2004). Entrepreneurship capital and economic performance. Regional Studies, 38(8), 949–959.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Audretsch, D. B., & Thurik, A. R. (2000). Capitalism and democracy in the 21st century: From the managed to the entrepreneurial economy. Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 10, 17–34.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Audretsch, D. B., & Thurik, A. R. (2001). What is new about the new economy: Sources of growth in the managed and entrepreneurial economies. Industrial and Corporate Change, 10, 267–315.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blanchflower, D. G. (2004). Self-employment: More may not be better. Swedish Economic Policy Review, 11(2), 15–74.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brock, W. A., & Evans, D. S. (1989). Small business economics. Small Business Economics, 1, 7–20.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carree, M. A., & Thurik, A. R. (2010). The impact of entrepreneurship on economic growth. In D. B. Audretsch & Z. J. Acs (Eds.), Handbook of entrepreneurship research (pp. 557–594). Berlin: Springer.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Carree, M. A., Van Stel, A. J., Thurik, A. R., & Wennekers, S. (2002). Economic development and business ownership: An analysis using data of 23 OECD countries in the period 1976-1996. Small Business Economics, 19, 271–290.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carree, M. A., Van Stel, A. J., Thurik, A. R., & Wennekers, S. (2007). The relationship between economic development and business ownership revisited. Entrepreneurship and Regional Development, 19(3), 281–291.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Caves, R. E. (1998). Industrial organization and new findings on the turnover and mobility of firms. Journal of Economic Literature, 36, 1947–1982.

    Google Scholar 

  • European Commission (2009). European competitiveness report 2008. Brussels: European Commission.

    Google Scholar 

  • European Commission (2010a). Europe 2020. A strategy for smart, sustainable and inclusive growth. Brussels: European Commission.

    Google Scholar 

  • European Commission (2010b). European SMEs under pressure: Annual report on EU small and medium-sized enterprises 2009. European Commission, Directorate-General for Enterprise and Industry, Report prepared by EIM Business & Policy Research.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fritsch, M., & Mueller, P. (2004). The effects of new business formation on regional development over time. Regional Studies, 38, 961–975.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Geroski, P. A. (1995). What do we know about entry? International Journal of Industrial Organization, 13, 421–441.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hamilton, L. C. (1991). srd1: How robust is robust regression? Stata Technical Bulletin (2), 21–26. Reprinted in Stata Technical Bulletin Reprints (1), 169–175. College Station, TX: Stata Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hamilton, L. C. (1992). Regression with graphics: A second course in applied statistics. Belmont, CA: Duxbury.

    Google Scholar 

  • Huber, P. J. (1964). Robust estimation of a location parameter. Annals of Mathematical Statistics, 35, 73–101.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Johnson, P. (2005). Targeting firm births and economic regeneration in a lagging region. Small Business Economics, 24, 451–464.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Li, G. (1985). Robust regression. In D. C. Hoaglin, F. Mosteller, & J. W. Tukey (Eds.), Exploring data tables, trends, and shapes (pp. 281–343). New York: Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Parker, S. C. (2007). Policymakers beware! In D. B. Audretsch, I. Grilo, & A. R. Thurik (Eds.), Handbook of research on entrepreneurship policy (pp. 54–63). Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter, J. (1934). The theory of economic development. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shane, S. (2009). Why encouraging more people to become entrepreneurs is bad public policy. Small Business Economics, 33, 141–149.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Storey, D. J. (2003). Entrepreneurship, small and medium sized enterprises and public policies. In Z. J. Acs & D. B. Audretsch (Eds.), Handbook of entrepreneurship research (pp. 473–514). Boston: Kluwer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Street, J. O., Carroll, R. J., & Ruppert, D. (1988). A note on computing robust regression estimates via iteratively reweighted least squares. American Statistician, 42(2), 152–154.

    Google Scholar 

  • Thurik, A. R., Audretsch, D. B., & Stam, E. (2013). The rise of the entrepreneurial economy and the future of dynamic capitalism. Technovation, 33(8–9), 302–310.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Van Praag, C. M., & Van Stel, A. J. (2013). The more business owners, the merrier? The role of tertiary education. Small Business Economics, 41(2), 335–357.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Van Stel, A. J. (2006). Empirical analysis of entrepreneurship and economic growth (International Studies in Entrepreneurship series, Vol. 13). New York: Springer.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Van Stel, A. J., De Vries, N. E., & De Kok, J. M. P. (2014). The effect of SME productivity increases on large firm productivity in the EU-27. Paper presented at Third GCW (‘Governance of a Complex World’) Conference, Campus Luigi Einaudi, Turin, Italy, 18–20 June 2014.

    Google Scholar 

  • Van Stel, A. J., & Suddle, K. (2008). The impact of new firm formation on regional development in the Netherlands. Small Business Economics, 30(1), 31–47.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgement

The research has been supported by the framework of the ‘Research Program on SMEs and Entrepreneurship’, financed by the Dutch Ministry of Economic Affairs. Mercedes Teruel and Jean Bonnet provided helpful comments on an earlier draft.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to André van Stel .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Appendices

Appendix 1: The Audretsch et al. (2002) Model

In this appendix we show the derivation of the Audretsch et al. (2002) model. The derivation is taken directly from their article (Audretsch et al. 2002, 88–90):

“We test the hypothesis that the extent of the gap between the actual industry structure and the optimal industry structure influences subsequent growth. We start with the assumption that a country’s growth can be decomposed into two components: (i) growth that would have occurred with an optimal industry structure, and (ii) the impact on growth occurring from any actual deviations from that optimal industry structure. This can be represented by

$$ \Delta GN{P}_{cp}=\Delta GN{P}_{cp}^{*}-\gamma \left|SF{P}_{cp-1}-SF{P}_c^{*}\right|, $$
(11)

where the dependent variable is the actual rate of economic growth. ΔGNP * cp is the rate of economic growth in country c in the case where the actual industry structure, summarized by small firm presence (SFP cp ), is at the optimal level at the start of the period p. For ease of exposition we assume that the optimal industry structure in a country remains constant for the total period under investigation. This is not vital to our analysis. Since we are considering only short-term periods, this may be a reasonable assumption.

Industry structure is multidimensional and spans a broad array of characteristics that defy measurement by a single statistic. However, as explained elsewhere (Audretsch and Thurik 2000, 2001), the most salient characteristic driving the shift in industry structure from the managed to the entrepreneurial economy is that the relative role of small and entrepreneurial firms has increased. Thus, we capture changes in industry structures by changes in the relative importance of small firms.

In Eq. (11) the parameter γ is positive. Deviations of the actual industry structure from the optimal industry structure negatively affect economic growth, both when the industry structure consists of too few or too many small firms. In either case there is a deviation from the optimal industry structure and number of small firms. Taking the first difference of Eq. (11) we obtain

$$ \Delta GN{P}_{cp}=\Delta GN{P}_{cp-1}+\Delta \Delta GN{P}_{cp}^{*}-\gamma \left(\;\left|SF{P}_{cp-1}-SF{P}_c^{*}\right|-\left|SF{P}_{cp-2}-SF{P}_c^{*}\right|\right)\;. $$
(12)

In case both \( SF{P}_{cp-1} \) and \( SF{P}_{cp-2} \) are above the optimal small-firm share, the expression between brackets reduces to \( \Delta SF{P}_{cp-1} \). Indeed, in case the small-firm share is too high, adding small firms to the industry structure reduces economic growth. In case both \( SF{P}_{cp-1} \) and \( SF{P}_{cp-2} \) are below the optimal small-firm share, the expression between brackets reduces to \( -\Delta SF{P}_{cp-1} \). An increase in the small firm share when this presence is below optimal enhances economic performance. Therefore, the sign of the parameter of \( \Delta SF{P}_{cp-1} \) reflects whether the small firm presence is below or above the optimal levels for the countries under consideration. In case the parameter is negative, the industry structure consists of too many small firms. In case the parameter is positive, the reverse holds and the industry structure consists of too few small firms.

We will denote the parameter of \( \Delta\;SF{P}_{cp-1} \) as κ. Note that this is not the same parameter as γ, since the sign of κ is dependent on whether the actual small-firm share is above or below the optimal one. So, κ can be both positive and negative whereas γ is necessarily positive.

We make some further assumptions to transform Eq. (12) into an equation that can be estimated using the data at hand. First, we approximate \( \Delta SF{P}_{cp-1} \) by \( \Delta S{F}_{cp-1}-\Delta L{F}_{cp-1} \), the difference between the growth of small firms and large firms in terms of value-of-shipments. Second, we assume that ΔGNP * cp is idiosyncratic with respect to time and country. Therefore country dummies and time dummies (the last to correct for European wide business cycle effects) are included. Thus, ΔΔGNP * cp is approximated by time dummies only because the country dummies drop out when taking first differences. Third, we add an error term e cp . Summarizing we have

$$ \Delta GN{P}_{cp}=\Delta GN{P}_{cp-1}+{\displaystyle \sum_{p=1}^P{\beta}_p{D}_p+}\kappa \left(\Delta S{F}_{cp-1}-\Delta L{F}_{cp-1}\right)+{e}_{cp}, $$
(13)

where D p denote dummy variables for periods \( p=1,\dots, P \). Factors specific to each time period are reflected by β p . A high value of this parameter indicates an unexplained increase in the extent of economic growth. In case of a low β p the reverse holds. The contribution of the shift in the size class distribution of firms to the percentage growth of GNP is represented by κ.”

Note that in the present paper we also have data at sector level. Accordingly, we assume that ΔGNP * cp is idiosyncratic with respect to time, country and sector. However, similar to the country dummies, sectoral dummies drop out when taking first differences of Eq. (11), hence ΔΔGNP * cp is approximated by time dummies only.

Appendix 2: Classification by Economic Development Level

In this appendix we provide a classification of countries based on their GNI per capita in 2005 (Table 3).

Table 3 EU-27 countries, by economic development level, 2005

Appendix 3: Robustness Test: Correcting for (the Possibility of) Reversed Causality

Table 4 presents the results of the robustness test described in Sect. 4.1. Independent variables are cleared from (contemporaneous) business cycle influences.

Table 4 Regression results Eqs. (3) and (5), correcting for reversed causalitya,b,c

Appendix 4: Correlation Matrixes by Economic Development Level

In this appendix we provide the correlation matrixes by level of economic development (Tables 5, 6, 7). The strong significant and negative correlation between the net growth of the share of large firms and the net growth of the share of SMEs is due to the definitions of the variables (see Sect. 2.1). Notice, however, that we include the net growth of the share of Small and Medium-sized Enterprises approximated by the annual percentage growth of real sales by SMEs minus the annual percentage growth of real sales by large firms and the net growth rates of the shares of micro, small, medium-sized and large firms in two different specifications.

Table 5 Correlation matrix for lower developed countries
Table 6 Correlation matrix for higher developed countries
Table 7 Correlation matrix for the general sample

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2016 Springer International Publishing Switzerland

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Albiol-Sanchez, J., van Stel, A. (2016). Investigating the Impact of Small Versus Large Firms on Economic Performance of Countries and Industries. In: Bögenhold, D., Bonnet, J., Dejardin, M., Garcia Pérez de Lema, D. (eds) Contemporary Entrepreneurship. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-28134-6_4

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics