Skip to main content

Returns Policies and Smart Salvaging: Benefiting from a Multi-Channel World

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Operations in an Omnichannel World

Part of the book series: Springer Series in Supply Chain Management ((SSSCM,volume 8))

Abstract

Up to 50% of online purchases are returned, reducing e-tailers’ profits. E-tailers employ two mitigating measures. First, returns management affects the number of returns via restocking fees and hassle cost; a restrictive policy leads to fewer returns but also depresses demand. Second, salvaging increases e-tailers’ revenue via the resale of returned items. We unite these two and analyze how to most profitably allocate returns to different salvaging channels and how this depends on and influences the returns policy, price, as well as profit. A competitive retailer must adopt a smart salvaging approach while simultaneously setting the price and restocking fee. The result is a profit-maximizing portfolio of salvage opportunities—which includes the primary market, the secondary market, and returns to the manufacturer (RTM)—as applied by highly profitable e-tailers such as Zalando. Yet in reality, most e-tailers salvage returns exclusively in the primary market; that strategy is suboptimal because it reduces profits and yields a too-strict returns policy. The alternative, smart salvaging policy reduces both price and restocking fee but still increases profit. Such a policy requires that managers respond dynamically: new competition calls for more salvaging of returns by RTM; increased market concentration calls for salvaging more in the primary and secondary markets. Products with a longer (resp., shorter) selling time are more profitably salvaged in the primary market (resp., via RTM). A firm’s investment in salvaging opportunities will not pay off unless these considerations are taken into account. We derive implications for e-tailers and recommend managerial strategies for remaining competitive.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 139.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 179.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 179.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

References

  • Anderson, E. T., Hansen, K., & Simester, D. (2009). The option value of returns, theory and empirical evidence. Marketing Science, 28(3), 405–423.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anderson, S. P., & Ginsburgh, V. A. (1994). Price discrimination via second-hand markets. European Economic Review, 38(1), 23–44.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Asdecker, B. (2015). Statistiken Retouren Deutschland - Definition. http://www.retourenforschung.de/definition_statistiken-retouren-deutschland.html. Visited on 10 Feb 2015.

  • Barnes, L., & Lea-Greenwood, G. (2006). Fast fashioning the supply chain: Shaping the research agenda. Journal of Fashion Marketing and Management: An International Journal, 10(3), 259–271.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bergmann, H. (2016). Versand- und Retourenmanagement im E-Commerce 2016, Trends und Strategien der Onlinehändler. Cologne: EHI Retail Institute. https://www.ehi.org/de/studien/versand-und-retourenmanagement-im-e-commerce-2016/

    Google Scholar 

  • Bower, A. B., & Maxham, J. G. (2012). Return shipping policies of online retailers, normative assumptions and the long-term consequences of fee and free returns. Journal of Marketing, 76(5), 110–124.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Che, Y.-K. (1996). Customer return policies for experience goods. The Journal of Industrial Economics, 44(1), 17–24.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chu, W. (1998). Managing dissatisfaction, how to decrease customer opportunism by partial refunds. Journal of Service Research, 1(2), 140–155.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Crocker, K. J., & Letizia, P. (2014). Optimal policies for recovering the value of consumer returns. Production and Operations Management, 23(10), 1667–1680.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Davis, S., Gerstner, E., & Hagerty, M. (1995). Money back guarantees in retailing: Matching products to consumer tastes. Journal of Retailing, 71(1), 7–22.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Davis, S., Hagerty, M., & Gerstner, E. (1998). Return policies and the optimal level of “hassle”. Journal of Economics and Business, 50(5), 445–460.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Difrancesco, R. M., & Huchzermeier, A. (2016). Closed-loop supply chains: A guide to theory and practice. International Journal of Logistics Research and Applications, 19(5), 443–464.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Difrancesco, R. M., Huchzermeier, A., & Schroeder, D. I. (2017). Optimizing the return window for online fashion retailers with closed-loop refurbishment. Omega, 78, 205–221.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Emmons, H., & Gilbert, S. M. (1998). Note. The role of returns policies in pricing and inventory decisions for catalogue goods. Management Science, 44(2), 276–283.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • European Commission (2011). Directive 2011/83/EU of the European Parliament and of the Council, L 304/64. http://eur-lex.europa.eu/legal-content/EN/TXT/PDF/?uri=CELEX:32011L0083&rid=1

    Google Scholar 

  • Greve, C., & Davis, J. (2015). Recovering lost profits by improving reverse logistics. https://www.ups.com/media/en/Reverse_Logistics_wp.pdf. Visited on 10 Feb 2017.

  • Guide, V. D. R., & Li, J. (2010). The potential for cannibalization of new products sales by remanufactured products. Decision Sciences, 41(3), 547–572.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hess, J. D., Chu, W., & Gerstner, E. (1996). Controlling product returns in direct marketing. Marketing Letters, 7(4), 307–317.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hotelling, H. (1990). The collected economics articles of Harold Hotelling. New York: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Huang, J., Leng, M., & Parlar, M. (2013). Demand functions in decision modeling, a comprehensive survey and research directions. Decision Sciences, 44(3), 557–609.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Huang, X., Gu, J. W., Ching, W. K., & Siu, T. K. (2014). Impact of secondary market on consumer return policies and supply chain coordination. Omega, 45, 57–70.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Janakiraman, N., Syrdal, H. A., & Freling, R. (2016). The effect of return policy leniency on consumer purchase and return decisions: A meta-analytic review. Journal of Retailing, 92(2), 226–235.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kogan, K. (2011). Second-hand markets and intrasupply chain competition. Journal of Retailing, 87(4), 489–501.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kumar, R., & Ramachandran, P. (2016). Revenue management in remanufacturing: Perspectives, review of current literature and research directions. International Journal of Production Research, 54(7), 2185–2201.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Matthews, S. A., & Persico, N. G. (2005, March 28). Information acquisition and the excess refund puzzle. PIER working paper No. 05–015. Available at SSRN: https://ssrn.com/abstract=694606 or https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.694606.

  • Matthews, S. A., & Persico, N. G. (2007, July 16). Information acquisition and refunds for returns. PIER working paper No. 07–021. Available at SSRN: https://ssrn.com/abstract=1004280 or https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.1004280.

  • Mitra, S. (2016). Models to explore remanufacturing as a competitive strategy under duopoly. Omega, 59, 215–227.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mixon, F. G. (1999). Customer return policies for experience goods, the impact of product price and consumer search costs on seller-provided informational cues. Applied Economics, 31(3), 331–336.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mollenkopf, D., Russo, I., & Frankel, R. (2007). The returns management process in supply chain strategy. International Journal of Physical Distribution & Logistics Management, 37(7), 568–592.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Moorthy, S., & Srinivasan, K. (1995). Signaling quality with a money-back guarantee: The role of transaction costs. Marketing Science, 14(4), 442–466.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Munbodh, E. (2017). John Lewis to cut ‘No Quibbles’ 90-day return policy under new rules - this is what’s changing, mirror. http://www.mirror.co.uk/money/john-lewis-cut-no-quibbles-9706360. Visited on 18 May 2017.

  • Padmanabhan, V., & Png, I. P. L. (1997). Manufacturer’s return policies and retail competition. Marketing Science, 16(1), 81–94.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pasternack, B. A. (1985). Optimal pricing and return policies for perishable commodities. Marketing Science, 4(2), 166–176.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Qiaolun, G., Jianhua, J., & Tiegang, G. (2008). Pricing management for a closed loop supply chain. Journal of Revenue & Pricing Management, 7(1), 45–60.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Roellecke, F., & Huchzermeier, A. (2017). Competitive returns policies with salvaging in a secondary market: When less is more, SSRN Electronic Journal. https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=2997567

  • Roellecke, F., Huchzermeier, A., & Schroeder, D. I. (2017). Returning customers: The hidden strategic opportunity of returns management. California Management Review, 60(2), 176–203.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rogers, D. S., Melamed, B., & Lembke, R. S. (2012). Modeling and analysis of reverse logistics. Journal of Business Logistics, 33(2), 107–117.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rust, J. (1986). When is it optimal to kill off the market for used durable goods? Econometrica, 54(1), 65–86.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Salop, S. C. (1979). Monopolistic competition with outside goods. The Bell Journal of Economics, 10, 141–156.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Seeberger, D. A., Huchzermeier, A., & Schroeder, D. I. (2017). Competitive returns management: Why higher salvage values are not necessarily better. SSRN Electronic Journal. http://ssrn.com/abstract=2809047

  • Shulman, J. D., Coughlan, A. T., & Savaskan, R. C. (2009). Optimal restocking fees and information provision in an integrated demand-supply model of product returns. Manufacturing & Service Operations Management, 11(4), 577–594.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shulman, J. D., Coughlan, A. T., & Savaskan, R. C. (2010). Optimal reverse channel structure for consumer product returns. Marketing Science, 29(6), 1071–1085.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shulman, J. D., Coughlan, A. T., & Savaskan, R. C. (2011). Managing consumer returns in a competitive environment. Management science, 57(2), 347–362.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Swan, P. L. (1980). Alcoa: The influence of recycling on monopoly power. The Journal of Political Economy, 88(1), 76–99.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weiss, S. (2017). Uh Oh: Nordstrom has revised its notoriously liberal refund policy. http://www.refinery29.com/2017/01/138291/nordstrom-return-policy-change. Visited on 18 May 2017.

  • Yalabik, B., Petruzzi, N. C., Chhajed, D. (2005). An integrated product returns model with logistics and marketing coordination. European Journal of Operational Research, 161(1), 162–182.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Dominic A. Seeberger .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Appendix

Appendix

1.1 Model Formulation and Equilibrium Solution

1.1.1 Demand and Model Formulation

Demand in the primary market is modeled in two steps (here illustrated for the duopoly case). Step I features a Hotelling line; Step II adds a linear demand model.

Step I Two differentiated retailers are located at the opposite ends of a unit-length Hotelling line (Hotelling 1990). On that line, consumers are distributed uniformly according to their a priori product preferences Θ ∈ [0, 1]. While accounting for p, f, and product preference, they decide where to purchase by maximizing their expected utility; i.e., the likelihood of keeping the purchase (1 − α) times the utility of a perfect match (u) minus the price of product i (ε P p i) minus the mismatch between expectations and reality (|x i − Θ|) minus the likelihood of returning the product (α) times the cost of a return (ε F αf i):

$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned} U_{i}=(1-\alpha)[u-\varepsilon _P p_{i}-\vert x_{i}-\varTheta\vert]-\varepsilon _F \alpha f_{i}\,\,\text{with}\,\, x_{i=1}=0\,\,\text{and}\,\,x_{i=2}=1. \end{aligned} $$
(5)

There exists a marginal consumer a with Θ = x a who is undecided between retailer 1 and 2. All consumers to the left of a (i.e., with Θ < a) purchase from 1, and all others from 2. This setting can be extended to an n-competitor circular city model (see Salop 1979). If the retailers behave symmetrically (i.e., charge the same price and restocking fee), demand is distributed equally with D i = 1∕n.

$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned} U_{1}=U_{2}\enspace\text{for}\enspace x_{a}&=\frac{\alpha \varepsilon _F (f_1-f_2)-(\alpha -1) \left((p_1-p_2)\varepsilon _P-1\right)}{2 (\alpha -1)};\\ D_1&=x_{a}\enspace\text{and}\enspace D_2=1-x_{a}. \end{aligned} $$
(6)

Step II Each consumer on the line is treated as a single, independent market with a negatively sloped, linear demand curve (Huang et al. 2014). Each demand depends on p i and f i as well as the likelihood of a return (α)—\(d_{p,i}=D_{\max }-\varepsilon _{P} p_i - \varepsilon _F \alpha f_i\). Total demand for each retailer equals the share of consumers deciding to purchase there (i.e., from the Hotelling line) multiplied by the quantity purchased (i.e., from the demand curve). For retailer i, demand in the primary market unfolds as

$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned} D_i{=}\frac{\left(D_{max}{-}(\varepsilon_F \alpha f_i{+}\varepsilon_P p_i)\right) \left(\alpha \varepsilon_F (f_{i}{-}f_{i+1})-(\alpha -1) \left(\varepsilon_P (p_i-p_{i+1}){-}1\right)\right)}{2 (\alpha -1)}. \end{aligned} $$
(7)

1.1.2 Equilibrium Solution

Resulting in a symmetric equilibrium, n retailers choose p i and f i to maximize π i. All retailers face the same cost and revenue functions as well α at 50% as in line with Zalando (Seeberger et al. 2017). Assuming ε S = 1 and ε F = ε P = ε and deriving a general solution we solve the retailers’ maximization problem (2) and (8).

$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned} \mathcal{L}(p_{i},f_{i},\lambda)=\pi_i^{**}(p_{i},f_{i})+\lambda_1(D_{\max}\varepsilon^{-1}-p_i-\alpha f_i)+\lambda_2(p_i-f_i). \end{aligned} $$
(8)
$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned} \begin{aligned} & \mathrm{(A)} && \frac{\partial \mathcal{L}}{\partial p_i} && = \frac{\partial \pi_i^{**}}{\partial p_i} -\lambda_1+\lambda_2 && \leq0 \textit{,} \\ & \mathrm{(B)} && \frac{\partial \mathcal{L}}{\partial f_i} && = \frac{\partial \pi_i^{**}}{\partial f_i} -\alpha \lambda_1-\lambda_2 && \leq0 \textit{,} \\ & \mathrm{(C)} && \frac{\partial \mathcal{L}}{\partial \lambda_1} && = D_{\max}\varepsilon^{-1}-p_i-\alpha f_i && \geq0 \textit{,} \\ & \mathrm{(D)} && \frac{\partial \mathcal{L}}{\partial \lambda_2} && = p_i-f_i && \geq0 \textit{,} \\ & \mathrm{(I)} && p_i\frac{\partial\mathcal{L}}{\partial p_{i}} && = p_i \frac{\partial \pi_i^{**}}{\partial p_i} -p_i \lambda_1+p_i \lambda_2 && =0 \textit{,} \\ & \mathrm{(II)} && f_{i}\frac{\partial\mathcal{L}}{\partial f_{i}} && = f_i\frac{\partial \pi_i^{**}}{\partial f_i} -f_i\alpha \lambda_1-f_i\lambda_2 && =0 \textit{,} \\ & \mathrm{(III)} && \lambda_1 \frac{\partial\mathcal{L}}{\partial \lambda_1} && = \lambda_1 \left(D_{\max}\varepsilon^{-1}-p_i-\alpha f_i\right) && =0 \textit{,} \\ & \mathrm{(IV)} && \lambda_2 \frac{\partial\mathcal{L}}{\partial \lambda_2} && = \lambda_2 \left(p_i-f_i\right) && =0 \textit{,} \\ & \mathrm{(N)} && && f_i,p_i, \lambda_1, \lambda_2 && \geq0 \textit{.} \\ \end{aligned} \end{aligned}$$

Price and Restocking Fee Reviewing the FOC for a maximum \(\frac {\partial \pi _i}{\partial p_i} \overset {!}{=} 0\) yields one solution for \(p_i^*\). With assumptions made in Table 7, \(p_i^*\) fulfills the SOC for a maximum \(\frac {\partial ^2\pi _i}{\partial p_i^2}<0\). For \(f_i^*\), there are five possible solutions to the FOC. The optimal f i as a function of q S,i and q P,i are the two solutions when solving the first derivative of π i with respect to f i for f i; which one represents the optimum f i depends on q S,i and q P,i. Here, the first derivative of π i (w.r.t. f i at \(f_i=f_i^*\)) is equal to zero whereas the second derivative is strictly negative and thus fulfilling the SOC for a maximum for \(f_i=f_i^*\) and \(p_i=p_i^*\). Note that the term for \(f_i^*\) is highly complex. We therefore do not show the closed form within this chapter.

Salvaging E-tailers set the salvaging allocation while accounting for \(f_i^{*}\) and \(p_i^{*}\). Even though a closed-form solution (satisfying both the FOC and SOC for a maximum) can be obtained for the optimization problem (see Eq. (9)), it is highly complicated. As the general form is not needed in this chapter, we do not show it.

$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned} \mathcal{L}(q_{P,i},q_{S,i},q_{R,i},\lambda) =\pi_i^{*}(q_{P,i},q_{S,i},q_{R,i})+\lambda(1-q_{P,i}-q_{S,i}-q_{R,i}). \end{aligned} $$
(9)
$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned} \begin{aligned} & \mathrm{(A)} && \frac{\partial\mathcal{L}}{\partial q_{P,i}} &&= \frac{\partial\pi_i^*}{\partial q_{P,i}}-\lambda q_{P,i} && \leq0 \textit{,} \\ & \mathrm{(B)} && \frac{\partial\mathcal{L}}{\partial q_{S,i}} &&= \frac{\partial\pi_i^*}{\partial q_{S,i}}-\lambda q_{S,i} && \leq0 \textit{,} \\ & \mathrm{(C)} && \frac{\partial\mathcal{L}}{\partial q_{R,i}} &&= \frac{\partial\pi_i^*}{\partial q_{R,i}}-\lambda q_{R,i} && \leq0 \textit{,} \\ & \mathrm{(D)} && \frac{\partial\mathcal{L}}{\partial \lambda} &&= 1-q_{P,i}-q_{S,i}-q_{R,i} && =0 \textit{,} \\ & \mathrm{(I)} && q_{P,i}\frac{\partial\mathcal{L}}{\partial q_{P,i}} &&= q_{P,i}\frac{\partial\pi_i^*}{\partial q_{P,i}}-\lambda q_{P,i}^2 && =0 \textit{,} \\ & \mathrm{(II)} && q_{S,i}\frac{\partial\mathcal{L}}{\partial q_{S,i}} &&= q_{S,i}\frac{\partial\pi_i^*}{\partial q_{S,i}}-\lambda q_{S,i}^2 && =0 \textit{,} \\ & \mathrm{(III)} && q_{R,i}\frac{\partial\mathcal{L}}{\partial q_{R,i}} &&= q_{R,i}\frac{\partial\pi_i^*}{\partial q_{R,i}}-\lambda q_{R,i}^2 && =0 \textit{,} \\ & \mathrm{(N)} && && q_{P,i},q_{S,i},q_{R,i},\lambda && \geq0 \textit{.} \\ \end{aligned} \end{aligned}$$

1.1.3 Numerical Proof of Conjectures

We outline in the following the proofs for Conjectures 15. Without loss of generalizability, we supply proofs that hold for all admissible parameter values (see Table 7). Note that for simplicity within this chapter, we show mainly numerical simulations (analytic proof for all conjectures is available upon request).

Conjecture 1 Given the properties of the first derivative of π i with respect to f i at f i = 0, we can show that \(f_i^*=0\) is not optimal. Since \(f_i^*=0\) would be a boundary solution to the optimization problem, this could only be true if \(\frac {\partial \pi _i}{\partial f_i}\) at f i = 0 is ≤ 0. While this can also be shown analytically, a simple numerical simulation outlines the same. In detail, we vary a, b, γ, ρ, and c from their minimum to their maximum with a 10−2 step size and vary n from 1 to 106 competitors. When c < 0.5, the first derivative of π i with respect to f i at f i = 0 always exceeds zero. Consequently, increasing f i at f i = 0 increases π i. Thus f i = 0 cannot be profit maximizing (except for c ≥ 0.5).

Conjecture 2 A single-source salvaging portfolio with q P,i = 1 is a boundary solution to the optimization problem; q P,i = 1 can only be optimal if the first derivative of π with respect to salvaging in the primary market is larger than the derivatives with respect to the other channels; otherwise, switching to another channel would boost profit—\(q_{P,i}^* = 1\) if \(\frac {\partial \pi _i}{q_{P,i}} > \frac {\partial \pi _i}{q_{S,i}}\) and \(\frac {\partial \pi _i}{q_{P,i}} > \frac {\partial \pi _i}{q_{R,i}}\). For robustness, we review these conditions in a setting which is most favoring toward salvaging in the primary market: duopoly competition (i.e., n = 2) and no refurbishment cost advantage in the secondary market (i.e., a = b = 0). For the above statement to be true, both \(\frac {\partial \pi _i}{q_{P,i}} - \frac {\partial \pi _i}{q_{S,i}}\) and \(\frac {\partial \pi _i}{q_{P,i}} - \frac {\partial \pi _i}{q_{R,i}}\) must be positive. Otherwise q P,i = 1 would not be an equilibrium solution. Considering all admissible parameter values, the terms are only positive (i.e., \(q_{P,i}^*=1 \)) if γ > γ crit, ρ ≤ ρ crit, and c ≥ c crit. As the exact critical values are not subject to this chapter and the results represent lengthy statements, they are omitted for brevity.

Conjecture 3 Via a brute-force approach we calculate the restocking fee, price, and the optimal salvaging portfolio for all admissible combinations of exogenous parameters. We vary a, b, γ, ρ, and c from their minimum to their maximum with a 10−2 step size and vary n from 1 to 106 competitors. While also showing the above claims to hold, this shows for n ≥ 1 and for any possible combination of variables (that allow a portfolio with all three salvaging channels), that \(q_{P,i,n}^*-q_{P,i,n+1}^*\in \mathbb {R}^{-}\), \(q_{S,i,n}^*-q_{S,i,n+1}^*\in \mathbb {R}^{+}\), and \(q_{R,i,n}^*-q_{R,i,n+1}^*\in \mathbb {R}^{-}\).

Conjecture 4 Equation (4) shows that in the primary and secondary markets, scale and learning effects accumulate (i.e., \(\sum _{j=1}^{t}q_{P/S,i,j}\) increases in t as q PS,i,j ≥ 0); no other components are affected by T. This lowers the retailer’s cost (per the minus before \(\sum _{j=1}^{t}\)) and these channels become more attractive in T. Contrary, impediments accumulate in the RTM market and increase cost (per the plus before \(\sum _{j=1}^{t}\)). Thus RTM becomes more costly. The optimal salvage allocation depends on the achievable margin, which is directly related to salvaging costs. Therefore, RTM becomes less advantageous while the other channels become more attractive. Then, the salvaging portfolio will be shifted away from RTM. Via a numerical simulation (see proof of Conjecture 3) we show that this intuition holds for all parameter values that allow a portfolio with all three salvaging channels. Here, for T between 2 and 104, \(q_{P,i,T}^*-q_{P,i,T+1}^*\in \mathbb {R}^{-}\), \(q_{S,i,T}^*-q_{S,i,T+1}^*\in \mathbb {R}^{-}\), and \(q_{R,i,T}^*-q_{R,i,T+1}^*\in \mathbb {R}^{+}\).

Conjecture 5 Business outcomes improve when acting dynamically (see Eq. (10) for constraints) in response to a changing environment. We use a numerical simulation (see methodology used for proof of Conjecture 3) to compare the least dynamic (B) against the static case (A). The profit effect is described by \(\sum \pi _{\mathrm {B}}-\sum \pi _{\mathrm {A}}\in \mathbb {R}^{+}_{0}\). The simulation shows that \( \varnothing p_{\mathrm {B}}-\varnothing p_{\mathrm {A}}\in \mathbb {R}^{-}_{0}\) and \(\varnothing f_{\mathrm {B}}-\varnothing f_{\mathrm {A}}\in \mathbb {R}^{-}_{0}\) for all admissible parameter values. Note that a dynamic retailer can replicate the decisions of a static one. Thus the former’s profit cannot be worse. Moreover, the dynamic retailer can adjust to new environments and achieve a superior salvage margin. Hence returns become less harmful. Therefore, \(\pi _i^*\) increases, \(f_i^*\) decreases, and \(p_i^*\) decreases.

$$\displaystyle \begin{aligned} \begin{small} \begin{gathered} \max_{\substack{p_{i,t},f_{i,t}, \\ q_{P,i,t},q_{S,i,t},q_{R,i,t}}} \sum^T_{t=1}\pi_{i,t}\quad \mathrm{s.t.}\enspace \begin{cases} \text{A:} & q_{P,i,t}+q_{S,i,t}+q_{R,i,t}=1, q_{P,i,1}=\cdots=q_{P,i,T}, q_{S,i,1}\\ & =\cdots=q_{S,i,T}, q_{R,i,1}=\cdots=q_{R,i,T}, f_{i,1}=\cdots=f_{i,T},\\ &p_{i,1}=\cdots=p_{i,T}; \\ \text{B:} & q_{P,i,t}+q_{S,i,t}+q_{R,i,t}=1, q_{P,i,1}=\cdots=q_{P,i,T},\\ & q_{S,i,1}=\cdots=q_{S,i,T},\, q_{R,i,1}=\cdots=q_{R,i,T}; \\ \text{C:} & q_{P,i,t}+q_{S,i,t}+q_{R,i,t}=1; \\ \text{D:} & \sum_{i,t}^{T}[(q_{P,i,t}+q_{S,i,t}+q_{R,i,t})R_{i,t}]=\sum_{i,t}^{T}R_{i,t}. \end{cases} \end{gathered} \end{small} \end{aligned} $$
(10)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2019 Springer Nature Switzerland AG

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Seeberger, D.A., Huchzermeier, A., Schroeder, D. (2019). Returns Policies and Smart Salvaging: Benefiting from a Multi-Channel World. In: Gallino, S., Moreno, A. (eds) Operations in an Omnichannel World. Springer Series in Supply Chain Management, vol 8. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-20119-7_5

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics