Skip to main content

The Myth of Money as a Veil

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Financial Markets in Perspective

Part of the book series: Springer Studies in the History of Economic Thought ((SSHET))

  • 714 Accesses

Abstract

This chapter focuses on the rise and fall of the twin ideas-myths of money as a veil and the invisible hand of the market. First, Middle Ages metallistic theory is considered. It is stressed that not all classical economists shared (Adam Smith’s and David Ricardo’s) “received view,” including the international trade Hume mechanism; as an example, reference is made to Antonio Serra and William Petty. The “analytical bricks” methodology of the classical economists is referred to, showing that the classical notion of money as a veil is compatible with the idea of an influence of the monetary on the real economy. The connection between the notion of money as a veil and the myth of the invisible hand of the market in neoclassical/marginalist economics is then explored. Finally, two pillars of a reconstructed modern monetary theory are considered: the Keynesian notions of uncertainty and liquidity preference and Minsky’s money manager economy. The new paradigm may be summarized in three points: money and finance cannot be kept separate and crucially affect the real economy; the Keynesian notions of uncertainty and liquidity preference constitute the foundations on which theorizing over money and finance should rely; the role of finance increases over time, with a change of regime to a “money manager capitalism.”

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 139.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 179.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 179.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. 1.

    For a general illustration of this point, cf. Roncaglia (2019).

  2. 2.

    For examples of imaginary money largely utilized in the late sixteenth and early seventeenth centuries, cf. Rosselli (1995, p. 42) and Goldsmith (1990, p. 246).

  3. 3.

    Schumpeter ([1954] 1994, pp. 277–278) hints in this direction.

  4. 4.

    Ricardo’s great intelligence is fully policy-oriented: we should keep in mind that the professionalization of economics is far off in the future, and the method of axiomatic theoretical models (Bourbaki) is still farther off. Sraffa, as great an admirer of Ricardo as we might desire, commented (in answer to some queries by Gramsci), “Ricardo was, and always remained, a stockbroker with a mediocre culture” (Sraffa, 1991, p. 74, my translation). In fact, it was James Mill who pushed his friend David to write the Principles and give them a relatively compact structure.

  5. 5.

    We should also keep in mind the role of usury laws in determining interest rates or at least maximum ceilings for them. On usury laws, cf. Tawney (1926).

  6. 6.

    “An alteration in the value of money has no effect on the relative value of commodities, for it raises or sinks their price in the same proportion” (Ricardo, 1951–1955, vol. 2, p. 396: quite explicit but the only explicit reference I was able to find). At the same time, as Hollander (1979, p. 480) remarks, Ricardo stresses that in the transitory periods required for full adjustment after a change in the quantity of money, such effects are possible, indeed likely.

  7. 7.

    On Serra’s monetary theory, cf. Rosselli (1995).

  8. 8.

    As a consequence, the main policy target is equality between the market and the official price of gold (cf. Marcuzzo & Rosselli, 1991).

  9. 9.

    For instance, in traditional oil or gas deals, both payments and commodity consignments may extend over years, even for decades, giving rise to financial derivatives.

  10. 10.

    Let us recall the controversies between bullionists and anti-bullionists and then between the currency and the banking schools. With the development of banking, a precise definition of money, so as to make it fully exogenous, becomes more difficult to attain. It requires either focusing on coins (commodity money) or relying on a univocal relation between convertible bank notes and the underlying metallic reserves. Tooke’s banking school rejects this tenet (cf. Arnon (1991), who also remarks that other classical authors do not strictly adhere to rigorous definitions of money; cf., e.g., p. 23 on Adam Smith).

  11. 11.

    Of course, this equality only holds when international relations and the public sector are assumed away.

  12. 12.

    Cf., for instance, Blaug, 1997, pp. 157 ff.

  13. 13.

    Things become more complex with the increasing complexity of the national and international monetary and financial markets. Hawtrey’s “Treasury View” with his adhesion to the loanable funds theory depends on his tenet of a separation between monetary and (long-term) financial markets (already criticized by Keynes) and is strictly speaking only valid for a stationary economy (cf. Tonveronachi, 2019).

  14. 14.

    On the method of “analytical bricks,” applied to the interpretation of Sraffa’s analysis, cf. Roncaglia (2009b, in particular pp. 25–28 and 49–51).

  15. 15.

    In fact, Modigliani and Miller (1958, p. 197), after stressing the assumption of perfect competition (and, earlier on, of certainty), call for a follow-up to their analysis where the simplifying assumptions could be abandoned. The preference for internal financing in more realistic analyses is stressed by post-Keynesian economists (Eichner, 1976 and others) who build on this foundation a theory of income distribution whereby investments determine financing requirements and hence pricing decisions, profits, and the profit rate.

  16. 16.

    Some mainstream economists (for instance, Blanchard & Summers, 2019) recently appear to be reconsidering their policy standing but without putting in doubt their theoretical foundations.

  17. 17.

    This important methodological element is often forgotten in financial risk analysis, with serious consequences in the setting of regulatory capital requirements for financial institutions (cf. Roncaglia, 2012).

  18. 18.

    Actually, my talk lasted 43′25″.

  19. 19.

    There is an analogy here with Keynes’s notion of “groups” proposed in the Treatise of Probability (Keynes, 1973, p. 134). On this, cf. Roncaglia (2009a, p. 498).

References

  • Arnon, A. (1991). Thomas Tooke. Pioneer of monetary theory. Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Blanchard, O., & Summers, L. H. (2019). Evolution or revolution? Rethinking macroeconomic policy after the Great Recession. MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Blaug, M. ([1962] 1997). Economic theory in retrospect. Richard Irwin. 5th edition, Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • de Finetti, B. (1931). Probabilismo. Saggio critico sulla probabilità e sul valore della scienza. Perrella.

    Google Scholar 

  • Eichner, A. S. (1976). The megacorp and oligopoly. Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fama, E. (1970). Efficient capital markets: A review of theory and empirical work. Journal of Finance, 25(2), 383–417.

    Google Scholar 

  • Goldsmith, R. W. (1990). Sistemi finanziari premoderni. Laterza.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hollander, S. (1979). The economics of David Ricardo. Toronto: University of Toronto Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Marcuzzo, M. C., & Rosselli, A. (1991). Ricardo and the gold standard. The foundations of international monetary order. Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Keynes, J.M. ([1921] 1973). A treatise on probability. Macmillan. As reprinted in The collected writings of John Maynard Keynes, vol. 8. Ed. by D. Moggridge. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press for the Royal Economic Society.

    Google Scholar 

  • Modigliani, F. (1944). Liquidity preference and the theory of interest and money. Econometrica, 12(1), 45–88.

    Google Scholar 

  • Modigliani, F. (1963). The monetary mechanism and its interaction with real phenomena. Review of Economics and Statistics, 45(supplement), 79–107.

    Google Scholar 

  • Modigliani, F., & Miller, M. (1958). The cost of capital, corporation finance and the theory of investment. American Economic Review, 48(3), 261–297.

    Google Scholar 

  • Petty, W. ([1691] 1899). Verbum sapienti. In appendix to W. Petty, The political anatomy of Ireland. D. Brown and W. Rogers. As reprinted in The economic writings of Sir William Petty. Ed. by C. Hull, vol. 1 (pp. 99–120). Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pigou, A. C. (1933). The theory of unemployment. Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pigou, A. C. (1941). Employment and equilibrium. Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ramsey, F. (1931). The foundations of mathematics. Routledge and Kegan Paul.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ricardo, D. (1951–55). Works and correspondence. 10 vols. Ed. by P. Sraffa. Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Roncaglia, A. (2005). The wealth of ideas. Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Roncaglia, A. (2009a). Keynes and probability: An assessment. European Journal of the History of Economic Thought, 16(3), 485–510.

    Google Scholar 

  • Roncaglia, A. (2009b). Piero Sraffa. Palgrave Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Roncaglia, A. (2012). Keynesian uncertainty and the shaky foundations of statistical risk assessment models. PSL Quarterly Review, 65(263), 437–454.

    Google Scholar 

  • Roncaglia, A. (2019). The age of fragmentation. A history of contemporary economic thought. Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Roncaglia, A., & Tonveronachi, M. (1985). The pre-Keynesian roots of the neoclassical synthesis. Cahiers d’économie politique, 10(11), 51–65.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rosselli, A. (1995). Antonio Serra e la teoria dei cambi. In A. Roncaglia (Ed.), Alle origini del pensiero economico in Italia (Moneta e sviluppo negli economisti napoletani dei secoli XVII–XVIII) (Vol. 1, pp. 37–58). Il Mulino.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rothschild, E. (1994). Adam Smith and the invisible hand. American Economic Review. Papers and Proceedings, 84(2), 319–322.

    Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson, P. A. (1948). Economics. McGraw Hill.

    Google Scholar 

  • Savage, L. J. (1954). The foundations of statistics. Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter J. (1954). History of economic analysis. Ed. by E. Boody Schumpeter. Oxford University Press. Reprinted (1994). Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Serra, A. (1613). Breve trattato delle cause che possono far abbondare li regni d’oro e d’argento dove non sono miniere con applicazione al Regno di Napoli. L. Scorriggio. Reprinted (1994). Verlag Wirtschaft und Finanzen GmbH.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sraffa, P. (1991). Lettere a Tania per Gramsci. Editori Riuniti.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stigler, G. J. (1951). The division of labor is limited by the extent of the market. Journal of Political Economy, 59(3), 185–193.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tawney, R.H. (1926). Introduction. In T. Wilson (1572). A discourse upon usurye. Ed. by R.H. Tawney. Bell. Reprinted (1963). Frank Cass.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tonveronachi, M. (2019). Ages of financial instability. Paper presented at the Fifth Thomas Guggenheim conference in the history of economic thought Financial instability, market disruptions and macroeconomics: Lessons from economic history and the history of economic thought. Rome, Accademia Nazionale dei Lincei, 17–18 December.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tucker, G. (1960). Progress and profits in British economic thought 1650–1850. Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wood, D. (2002). Medieval economic thought. Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

Thanks (but no implication) are due to Carlo D’Ippoliti, Jan Kregel, Cristina Marcuzzo, Annalisa Rosselli, and Mario Tonveronachi for comments on a previous draft.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Alessandro Roncaglia .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2022 The Author(s), under exclusive license to Springer Nature Switzerland AG

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Roncaglia, A. (2022). The Myth of Money as a Veil. In: Arnon, A., Marcuzzo, M.C., Rosselli, A. (eds) Financial Markets in Perspective. Springer Studies in the History of Economic Thought. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-86753-9_1

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics