Skip to main content

Intangible Assets and a Theory of Heterogeneous Firms

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Intangibles, Market Failure and Innovation Performance

Abstract

This article outlines a capabilities-enriched economic theory of the firm and its sources of competitive advantage. The nature and key categories of intangibles are discussed, with an emphasis on their suitability for providing differentiation in an era when so many services and tangible goods are readily available on a global basis. The linkages in the conversion of intangibles into profits are analyzed, including the frequent need for co-specialized complements. Among the key categories of intangibles are organizational capabilities, which can be either ordinary or dynamic. Ordinary capabilities are, generally, those that can be measured against best practice and with some effort, imitated by rivals. Dynamic capabilities, which reside in both signature processes and management skills, allow the enterprise and its top management to develop conjectures about the evolution of consumer preferences, business problems, markets, and technology; validate them; and realign assets and competences to enable continuous innovation for the creation of competitive advantage. The key concepts of complementarity, entrepreneurial management, and dynamic capabilities are then applied to deepening the economic theory of the firm, combining with the dominant transaction cost approach to provide a richer understanding of why firms are needed in the economic system.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 84.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. 1.

    Needless to say, through land use and other controls, national governments and local authorities can dramatically impair the value of real estate by limiting its use.

  2. 2.

    Business models in their entirety are generally not protected by intellectual property rights. Certain elements of a model might qualify for patent or copyright protection.

  3. 3.

    The VRIN criteria discussed earlier tend to overlook this point, i.e., the V of VRIN is likely to be highly context dependent.

  4. 4.

    The leaked Nokia memo was widely reproduced online. See, for example, http://www.engadget.com/2011/02/08/nokia-ceo-stephen-elop-rallies-troops-in-brutally-honest-burnin/ (accessed December 26, 2013).

  5. 5.

    Mansfield et al. (1981) found that about 60% of the patented innovations in their sample were imitated within four years. In a later study, Mansfield (1985) found that information concerning product and process development decisions was generally in the hands of at least several rivals within 12–18 months, on average, after the decision was made. Process development decisions tend to leak out more than product development decisions in practically all industries, but the average difference was found to be less than 6 months.

  6. 6.

    For a review of the literature on complementarity and the related mathematical concept of supermodularity, see Ennen and Richter (2010).

  7. 7.

    Langlois (1992) defines dynamic transaction costs as “the costs of persuading, negotiating, coordinating and teaching outside suppliers” (1992: 113).

  8. 8.

    See Bloom and Van Reenen (2007) for a notable exception to the virtual exclusion of firm-specific managerial practices from the economics literature.

  9. 9.

    This section draws on material in Al-Aali and Teece (2014).

References

  • Abernathy, W. J., & Utterback, J. M. (1978). Patterns of industrial innovation. Technology Review, 80(7), 40–47.

    Google Scholar 

  • Adner, R., & Helfat, C. E. (2003). Corporate effects and dynamic managerial capabilities. Strategic Management Journal, 24(10), 1011–1025.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Al-Aali, A., & Teece, D. J. (2014). International entrepreneurship and the theory of the (long-lived) international firm: A capabilities perspective. Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, 38(1), 95–116.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alvarez, S. A., & Barney, J. B. (2007). Discovery and creation: Alternative theories of entrepreneurial action. Strategic Entrepreneurship Journal, 1(1–2), 11–26.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Armour, H. O., & Teece, D. J. (1978). Organizational structure and economic performance: A test of the multidivisional hypothesis. Bell Journal of Economics, 9(18), 106–122.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barney, J. B. (1986). Organizational culture: Can it be a source of sustained competitive advantage? Academy of Management Review, 11(3), 656–665.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barney, J. B. (1991). Firm resources and sustained competitive advantage. Journal of Management, 17(1), 99–120.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bloom, N., Eifert, B., Mahajan, A., McKenzie, D., & Roberts, J. (2013). Does management matter? Evidence from India. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 128(1), 1–51.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bloom, N., & Van Reenen, J. (2007). Measuring and explaining management practices across firms and countries. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 122(4), 1351–1408.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boudreaux, D. J., & Holcombe, R. G. (1989). The Coasian and Knightian theories of the firm. Managerial and Decision Economics, 10(2), 147–154.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chesbrough, H., & Rosenbloom, R. S. (2002). The role of the business model in capturing value from innovation: Evidence from Xerox Corporation’s technology spin-off companies. Industrial and Corporate Change, 11(3), 529–555.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coase, R. (1937). The nature of the firm. Economica, 4(16), 386–405.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ennen, E., & Richter, A. (2010). The whole is more than the sum of its parts—or is it? A review of the empirical literature on complementarities in organizations. Journal of Management, 36(1), 207–233.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Feiler, P., & Teece, D. (forthcoming). Case study: Dynamic capabilities and upstream strategy: Supermajor EXP. Energy Strategy Reviews.

    Google Scholar 

  • Foss, K., Foss, N. J., Klein, P. G., & Klein, S. K. (2007). The entrepreneurial organization of heterogeneous capital. Journal of Management Studies, 44(7), 1165–1186.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Foss, N. J., Klein, P. G., Kor, Y. Y., & Mahoney, J. T. (2008). Entrepreneurship, subjectivism, and the resource-based view: Toward a new synthesis. Strategic Entrepreneurship Journal, 2(1), 73–94.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Friedman, T. L. (2005). The world is flat: A brief history of the twenty-first century. New York: Farrar, Straus and Giroux.

    Google Scholar 

  • Garvin, D. A. (2013). How Google sold its engineers on management. Harvard Business Review, 91(12), 74–82.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ghemawat, P. (2003). Semiglobalization and international business strategy. Journal of International Business Studies, 34(2), 138–152.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gratton, L., & Ghoshal, S. (2005). Beyond best practice. MIT Sloan Management Review, 46(3), 49–57.

    Google Scholar 

  • Greenspan, A. (2004, February 27). Remarks on intellectual property rights. Paper presented at the Stanford Institute for Economic Policy Research Economic Summit, Stanford, CA. Available at Federal Reserve Board. Accessed April 28, 2010, from http://www.federalreserve.gov/boarddocs/speeches/2004/200402272/default.htm

  • IFRS. (2012). IAS 38 intangible assets. International Financial Reporting Standards Foundation. Retrieved December 10, 2013, from http://www.ifrs.org/IFRSs/IFRS-technical-summaries/Documents/IAS38-English.pdf

  • Jacobides, M. G., & Winter, S. G. (2012). Capabilities: Structure, agency, and evolution. Organization Science, 23(5), 1365–1381.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jensen, M. C. (2000). A theory of the firm: Governance, residual claims, and organizational forms. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kirzner, I. M. (1985). Discovery and the capitalist process. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Knight, F. (1921). Risk, uncertainty and profit. New York: Augustus Kelley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kraemer, K. L., Dedrick, J., & Yamashiro, S. (2000). Refining and extending the business model with information technology: Dell Computer Corporation. Information Society, 16(1), 5–21.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Langlois, R. N. (1992). Transaction-cost economics in real time. Industrial and Corporate Change, 1(1), 99–127.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leibenstein, H. (1966). Allocative efficiency vs. “X-inefficiency”. American Economic Review, 56(3), 392–419.

    Google Scholar 

  • Levin, R. C., Klevorick, A. K., Nelson, R. R., Winter, S. G., Gilbert, R., & Griliches, Z. (1987). Appropriating the returns from industrial research and development. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1987(3), 783–831.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lippman, S. A., & Rumelt, R. P. (1982). Uncertain imitability: An analysis of inter-firm differences in efficiency under competition. Bell Journal of Economics, 13(2), 418–438.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mansfield, E. (1985). How rapidly does new industrial technology leak out? Journal of Industrial Economics, 34(2), 217–223.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mansfield, E., Schwartz, M., & Wagner, S. (1981). Imitation costs and patents: An empirical study. Economic Journal, 91(364), 907–918.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Milgrom, P., & Roberts, J. (1990a). The economics of modern manufacturing: Technology, strategy, and organization. American Economic Review, 80(3), 511–528.

    Google Scholar 

  • Milgrom, P., & Roberts, J. (1990b). Rationalizability, learning and equilibrium in games with strategic complementarities. Econometrics, 58(6), 1255–1277.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Miller, D. (1988). Relating Porter’s business strategies to environment and structure: Analysis and performance implications. Academy of Management Journal, 31(2), 280–308.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Monteverde, K., & Teece, D. J. (1982). Supplier switching costs and vertical integration in the automobile industry. Bell Journal of Economics, 13(1), 206–213.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Morgan, N. A., Vorhies, D. W., & Mason, C. H. (2009). Market orientation, marketing capabilities, and firm performance. Strategic Management Journal, 30(8), 909–920.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • O’Reilly, C. A., & Tushman, M. L. (2004). The ambidextrous organization. Harvard Business Review, 82(4), 74–81.

    Google Scholar 

  • O’Reilly, C. A., & Tushman, M. L. (2008). Ambidexterity as a dynamic capability: Resolving the innovator’s dilemma. Research in Organizational Behavior, 28, 185–206.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Parmigiani, A., & Mitchell, W. (2009). Complementarity, capabilities, and the boundaries of the firm: The impact of within-firm and interfirm expertise on concurrent sourcing of complementary components. Strategic Management Journal, 30(10), 1065–1091.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Penrose, E. T. (1959). The theory of the growth of the firm. New York: Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pisano, G., & Teece, D. J. (2007). How to capture value from innovation: Shaping intellectual property and industry architecture. California Management Review, 50(1), 278–296.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pitelis, C. N., & Teece, D. J. (2010). Cross-border market co-creation, dynamic capabilities and the entrepreneurial theory of the multinational enterprise. Industrial and Corporate Change, 19(4), 1247–1270.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ries, E. (2011). The lean startup: How today’s entrepreneurs use continuous innovation to create radically successful businesses. New York: Crown Business.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rosenberg, N. (1979). Technological interdependence in the American economy. Technology and Culture, 20(1), 25–50.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rosenberg, N. (1982). Inside the black box: Technology and economics. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rumelt, R. P., Schendel, D., & Teece, D. J. (1991). Strategic management and economics. Strategic Management Journal, 12(Winter Special Issue), 5–29.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sarasvathy, S. D., Dew, N., Velamuri, S. R., & Venkataraman, S. (2003). Three views of entrepreneurial opportunity. In Z. J. Acs & D. B. Audretsch (Eds.), Handbook of entrepreneurship research: An interdisciplinary survey and introduction (pp. 141–160). Dordrecht, The Netherlands: Kluwer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sautet, F. E. (2000). An entrepreneurial theory of the firm. London: Routledge.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Sherry, E. F., & Teece, D. J. (2004). Royalties, evolving patent rights, and the value of innovation. Research Policy, 33(2), 179–191.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Somaya, D., Teece, D., & Wakeman, S. (2011). Innovation in multi-invention contexts: Mapping solutions to technological and intellectual property complexity. California Management Review, 53(4), 47–79.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Teece, D. J. (1980). Economies of scope and the scope of the enterprise. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 1(3), 223–247.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Teece, D. J. (1981). The market for know-how and the efficient international transfer of technology. Annals of the Academy of Political and Social Science, 458(1), 81–96.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Teece, D. J. (1984). Economic analysis and strategic management. California Management Review, 26(3), 87–110.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Teece, D. J. (1986). Profiting from technological innovation. Research Policy, 15(6), 285–305.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Teece, D. J. (2000). Managing intellectual capital: Organizational, strategic, and policy dimensions. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Teece, D. J. (2005). Technology and technology transfer: Mansfieldian inspirations and subsequent developments. Journal of Technology Transfer, 30(1–2), 17–33.

    Google Scholar 

  • Teece, D. J. (2006). Reflections on profiting from innovation. Research Policy, 35(8), 1131–1146.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Teece, D. J. (2007). Explicating dynamic capabilities: The nature and microfoundations of (sustainable) enterprise performance. Strategic Management Journal, 28(13), 1319–1350.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Teece, D. J. (2010). Business models, business strategy and innovation. Long Range Planning, 43(2–3), 172–194.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Teece, D. J. (2014). A dynamic capabilities-based entrepreneurial theory of the multinational enterprise. Journal of International Business Studies, 45(1), 8–37.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Teece, D. J., Pisano, G., & Shuen, A. (1997). Dynamic capabilities and strategic management. Strategic Management Journal, 18(7), 509–533.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wernerfelt, B. (1984). A resource-based view of the firm. Strategic Management Journal, 5(2), 171–180.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Williamson, O. E. (1971). The vertical integration of production: Market failure considerations. American Economic Review, 61(2), 112–123.

    Google Scholar 

  • Williamson, O. E. (1975). Markets and hierarchies: Analysis and antitrust implications. New York: Free Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Williamson, O. E. (1985). The economic institutions of capitalism. New York: Free Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Williamson, O. E. (1999). Some reflections. In G. R. Carroll & D. J. Teece (Eds.), Firms, markets, and hierarchies: The transaction cost economics perspective (pp. 32–36). New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Womack, J. P., Jones, D. T., & Roos, D. (1990). The machine that changed the world: Based on the Massachusetts Institute of Technology 5-million dollar 5-year study on the future of the automobile. New York: Rawson.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgement

I wish to thank Greg Linden for comments and help in editing.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to David J. Teece .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2015 Springer International Publishing Switzerland

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Teece, D.J. (2015). Intangible Assets and a Theory of Heterogeneous Firms. In: Bounfour, A., Miyagawa, T. (eds) Intangibles, Market Failure and Innovation Performance. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-07533-4_9

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics