Skip to main content

The Costs of Overambitious Seeding of Social Products

  • Conference paper
  • First Online:
Complex Networks and Their Applications VII (COMPLEX NETWORKS 2018)

Part of the book series: Studies in Computational Intelligence ((SCI,volume 813))

Included in the following conference series:

Abstract

Product-adoption scenarios are often theoretically modeled as “influence-maximization” (IM) problems, where people influence one another to adopt and the goal is to find a limited set of people to “seed” so as to maximize long-term adoption. In many IM models, if there is no budgetary limit on seeding, the optimal approach involves seeding everybody immediately. Here, we argue that this approach can lead to suboptimal outcomes for “social products” that allow people to communicate with one another. We simulate a simplified model of social-product usage where people begin using the product at low rates and then ramp their usage up or down depending upon whether they are satisfied with their experiences. We show that overambitious seeding can result in people adopting in suboptimal contexts, where their friends are not active often enough to produce satisfying experiences. We demonstrate that gradual seeding strategies can do substantially better in these regimes.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 169.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Hardcover Book
USD 219.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    Other variants of this rule can certainly be considered and may even lead to better long-term outcomes, but this choice suffices to demonstrate our main results.

  2. 2.

    We set \(\langle k_{oc} \rangle < k_{in}\), so the average person has many more friendships within the same cluster than with people in the other clusters.

  3. 3.

    On average, each person in each cluster has at least one out-of-cluster friend.

  4. 4.

    The size of the three-cluster network can differ slightly from the size of the three clusters individually because, in both cases, we exclude people with zero degree, who would inevitably churn under our model. In a small percentage of cases, a person who has no within-cluster friends may still have friends in another cluster when three clusters are considered together.

  5. 5.

    Figure 3 shows the case of \(k_{ic} = 10\), but this approximate pattern holds for \(k_{ic} = 50\) as well.

  6. 6.

    There is only one network (FGH) where single-shot universal seeding wins, and then only at high \(p_0\)

  7. 7.

    For other recent explorations of the advantages of gradual seeding, see references [6] and [14].

  8. 8.

    Although it is definitely questionable whether churn is ever completely irreversible.

References

  1. Abebe, R., Adamic, L., Kleinberg, J.: Mitigating overexposure in viral marketing. In: Proceedings of the 32nd Conference on Artificial Intelligence. AAAI (2018)

    Google Scholar 

  2. Alkemade, F., Castaldi, C.: Strategies for the diffusion of innovations on social networks. Comput. Econ. 25(1–2), 3–23 (2005)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  3. Centola, D.: How Behavior Spreads: The Science of Complex Contagions, vol. 3. Princeton University Press, Princeton (2018)

    Book  Google Scholar 

  4. Fortunato, S., Hric, D.: Community detection in networks: a user guide. Phys. Rep. 659, 1–44 (2016)

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  5. Hagberg, A., Swart, P., Chult, S.D.: Exploring network structure, dynamics, and function using networkX. Technical report, Los Alamos National Laboratory (LANL), Los Alamos, NM (United States) (2008)

    Google Scholar 

  6. Jankowski, J., Bródka, P., Kazienko, P., Szymanski, B.K., Michalski, R., Kajdanowicz, T.: Balancing speed and coverage by sequential seeding in complex networks. Scientific reports 7(1), 891 (2017)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  7. Juul, J.S., Porter, M.A.: Hipsters on networks: How a small group of individuals can lead to an anti-establishment majority. arXiv preprint arXiv:1707.07187 (2017)

  8. Kabiljo, I., Karrer, B., Pundir, M., Pupyrev, S., Shalita, A.: Social hash partitioner: a scalable distributed hypergraph partitioner. Proceedings of the VLDB Endowment 10(11), 1418–1429 (2017)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  9. Kempe, D., Kleinberg, J., Tardos, É.: Maximizing the spread of influence through a social network. In: Proceedings of the ninth ACM SIGKDD international conference on Knowledge discovery and data mining, pp. 137–146. ACM (2003)

    Google Scholar 

  10. Kiesling, E., Günther, M., Stummer, C., Wakolbinger, L.M.: Agent-based simulation of innovation diffusion: a review. Central European Journal of Operations Research 20(2), 183–230 (2012)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  11. Kim, J.H., Vu, V.H.: Generating random regular graphs. In: Proceedings of the 35th Annual ACM symposium on Theory of Computing, pp. 213–222. ACM (2003)

    Google Scholar 

  12. Li, Y., Fan, J., Wang, Y., Tan, K.L.: Influence maximization on social graphs: A survey. IEEE Transactions on Knowledge and Data Engineering (2018)

    Google Scholar 

  13. Moore, C., et al.: The computer science and physics of community detection: landscapes, phase transitions, and hardness. Bull. EATCS 1(121) (2017)

    Google Scholar 

  14. Sela, A., Shmueli, E., Goldenberg, D., Ben-Gal, I.: Why spending more might get you less, dynamic selection of influencers in social networks. In: IEEE International Conference on the Science of Electrical Engineering (ICSEE), pp. 1–4. IEEE (2016)

    Google Scholar 

  15. Shalita, A., et al.: Social hash: an assignment framework for optimizing distributed systems operations on social networks. In: NSDI, pp. 455–468 (2016)

    Google Scholar 

  16. Steger, A., Wormald, N.C.: Generating random regular graphs quickly. Comb. Probab. Comput. 8(4), 377–396 (1999)

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  17. Ugander, J., Backstrom, L., Marlow, C., Kleinberg, J.: Structural diversity in social contagion. Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci. 109(16), 5962–5966 (2012)

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

We thank Udi Weinsberg and Israel Nir for helpful discussions, Shuyang Lin for development of the original simulation infrastructure, and Justin Cheng for reviewing code.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Shankar Iyer .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2019 Springer Nature Switzerland AG

About this paper

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this paper

Iyer, S., Adamic, L.A. (2019). The Costs of Overambitious Seeding of Social Products. In: Aiello, L., Cherifi, C., Cherifi, H., Lambiotte, R., Lió, P., Rocha, L. (eds) Complex Networks and Their Applications VII. COMPLEX NETWORKS 2018. Studies in Computational Intelligence, vol 813. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-05414-4_22

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics