Skip to main content

Guaranteed Deterministic Approach to Superhedging: Lipschitz Properties of Solutions of the Bellman–Isaacs Equations

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Frontiers of Dynamic Games

Part of the book series: Static & Dynamic Game Theory: Foundations & Applications ((SDGTFA))

Abstract

For the discrete-time superreplication problem, a guaranteed deterministic formulation is proposed: the problem is to ensure the cheapest coverage of the contingent claim on an American option under all admissible scenarios. These scenarios are set by a priori defined compacts depending on the price history; the price increment at each moment of time must lie in the corresponding compact. The market is considered without trading constraints and transaction costs. The problem statement is game-theoretic in nature and leads directly to the Bellman–Isaacs equations of a special form under the assumption of no trading constraints. In the present study, we estimate the modulus of continuity of uniformly continuous solutions, including the Lipschitz case.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 84.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. 1.

    The increments are taken “backward”, i.e., ΔX t = X t − X t−1, where X t is a discounted price vector at time t.

  2. 2.

    We suppose that a risk-free asset has a fixed price equal to one.

  3. 3.

    The point indicates the variables representing the price evolution. More precisely, prehistory \( \bar {x}_{t-1}=(x_0,\ldots , x_{t-1})\in (\mathbb {R}^n)^t \) for K t, whereas it is the history \( \bar {x}_t=(x_0,\ldots , x_{t})\in (\mathbb {R}^n)^{t+1} \) for the functions \( v^*_t \) and g t introduced below.

  4. 4.

    The sign denotes the maximum; hy = 〈h, y〉 is the dot product of vector h by vector y.

  5. 5.

    Neighborhoods of points − and +  are given by [, a), \(a \in \mathbb {R}\) and (b,  +], \(b \in \mathbb {R}\), respectively.

  6. 6.

    Here, x + A = {z :  z − x ∈ A}.

  7. 7.

    It can be interpreted as the guaranteed profit for a strategy h ∈ D t(⋅). Note that \( \min \{hy,\; y\in K_t (\cdot )\} \) is attained due to the compactness of K t(⋅) for some (worst scenario) \( y_h^*\in K_t (\cdot ) \); it is positive for the sure arbitrage strategy h ∈ D t(⋅).

  8. 8.

    Here, 2 T is the class of all subsets of T.

  9. 9.

    In this case, considering the property 10, the subadditivity holds trivially.

  10. 10.

    Wherein, it is possible that ω(δ)= for all δ > 0. If ω satisfies the conditions 10, 20 and 50, then, for 30, it is sufficient that ω(δ) is finite at a point δ > 0.

  11. 11.

    For such a function φ, the conditions of Remark 14.1 clause 2) are satisfied.

  12. 12.

    A similar statement can be found in the literature; see, for example, Sect. 6 in the book [2]; however, there are redundant requirements on φ.

  13. 13.

    If, in addition to 10 and 20, the function is concave, then 40 and 50 are fulfilled.

  14. 14.

    More precisely, it is a continuation of the Cantor function ψ : [0,  1]↦[0,  1], setting φ(δ) = 1 when δ > 1.

  15. 15.

    This property can be considered a continuous version of the Fekete lemma.

  16. 16.

    As the additive function, i.e., the solution of the Cauchy equation, is subadditive, then, without additional conditions, it is impossible to obtain asymptotic linearity for the subadditive function, because the axiom of choice implies the existence of a solution (not measurable) of the Cauchy equation such that its graph is dense everywhere on the plane [6]. It suffices to require the boundness of ω in a neighborhood of the point 0; in our case, this follows from the nonnegativity of ω (a consequence of the properties of 10 and 20) and the properties of monotonicity of 20 and the finiteness 30.

  17. 17.

    If a function ω, satisfying 10 and 20, is concave, then the function \(t \to \frac {\omega (t))}{t}\) is non-increasing.

  18. 18.

    It is possible that h ρ(A, B) = .

  19. 19.

    Recall that hy denotes the inner product.

  20. 20.

    For such arguments, the function r takes finite non-negative values.

  21. 21.

    The convex hull of a compact is compact; see, for example, [7], Theorem 2.6. Note that we use the notation (14.11) here.

  22. 22.

    Here, \( \operatorname *{\mathrm {aff}}(N)\) is the affine hull of N (that is the smallest affine set containing N, see [13, Section 1]); \(\dim (A)\) is the dimension of an affine space A.

  23. 23.

    Here, \( \operatorname *{\mathrm {ri}}(A) \) denotes the relative interior of a convex set A, that is the interior of A with respect to the relative topology on \( \operatorname *{\mathrm {aff}}(A)\subseteq \mathbb {R}^n \), see [13, Section 6].

  24. 24.

    At least, with respect to the functions of potential payments g t, t = 1, …, N, this is not only convenient, but also natural, as, usually, it is how these functions are defined in practice.

  25. 25.

    For compact-valued mappings, h-continuity is equivalent to continuity; see Theorem 2.68 from [5].

  26. 26.

    See, for example, Theorem 3.16.5 from [3].

  27. 27.

    See, for example,Theorem 5.1 and Lemma 5.5 from [8].

  28. 28.

    Here, the Lipschitz constants can be considered as minimal, i.e., \( L_ {g_{t-1}} = \sup \{\omega _{g_{t-1}} (\delta ) / \delta , \; \delta > 0 \} \), \( L_{K_{t-1}} = \sup \{\omega _{K_ {t-1}} (\delta ) / \delta , \; \delta > 0 \} \).

  29. 29.

    Also called the digital option.

  30. 30.

    This terminology was introduced in [9].

References

  1. Bernhard, P., Engwerda, J.C., Roorda, B., Schumacher, J., Kolokoltsov, V., Saint-Pierre, P., Aubin, J.-P.: The Interval Market Model in Mathematical Finance: Game-Theoretic Methods, p. 348. Springer, New York (2013)

    Book  Google Scholar 

  2. DeVore, R.A., Lorentz, G.G.: Constructive Approximation, p. 452. Springer, New York (1993)

    Book  Google Scholar 

  3. Diedonné, J.: Foundations of Modern Analysis, p. 361. Academic, New York (1960)

    Google Scholar 

  4. Dovgoshey, O., Martio, O., Ryazanov, V., Vuorinen, M.: The Cantor function. Expo. Math. 24(1), 1–37 (2006)

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  5. Hu, S., Papageorgiou, N.: Handbook of Multivalued Analysis: Theory, vol. I. Mathematics and Its Applications, vol. 419, p. 968. Springer, Berlin (1997)

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  6. Jones, F.B.: Connected and disconnected plane sets and the functional equation f(x + y) = f(x) + f(y). Bull. Am. Math. Soc. 48, 115–120 (1942)

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  7. Leichtweiss, K.: Konvexe Mengen, p. 330. Springer, Berlin (1980) (in German)

    Book  Google Scholar 

  8. Polovinkin, E.S.: Mnogoznachniy analiz i differencialniye vklucheniya [Set-valued analysis and differential inclusions], p. 524. Nauka, FizMatLit Publication, Moscow (2015) (in Russian)

    Google Scholar 

  9. Smirnov, S.N.: A guaranteed deterministic approach to superhedging: financial market model, trading constraints and Bellman–Isaacs equations. Math. Game Theory Appl. 10(4), 59–99 (2018) (in Russian)

    MATH  Google Scholar 

  10. Smirnov, S.N.: A guaranteed deterministic approach to superhedging: no arbitrage market condition. Math. Game Theory Appl. 11(2), 68–95 (2019) (in Russian)

    Google Scholar 

  11. Smirnov, S.N.: A guaranteed deterministic approach to superhedging: the proprieties of semicontinuity and continuity of the Bellman–Isaacs equations. Math. Game Theory Appl. (2019, in print) (in Russian)

    Google Scholar 

  12. Titman, A.F.: Theory of approximation of functions of a real variable. In: International Series of Monographs in Pure and Applied Mathematics, vol. 34, p. 644. Pergamon Press, Oxford (1963)

    Google Scholar 

  13. Rockafellar, R.T.: Convex Analysis, p. 451. Princeton University Press, Princeton (1970)

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2019 Springer Nature Switzerland AG

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Smirnov, S.N. (2019). Guaranteed Deterministic Approach to Superhedging: Lipschitz Properties of Solutions of the Bellman–Isaacs Equations. In: Petrosyan, L., Mazalov, V., Zenkevich, N. (eds) Frontiers of Dynamic Games. Static & Dynamic Game Theory: Foundations & Applications. Birkhäuser, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-23699-1_14

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics