Skip to main content

Determinants of Maximum Sustainable Government Debt

  • Chapter
Dynamic Approaches to Global Economic Challenges

Abstract

Debt ratios around the globe differ quite radically between countries. Whereas Japan has maintained a debt–GDP ratio of more than 200 % for some years, significantly lower debt ratios in Europe have caused substantial difficulties for some countries, such as Greece. Therefore, one can suspect that the reasons for this difference in sustainable debt ratios are varying magnitudes of economic variables, such as savings rates, public expenditure shares, the output elasticity of capital, and the debt ratios of main trading partners.

Farmer and Zotti (Int Rev Econ 57:289–316, 2010) showed that debt limits exist in a two-country overlapping generations (OLG) model with trade in commodities. They discovered a negative relationship between one country’s maximum government debt limits and foreign debt ratios. However, little research has been conducted on the linkage between maximum sustainable government debt limits and other economic variables, such as saving rates, productive and unproductive public expenditures, and the output elasticity of capital. Hence, the purpose of our research is to analyze the impact of these variables on maximum sustainable government debt.

Our main findings are that higher savings rates induce an increase in debt limits and we confirm that domestic debt limits are negatively related to foreign debt ratios. Both productive and unproductive government expenditures influence the maximum sustainable debt ratio negatively and, surprisingly, to the same extent. An increase in the output elasticity of private capital decreases the limit of government debt.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

eBook
USD 16.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. 1.

    Some rationales for considering productive government expenditures in the analysis of debt and debt limits are given in Schelnast (2013, p. 5ff).

  2. 2.

    The proof works very similar to that in 3.2.2.1 in Schelnast (2013). For further details, please consult the authors.

  3. 3.

    For details on the elements of the Jacobian matrix, please consult the authors.

  4. 4.

    This assumption is also applied in Rankin and Roffia (2003).

  5. 5.

    Proved in 3.2.2.1 in Schelnast (2013).

  6. 6.

    If the debt ratio is higher than the maximum sustainable one, the function F(k) never crosses k in the domain (0, k up).

  7. 7.

    The basis for this derivative is given in the Appendix.

  8. 8.

    The proof is given in the Appendix.

References

  • De la Croix D, Michel P (2002) A theory of economic growth. Dynamics and policy in overlapping generations. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Diamond PA (1965) National debt in a neoclassical growth model. Am Econ Rev 55:1135–1150

    Google Scholar 

  • Farmer K (2006) Reducing public debt under dynamic efficiency: transitional dynamics in Diamond’s OLG model. Atl Econ J 34:195–208

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Farmer K, Schelnast M (2013) Growth and international trade. An introduction to the overlapping generations approach. Springer, Berlin, Heidelberg

    Google Scholar 

  • Farmer K, Zotti J (2010) Sustainable government debt in a two-good, two-country overlapping generations model. Int Rev Econ 57:289–316

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rankin N, Roffia B (2003) Maximum sustainable government debt in the overlapping generations model. Manch Sch 71:217–241

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schelnast M (2013) Public debt: maximum sustainability and welfare effects of debt reduction in a two-country two-good diamond-type OLG model. Dissertation, University of Graz

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Anna Boisits .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Appendix

Appendix

We seek the debt ratio, \( \overline{b} \), for which only one steady state equilibrium exists. This debt ratio is called the maximum sustainable debt ratio as for a higher debt ratio there is no steady state equilibrium. Both, Eqs. (26) and (27) have to be fulfilled simultaneously. Through rearranging Eqs. (26) and (27), we obtain:

$$ {S}^1\left(k,\overline{b}\right)\equiv {A}^LF\left(k,\overline{b}\right)-{A}^Lk=\frac{1-\zeta }{\zeta}\frac{H}{H^{*}}{\varPhi}^{*}+\varPhi =0 $$
(29)

and

$$ {S}^2\left(k,\overline{b}\right)\equiv {F}_k^{\prime}\left(k,\overline{b}\right)-1=0. $$
(30)

Equation (30) equals:

$$ \left[\frac{\left(1-\zeta \right)}{\zeta }H\left({A}^L-\frac{\sigma^{*}{b}^{*}q{}^2}{\alpha^{*}}\right){k}^{\eta }+{H}^{*}k\left({A}^L-\frac{\sigma \overline{b}q{}^2}{\alpha}\right)\right]=\frac{\varPhi }{H}{A}^L\left(k{H}^{*}-{k}^{\eta }H\right), $$
(31)

which can be derived by calculating the partial derivatives F k (k, b) and using Eq. (29) to simplify terms.

Equations (29) and (30) represent a system of two equations with two unknowns, k and \( \overline{b} \). We are interested in the change in the maximum sustainable debt ratio if a parameter z, \( z\in \left\{{b}^{*},\sigma, {\sigma}^{*},\alpha, {\alpha}^{*},g,{g}^{*},u,{u}^{*}\right\} \), changes. Thus, by totally differentiating Eqs. (29) and (30), we obtain:

$$ \left[\begin{array}{cc}\hfill \frac{\partial {S}^1}{\partial k}\hfill & \hfill \frac{\partial {S}^1}{\partial \overline{b}}\hfill \\ {}\hfill \frac{\partial {S}^2}{\partial k}\hfill & \hfill \frac{\partial {S}^2}{\partial \overline{b}}\hfill \end{array}\right]\left[\begin{array}{c}\hfill \frac{\partial k}{\partial z}\hfill \\ {}\hfill \frac{\partial \overline{b}}{\partial z}\hfill \end{array}\right]=\left[\begin{array}{c}\hfill -\frac{\partial {S}^1}{\partial z}\hfill \\ {}\hfill -\frac{\partial {S}^2}{\partial z}\hfill \end{array}\right]. $$
(32)

Note that \( \partial {S}^1/\partial k={A}^L\left({F}_k^{\prime}-1\right)=0 \) because of Eq. (30). By using this fact and Cramer’s rule, the following equation then follows from Eq. (32):

$$ \frac{\partial \overline{b}}{\partial z}=-\frac{\partial {S}^1}{\partial z}/\frac{\partial {S}^1}{\partial \overline{b}}. $$
(33)

The denominator of Eq. (33) is negative and given by:

$$ \frac{\partial {S}^1}{\partial \overline{b}}=\left(-1\right)\left(\sigma q+\left(1-\sigma \right){A}^L\right)\tilde{g}{k}^{\frac{\alpha }{1-{\alpha}^G}}<0. $$
(34)

Hence, whether the maximum sustainable debt ratio decreases or increases depends on whether \( \partial {S}^1/\partial z \) is smaller or larger than zero.

First, we consider the effect on the maximum sustainable debt ratio if Foreign’s debt ratio increases. Thus, we have to calculate the partial derivative \( \partial {S}^1/\partial {b}^{*} \), which is negative:

$$ \frac{\partial {S}^1}{\partial {b}^{*}}=\frac{1-\zeta }{\zeta}\frac{H}{H^{*}}\left(-1\right)\left(\left({\sigma}^{*}q+\left(1-{\sigma}^{*}\right){A}^L\right)\frac{\alpha }{\alpha^{*}}\tilde{g}{k}^{\eta \frac{\alpha }{1-{\alpha}^G}}\right)<0. $$
(35)

Next, we consider the effects of a change in the time preference of Home’s consumption: an increase in β. If β increases, σ also increases and vice versa.

$$ \frac{\partial {S}^1}{\partial \sigma }=\left(\left(1-\alpha -\left(g+u\right)\right)-b\left(q-{A}^L\right)\right)\tilde{g}{k}^{\frac{\alpha }{1-{\alpha}^G}}>0 $$
(36)

The inequality in (36) follows from the condition that the tax rate is smaller than one. The government cannot collect more money than the workers earn. The tax rate is given by Eq. (21) and can be simplified to: \( \tau ={\left(1-\alpha \right)}^{-1}\left[b\left(q-{A}^L\right)+\left(g+u\right)\right] \) in the steady state equilibrium. From \( \tau <1 \), through rearranging terms, we obtain: \( \left(1-\alpha -\left(g+u\right)\right)-b\left(q-{A}^L\right)>0 \).

Similar argumentation leads to the following inequality:

$$ \frac{\partial {S}^1}{\partial {\sigma}^{*}}=\frac{1-\zeta }{\zeta}\frac{H}{H^{*}}\left(\left(1-{\alpha}^{*}-\left({g}^{*}+{u}^{*}\right)\right)-{b}^{*}\left({q}^{*}-{A}^L\right)\right)\frac{\alpha }{\alpha^{*}}\tilde{g}{k}^{\eta \frac{\alpha }{1-{\alpha}^G}}>0. $$
(37)

Next, we are interested in how a change in g influences the maximum sustainable debt. Thus, we need to calculate the following partial derivative:

$$ \frac{\partial {S}^1}{\partial g}=\left[\frac{\left(1-\zeta \right)}{\zeta}\frac{H}{H^{*}}{\varPhi^{*}}_g^{\prime}+\frac{\left(1-\zeta \right)}{\zeta}\frac{H_g^{\prime}{H}^{*}-H{H^{*}}_g^{\prime}}{{\left({H}^{*}\right)}^2}{\varPhi}^{*}+{\varPhi}_g^{\prime}\right]. $$
(38)

This can be rearranged by using Eq. (29) to:

$$ \begin{array}{l}\frac{\partial {S}^1}{\partial g}=\frac{1}{H^{*}}\frac{\alpha^G}{1-{\alpha}^G}\frac{1}{g}\left(\frac{\left(1-\zeta \right)}{\zeta }H\left({A}^L-\frac{\sigma^{*}}{\alpha^{*}}{b}^{*}{q}^2\right){k}^{\eta }+{H}^{*}\left({A}^L-\frac{\sigma }{\alpha }b{q}^2\right)k\right.\\ {}-\left.\frac{\varPhi }{H}{A}^L\left[k{H}^{*}-{k}^{\eta }H\right]\right)+\left(\frac{\varPhi }{H}-\sigma \right)\frac{1}{\alpha }qk.\end{array} $$
(39)

Expression (39) can be simplified using Eqs. (29) and (31):

$$ \frac{\partial {S}^1}{\partial g}=\frac{1}{\alpha }qk\left(\frac{\phi }{H}-\sigma \right). $$
(40)

Hence, the change in maximum sustainable debt caused by a change in g is given by:

$$ \frac{\partial \overline{b}}{\partial g}=-\frac{\partial {S}^1}{\partial g}/\frac{\partial {S}^1}{\partial b}=-\frac{\alpha^{-1}qk\left(\left(\phi /H\right)-\sigma \right)}{\left(-1\right)\left(\sigma q+\left(1-\sigma \right){A}^L\right)qk{\alpha}^{-1}}=\frac{\left(\left(\phi /H\right)-\sigma \right)}{\left(\sigma q+\left(1-\sigma \right){A}^L\right)}. $$
(41)

Differentiating Eq. (29) with respect to g* und using a similar simplification approach leads to:

$$ \begin{array}{l}\frac{\partial {S}^1}{\partial {g}^{*}}=\frac{1-\zeta }{\zeta}\frac{1}{\alpha^{*}}q{k}^{\eta}\frac{1}{H^{*}}\left(\frac{\phi^{*}}{H^{*}}-{\sigma}^{*}\right)=\\[6pt] {}=\frac{1-\zeta }{\zeta}\frac{1}{\alpha^{*}}q{k}^{\eta}\frac{1}{H^{*2}}\left(-\left[\frac{\sigma^{*}q+\left(1-{\sigma}^{*}\right){A}^L}{\alpha^{*}}\right]{k}^{\eta}\left({\alpha}^{*}+{b}^{*}q\right)\right)<0.\end{array} $$
(42)

The inequality holds for all non-negative debt ratios, b*.

Likewise, the partial derivative of S 1 with respect to u and u* is given by:

$$ \begin{array}{ll}\displaystyle \frac{\partial {S}^1}{\partial u}&=\left[\frac{\left(1-\zeta \right)}{\zeta}\frac{H}{H^{*}}{\varPhi^{*}}_u^{\prime}+\frac{\left(1-\zeta \right)}{\zeta}\frac{H_u^{\prime}{H}^{*}-H{H^{*}}_u^{\prime}}{{\left({H}^{*}\right)}^2}{\varPhi}^{*}+{\varPhi}_u^{\prime}\right]=\left[\frac{\varPhi }{H}-\sigma \right]\\&\quad \displaystyle \tilde{g}{k}^{\alpha /\left(1-{\alpha}^G\right)} \end{array}$$
(43)

and

$$ \begin{array}{l}\frac{\partial {S}^1}{\partial {u}^{*}}=\left[\frac{\left(1-\zeta \right)}{\zeta}\frac{H}{H^{*}}{\varPhi^{*}}_{u*}^{\prime}+\frac{\left(1-\zeta \right)}{\zeta}\frac{H_{u*}^{\prime}{H}^{*}-H{H^{*}}_{u*}^{\prime}}{{\left({H}^{*}\right)}^2}{\varPhi}^{*}+{\varPhi}_{u*}^{\prime}\right]\\ [6pt]{}=\frac{\left(1-\zeta \right)}{\zeta}\frac{H}{H^{*}}\left[\frac{\varPhi^{*}}{H^{*}}-{\sigma}^{*}\right]\frac{\alpha }{\alpha^{*}}\tilde{g}{k}^{\eta {\alpha}^{*}/\left(1-{\alpha}^{*G}\right)}.\end{array} $$
(44)

Next, we are interested in the change in maximum sustainable debt ratio if the production elasticity changes. Thus, we have to calculate the derivative of S 1 with respect to α:

$$ \begin{array}{l}\frac{\partial {S}^1}{\partial \alpha }=\left[\frac{\left(1-\zeta \right)}{\zeta}\frac{H}{H^{*}}{\varPhi^{*}}_{\alpha}^{\prime}+\frac{\left(1-\zeta \right)}{\zeta}\frac{H_{\alpha}^{\prime}{H}^{*}-H{H^{*}}_{\alpha}^{\prime}}{{\left({H}^{*}\right)}^2}{\varPhi}^{*}+{\varPhi}_{\alpha}^{\prime}\right]=\frac{1}{\alpha}\frac{1}{H}\left[\varPhi {A}^L-H{A}^L-H\sigma q\right]k\\ {}=-\frac{1}{\alpha H}\frac{qk}{\alpha}\left[\left(\sigma q+\left(1-\sigma \right){A}^L\right)\left(\left(1-\left(g+u\right)\right)+b{A}^L\right)\right]k<0\end{array} $$
(45)

The second equality follows from calculating the partial derivatives with respect to α and simplifying the term using the functional relations given in (29) and (31). This partial derivative is negative for non-negative debt ratios in Home, \( b\ge 0 \). Hence, the change in the maximum sustainable debt ratio caused by a change in the production elasticity is negative, \( \partial \overline{b}/\partial \alpha =-\left(\partial {S}^1/\partial \alpha \right)/\left(\partial {S}^1/\partial b\right) \) as both denominator and nominator are negative.

A similar approach can be used to calculate a change in the maximum sustainable debt ratio caused by a change in Foreign’s production elasticity:

$$ \begin{array}{ll} \displaystyle \frac{\partial {S}^1}{\partial {\alpha}^{*}}&=-\frac{\left(1-\zeta \right)}{\zeta}\frac{H}{H^{*2}}\frac{1}{\alpha^{*}}\frac{q{k}^{\eta }}{\alpha^{*}}\left[\left(\left(1-\left({g}^{*}+{u}^{*}\right)\right)+{b}^{*}{A}^L\right)\left({\sigma}^{*}q+\left(1-{\sigma}^{*}\right){A}^L\right)\right]\\& \quad \displaystyle {k}^{\eta }<0,\end{array} $$
(46)

where the inequality follows from a non-negative debt ratio in Foreign.

Finally, we have to show that the effects on the capital intensity are different depending on whether the government increases productive or unproductive expenditures. By using Cramer’s rule as well as (29), (31), (41), and (43), we obtain:

$$ \frac{\partial k}{\partial g}-\frac{\partial k}{\partial u}=\frac{\partial {S}^2/\partial g-\partial {S}^2/\partial u\ }{-\partial {S}^2/\partial k}=\frac{\alpha^Gk}{\left(1-{\alpha}^G-\alpha \right)g}>0. $$
(47)

Thus, in the case that the maximum sustainable debt ratio is reached, capital intensity is higher if the government invests in productive expenditures.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2016 Springer International Publishing Switzerland

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Boisits, A., Schelnast, M. (2016). Determinants of Maximum Sustainable Government Debt. In: Bednar-Friedl, B., Kleinert, J. (eds) Dynamic Approaches to Global Economic Challenges. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-23324-6_5

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics