Skip to main content

The Permanent-Transitory Confusion: Implications for Tests of Market Efficiency and for Expected Inflation During Turbulent and Tranquil Times

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Expectations

Abstract

Even when all past and present information is known, individuals usually remain uncertain about the permanence of observed variables. After reviewing the history and role of adaptive expectations and its statistical foundations in modeling this permanent-transitory confusion, the paper investigates the consequences of this confusion for tests of market efficiency in the treasury bill and foreign exchange markets. A central result is that the detection of serial correlation in efficiency tests based on finite samples does not necessarily imply that markets are inefficient. The second part of the paper utilizes data on Israeli inflation expectations from the capital market to estimate the implicit speed of learning about changes in inflation and to examine the performance of adaptive expectations in tracking the evolution of those expectations during the 1985 shock stabilization as well as during the stable inflation targeting period.

6 August 2018

Personal note on the history of the paper by Alex Cukierman

The origin of this paper goes back to an old unpublished manuscript by Cukierman and Meltzer (1982). A couple of years before that time Karl Brunner and Allan Meltzer became aware of the importance of the permanent-transitory confusion. I first discovered the universality of this confusion for the formation of expectations and for economic behavior when, as a visiting scholar at Carnegie-Mellon during the end of the seventies and beginning of the eighties, I started to interact with Allan and Karl on this topic. This interaction culminated in a number of joint published papers. The Cukierman and Meltzer (1982) paper was a later spinoff of this research effort and was never completed mainly because the research attention of both Allan and myself had turned to other topics and I had returned to Tel-Aviv.

But I always felt that the ideas in our unpublished manuscript are sufficiently important to justify bringing it up to date and amplifying its message with empirical work. This is particularly important for younger generations of economists who, due to the early criticism by the rational expectation school that adaptive expectations are not rational, might not be aware of the fact that Muth (1960) provided a statistical foundation for the permanent-transitory confusion in which adaptive expectations are rational.

When the organizers of the conference on “Expectations: Theory and applications in historical perspectives” suggested I write a paper for the conference I felt the time had come to do that. Unfortunately, on May 8, 2017, my long-time friend and collaborator Allan Meltzer passed away.

My young collaborator, Thomas Lustenberger, joined me in this effort. The current updated and expanded version of the paper integrates the analysis in the original manuscript with some newer empirical work. Beyond the personal loss I feel along with Allan’s family, the history of the paper is one illustration of the process through which the research torch is being passed across generations of economists. I view it as a personal token of appreciation to Allan Meltzer who had a major influence on my professional life.

Allan Meltzer passed away on May 8 2017.

This research project was conducted while Thomas Lustenberger was affiliated with the Swiss National Bank and the University of Basel.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 129.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 169.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 169.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    Although this article is relatively less known (and quoted) than Muth (1961), Econometrica article that inspired the rational expectations revolution in macroeconomics its contribution is, nonetheless, not less important.

  2. 2.

    Statistically minded readers may note that this optimal predictor is the expected value of yt+j, j ≥ 1 conditional on the information set, It ≡ {yt, yt−1, yt−2, …}. Due to the normality assumption, this conditional expected value is linear in the elements of the conditioning set and the weights are those that minimize the variance of forecasts around this expected value.

  3. 3.

    A compact useful presentation of the Kalman filter appears in Chapter 21 of Ljungqvist and Sargent (2000).

  4. 4.

    Fama and others subsequently extended the test to fluctuating real rates. The central point of the next section applies to those extensions as well.

  5. 5.

    For simplicity of exposition, we focus in the text on the one period ahead forward premium as a predictor of the change in the exchange rate between the current and the next period. However, all the discussion that follows in the text also applies to the k periods ahead forward premium. In this case, Eq. (7) is simply replaced by

    $$ s_{t + k} - s_{t} = \alpha + \beta \left( {f_{t + k} - s_{t} } \right) + u_{t + k} . $$
  6. 6.

    This equation is the canonical regression used in the voluminous literature on the forward premium puzzle. See Chinn (2009), Eq. (2) and the adjoining discussion. Early formulations of the test were done in levels rather than in actual and expected rates of change (Frenkel (1977) and Frenkel (1979)).

  7. 7.

    Subsequent literature such as Fama (1984) recognized the potential existence of risk aversion by introducing a risk premium into regression (7). A survey of this literature appears in Engel (1996).

  8. 8.

    As was the case before the estimate of β0 = c0, provides an estimate of minus the (assumed) constant real rate of interest.

  9. 9.

    Details appear in Sect. 1 of the Appendix.

  10. 10.

    It is likely that this is the case also for higher-order covariances between forecast errors.

  11. 11.

    Note that, since it depends on a particular realization of the innovation to the permanent component, ρj(∆ypt) is not necessarily smaller than one.

  12. 12.

    A detailed description of the 1985 stabilization appears in Bruno and Piterman (1988).

  13. 13.

    A detailed description of the convergence process and other details appear in Cukierman and Melnick (2015).

  14. 14.

    One example is Chapter 21 of Ljungqvist and Sargent (2000).

  15. 15.

    Furthermore, as demonstrated by Friedman (1979), serial correlation may also arise when a slope coefficient of an economic model changes permanently. The reason is that an econometrician using least square becomes aware of the change only gradually as post-change observations cumulate over time.

  16. 16.

    This conclusion is consistent with results obtained in Cukierman and Melnick (2015).

References

  • Barro, R. J., & Gordon, D. B. (1983). A positive theory of monetary policy in a natural rate model. Journal of Political Economy, 91(4), 589–610.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brunner, K., Cukierman, A., & Meltzer, A. H. (1980). Stagflation, persistent unemployment and the permanence of economic shocks. Journal of Monetary Economics, 6, 467–492.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bruno, M., & Piterman, S. (1988). Israel’s stabilization: A two-years review. In M. Bruno, G. Di Tella, R. Dornbusch, & S. Fischer (Eds.), Inflation stabilization: The experience of Israel, Argentina, Brazil, Bolivia and Mexico. Cambridge MA and London: The MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cagan, P. D. (1956). The monetary dynamics of hyper-inflation. In M. Friedman (Ed.), Studies in the quantity theory of money. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chinn, M. D. (2009). Forward premium puzzle. In K. A. Reinert & R. S. Rajan (Eds.), Princeton encyclopedia of the world economy. Princeton and Oxford: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cukierman, A. (1982). Relative price variability, inflation and the allocative efficiency of the price system. Journal of Monetary Economics, 9, 131–162.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cukierman, A. (1988). The end of the high Israeli inflation: An experiment in heterodox stabilization. In M. Bruno, G. Di Tella, R. Dornbusch, & S. Fischer (Eds.), Inflation stabilization: The experience of Israel, Argentina, Brazil, Bolivia and Mexico. Cambridge MA and London: The MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cukierman, A., & Melnick, R. (2015). The conquest of Israeli inflation and current policy dilemmas. In A. Offenbacher (Ed.), Maintaining price stability: The Bank of Israel’s sixth decade (pp. 13–62).

    Google Scholar 

  • Cukierman, A., & Meltzer, A. H. (1982). What do tests of market efficiency show? Unpublished manuscript, Carnegie-Mellon University.

    Google Scholar 

  • Engel, C. (1996). The forward discount anomaly and the risk premium: A survey of recent evidence. Journal of Empirical Finance, 3, 123–192.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fama, E. F. (1975). Short-term interest rates as predictors of inflation. The American Economic Review, 65(3), 269–282.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fama, E. F. (1984). Forward and spot exchange rates. Journal of Monetary Economics, 14, 319–338.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Figlewski, S., & Wachtel, P. (1981). The formation of inflationary expectations. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 63(1), 1–10.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fisher, I. (1911). The purchasing power of money. Macmillan, New York (latest edition, A.M. Kelley, New York, 1963).

    Google Scholar 

  • Fisher, I. (1930). The theory of interest. New York: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Frankel, J., & Poonawala, J. (2006). The forward market in emerging currencies: Less biased than in major currencies. NBER Working Paper Series 12496.

    Google Scholar 

  • Frenkel, J. A. (1977). The forward exchange rate, expectations, and the demand for money: The German hyperinflation. The American Economic Review, 67(4), 653–670.

    Google Scholar 

  • Frenkel, J. A. (1979). Further evidence on expectations and the demand for money during the German hyperinflation. Journal of Monetary Economics, 5, 81–96.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Friedman, M. (1957). A theory of the consumption function. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Friedman, B. M. (1979). Optimal expectations and the extreme information assumptions of ‘rational expectations’ macromodels. Journal of Monetary Economics, 5, 23–42.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hamburger, M. J., & Platt, E. N. (1975). The expectations hypothesis and the efficiency of the trasury bill market. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 57(2), 190–199.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kalman, R. E. (1960). A new approach to linear filtering and prediction problems. Transactions of the ASME—Journal of Basic Engineering, 85(Series D), 35–45.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ljungqvist, L., & Sargent, T. J. (2000). Recursive macroeconomic theory. Cambridge MA and London: The MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lucas, R. E. (1972). Econometric testing of the natural rate hypothesis. In O. Eckstein (Ed.), The econometrics of price determination. Washington D.C.: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lucas, R. E. (1973). Some international evidence on output-inflation tradeoffs. The American Economic Review, 63(3), 326–334.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lucas, R. E., & Rapping, L. A. (1969). Real wages, employment and inflation. Journal of Political Economy, 77(5), 721–754.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Muth, J. F. (1960). Optimal properties of exponentially weighted forecasts. Journal of the American Statistical Association, 55(290), 299–306.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Muth, J. F. (1961). Rational expectations and the theory of price movements. Econometrica, 29(3), 315–335.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

We benefited from useful discussions on tests of market efficiency in the foreign exchange market with Menzie Chinn. The views expressed in this paper are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily reflect those of the SNB.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Alex Cukierman .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Appendix

Appendix

1.1 Derivation of Equation (15)

Inserting Eq. (3) into Eq. (14) for all t

$$ u_{t + 1} = y_{t + 1}^{p} + y_{t + 1}^{q} - \sum\limits_{i = 0}^{\infty } \theta (1 - \theta )^{i} \left( {y_{t - i}^{p} + y_{t - i}^{q} } \right). $$

Grouping all the transitory terms into one expression and all the first differences of the random walk component into another expression and rearranging

$$ u_{t + 1} = Q_{t + 1} + P_{t + 1} $$

where Qt+1 and Pt+1 are given by Eq. (18) in the text. QED.

1.2 Proof that Eut+1ut = 0

It is convenient to first prove the following Lemma

Lemma 1

\( (1 - \theta )\sigma_{p}^{2} - \theta^{2} \sigma_{q}^{2} = 0 \)

  • Proof Rearranging Eq. (4) in the text

$$ \theta + \frac{a}{2} = \sqrt {a + \frac{{a^{2} }}{4}} . $$

Raising both sides of this equation to second power, cancelling terms and noting that \( a \equiv \frac{{\sigma_{p}^{2} }}{{\sigma_{q}^{2} }} \)

$$ \theta^{2} = \frac{{\sigma_{p}^{2} }}{{\sigma_{q}^{2} }}(1 - \theta ). $$

The proof is completed by moving \( \sigma_{q}^{2} \) to the left hand side of this equation.

Since all the terms in Pt+1 are statistically independent from the terms in Qt+1

$$ Eu_{t + 1} u_{t} = EQ_{t + 1} Q_{t} + EP_{t + 1} P_{t} . $$
(26)

Using the definitions of Qt+1 and of Pt+1 from Eq. (18) in the text, it can be shown after some tedious algebra that

$$ EQ_{t + 1} Q_{t} = - \frac{{\theta \sigma_{q}^{2} }}{2 - \theta }, $$
(27)
$$ EP_{t + 1} P_{t} = \frac{{\sigma_{p}^{2} (1 - \theta )}}{\theta (2 - \theta )}. $$
(28)

Substituting those expressions into Eq. (26)

$$ Eu_{t + 1} u_{t} = \frac{{(1 - \theta )\sigma_{p}^{2} - \theta^{2} \sigma_{q}^{2} }}{\theta (2 - \theta )}. $$

By Lemma 1, the numerator of this expression is zero. Since the denominator is positive Eut+1ut = 0. QED

1.3 Derivation of ρj(∆Ypt) (Eq. 20)

From Eq. (15) in the text,

$$ E\left[ {u_{t + j + 1} u_{t + j} |\varDelta y_{t}^{p} } \right] = EQ_{t + 1} Q_{t} + E\left[ {P_{t + j + 1} P_{t + j} |\varDelta y_{t}^{p} } \right] $$
(29)

where

$$ \begin{aligned} E\left[ {P_{t + j + 1} P_{t + j} |\varDelta y_{t}^{p} } \right] = & E\left\{ {\varDelta y_{t + j + 1}^{p} + (1 - \theta )\varDelta y_{t + j}^{p} + ..} \right\} \\ & \left\{ {\varDelta y_{t + j}^{p} + (1 - \theta )\varDelta y_{t + j - 1}^{p} + ..} \right\} \\ & + (1 - \theta )^{2j + 1} \left\{ {\left( {\varDelta y_{t}^{p} } \right)^{2} - \sigma_{p}^{2} } \right\} \\ \end{aligned} $$
(30)

Taking the expected value of the product in Eq. (30), summing up the resulting infinite series and rearranging this equation reduces to

$$ E\left[ {P_{t + j + 1} P_{t + j} |\varDelta y_{t}^{p} } \right] = \frac{{(1 - \theta )\sigma_{p}^{2} }}{\theta (2 - \theta )} + (1 - \theta )^{2j + 1} \left\{ {\left( {\varDelta y_{t}^{p} } \right)^{2} - \sigma_{p}^{2} } \right\}. $$
(31)

Substituting Eqs. (28) and (30) into Eq. (29), rearranging and using Lemma 1

$$ E\left[ {u_{t + j + 1} u_{t + j} |\varDelta y_{t}^{p} } \right] = (1 - \theta )^{2j + 1} \left\{ {\left( {\varDelta y_{t}^{p} } \right)^{2} - \sigma_{p}^{2} } \right\}. $$
(32)

From Eq. (17) in the text,

$$ Eu_{t}^{2} = EQ_{t}^{2} + EP_{t}^{2} \,{\text{for}}\,{\text{all}}\,t. $$
(33)

Using the expressions for Qt and Pt from Eq. (18) in Eq. (33), taking expectations of the resulting expressions, rearranging and using Lemma 1 yields

$$ Eu_{t}^{2} = \frac{{\sigma_{q}^{2} }}{1 - \theta } {\text{for}}\,{\text{all}}\,t. $$

Hence

$$ \sqrt {E\left( {u_{t + j + 1} } \right)^{2} E\left( {u_{t + j} } \right)^{2} } = \frac{{\sigma_{q}^{2} }}{1 - \theta }. $$
(34)

Equations (32) and Eq. (34) imply that

$$ \rho_{j} \left( {\varDelta y_{t}^{p} } \right) \equiv \frac{{E\left\{ {u_{t + j + 1}, u_{t + j} |\varDelta y_{t}^{p} } \right\}}}{{\sqrt {E\left( {u_{t + j + 1} } \right)^{2} E\left( {u_{t + j} } \right)^{2} } }} = (1 - \theta )^{2(j + 1)} \left\{ {\frac{{\left( {\varDelta y_{t}^{p} } \right)^{2} }}{{\sigma_{q}^{2} }} - \frac{{\sigma_{p}^{2} }}{{\sigma_{q}^{2} }}} \right\} $$

QED

1.4 Derivation of Equation (23)

The proof is an immediate consequence of Lemma 1. QED

1.5 Proof that Using Observations on yt and yet or on πt and πet Yield Identical Estimates of \( \theta \) and of \( \sigma_{{\varDelta y_{t}^{p} }}^{2} \)

When the pair \( \left\{ {\pi_{t} ,\pi_{t}^{e} } \right\} \) is used the estimate of θ is obtained by running the regression

$$ \pi_{t}^{e} - \pi_{t - 1}^{e} = \theta \left( {\pi_{t} - \pi_{t - 1}^{e} } \right). $$

When the pair \( \left\{ {y_{t} ,y_{t}^{e} } \right\} \) is used the estimate of θ is obtained by running the regression

$$ y_{t}^{e} - y_{t - 1}^{e} = \theta \left( {y_{t} - y_{t - 1}^{e} } \right). $$

The definitions of \( \left\{ {y_{t} ,y_{t}^{e} } \right\} \) in Eq. (25) in the text imply that the first and the second equations are identical so the estimate of θ obtained from either equation is the same.

When πt is used to estimate σ2yt the estimate is the sample variance of \( \pi_{t} - \pi_{t - 1} \) and when yt is used it is the sample variance of \( y_{t} - y_{t - 1} \). Since the definitions in Eq. (25) imply

$$ y_{t} - y_{t - 1} = \pi_{t} - \pi_{t - 1} $$

the two estimates are identical. QED

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2020 Springer Nature Switzerland AG

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Cukierman, A., Lustenberger, T., Meltzer, A. (2020). The Permanent-Transitory Confusion: Implications for Tests of Market Efficiency and for Expected Inflation During Turbulent and Tranquil Times. In: Arnon, A., Young, W., van der Beek, K. (eds) Expectations. Springer Studies in the History of Economic Thought. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-41357-6_12

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics