Skip to main content

Forecasting: Its Purpose and Accuracy

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Introduction to Financial Forecasting in Investment Analysis

Abstract

The purpose of this monograph is to concisely convey forecasting techniques to applied investment analysis. People forecast when they make an estimate as to the future value of a time series. That is, if I observe that IBM has a stock price of $205.48, as of March 23, 2012, and earned an earnings per share (eps) of $13.06 for fiscal year 2011, then I might wonder at what price IBM would trade for on December 31, 2012, if it achieved the $14.85 eps that 21 analysts, on average, expect it to earn in 2012 (source: MSN, Money, March 23, 2012, 1:30 p.m., AST). The low estimate is $14.18 and the high estimate is $15.28. Ten stock analysts currently recommend IBM as a “Strong Buy,” one as a “Moderate Buy,” and ten analysts recommend “Hold.” Moreover, if IBM achieves its forecasted $16.36 eps average estimate for December 2013, when could be its stock price and should an investor purchase the stock? One sees several possible outcomes; can IBM achieve its forecasted eps figure? How accurate are the analysts’ forecasts? Second, should an investor purchase the stock on the basis of an earnings forecast? Is there a relationship between eps forecasts and stock prices? How accurate is it necessary for analysts to be for investors to make excess returns (stock market profits) trading on the forecasts?

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 84.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

References

  • Brown, R.G. 1963. Smoothing, Forecasting and Prediction of Discrete Time Series. Englewood Cliffs, N.J.: Prenctice-Hall, Inc.

    Google Scholar 

  • Clements, M.P. and D.F. Hendry. 1998. Forecasting Economic Time Series. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cragg, J.G. and B.G. Malkiel.1968. “The Consensus and Accuracy of Some Predictions of the Growth of Corporate Earnings”. Journal of Finance 23, 67–84.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Davis, H.T. and W.F.C. Nelson. 1937. Elements of Statistics with Application to Economic Data. Bloomington, Ind: The Principia Press, Inc.

    Google Scholar 

  • Elton, E.J. and M.J. Gruber. 1972. “Earnings Estimates and the Accuracy of Expectational Data. Management Science 18, B409–B424.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Elton, E.J., M.J. Gruber, S.J. Brown, and W.N. Goetzmann. 2009. Modern Portfolio Theory and Investment Analysis. New York: Wiley. 7th Edition.

    Google Scholar 

  • Elton, E. J., M.J. Gruber, and M. Gultekin. 1981. “Expectations and Share Prices.” Management Science 27, 975–987.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Granger, C.W.J. 1980a. “Testing for Causality: A Personal Viewpoint.” Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 2, 329–352.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Granger, C.W.J. 1980b. Foreccasting in Business and Economics. New York: Academic Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Granger, C.W.J. and P. Newbold. 1977. Forecasting Economic Time Series. New York: Academic Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Guerard, J.B.,Jr. and B.K. Stone. 1992. “Composite Forecasting of Annual corporate Earnings”. In A. Chen, Ed. Research in Finance 10, 205–230.

    Google Scholar 

  • Guerard, J.B., Jr., M. Gultekin, and B.K. Stone. 1997. “The Role of Fundamental Data and Analysts’ Earnings Breadth, Forecasts, and Revisions in the Creation of Efficient Portfolios.” In Research in Finance 15, edited by A. Chen.

    Google Scholar 

  • Holt, C.C. 1957. “Forecasting Trends and Seasonals by Exponentially Weighted Moving Averages” O.N.R. Memorandum, No. 52, Pittsburgh: Carnegie Institute of Technology. Holt's unpublished paper was published, with several corrected two graphical errors in the International Journal of Forecasting 20(2004), 5–10, The paper was published due to its successful use in the M1 competition, see Makridakis et al. (1984), and M3 competition see Makridakis and Hibon (2000).

    Google Scholar 

  • Holt's unpublished paper was published, with several corrected two graphical errors in the International Journal of Forecasting 20(2004), 5–10.

    Google Scholar 

  • Keane, M.P. and D.E. Runkle. 1998. “Are Financial Analysts’ Forecasts of Corporate Profits Rational?” The Journal of Political Economy 106, 768–805.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Klein, L. 1985. Economic Theory and Econometrics. Philadelphia: University of Pennsylvania Press. Chapter 22.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lim, T. 2001. “Rationality and Analysts’ Forecast Bias”. Journal of Finance 56, 369–385.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Makridakis, S. and M. Hibon. 2000. “The M3-Competition: Results, Conclusions and Implications.” International Journal of Forecasting 16, 451–476.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Makridakis, S., S.C. Wheelwright, and R. J. Hyndman. 1998. Forecasting: Methods and Applications, Third edition. New York: John Wiley & Sons. Chapters 7 and 8.

    Google Scholar 

  • Makridakis, S. and Winkler, R.L. 1983. “Averages of Forecasts: Some Empirical Results”. Management Science 29, 987–996.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Makridakis, S., A. Anderson, R. Carbone, R. Fildes, M. Hibon, J. Newton, E. Parzen, and R. Winkler. 1984. The Forecasting Accuracy of Major Time Series Methods. New York: Wiley

    Google Scholar 

  • Mincer, J. and V. Zarnowitz. (1969). “The Evaluation of Economic Forecasts,” J. Mincer editor, Economic Forecasts and Expectations, New York, Columbia University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Theil, H. 1961. Economic Forecasts and Policy. Amsterdam: North-Holland Publishing Company. Second Revised Edition.

    Google Scholar 

  • Theil, H. 1966. Applied Economic Forecasting. Amsterdam, North-Holland.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wheeler, L. 1994. “Changes in Consensus Earnings Estimates and their Impact on Stock Returns”, in B. Bruce and C. Epstein, Eds., The Handbook of Corporate Earnings Analysis. Chicago: Probus Publishing Company.

    Google Scholar 

  • Winkler, R.L. and Makridakis, S. 1983. “The Combination of Forecasts.” Journal of the Royal Statistical Society, Series A., 146, 150–157.

    Google Scholar 

  • Winters, P.R. 1960. “Forecasting Sales by Exponentially Weighted Averages”, Management Science 6, 324–342.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Appendix

Appendix

Exponential Smoothing

The most simple forecast of a time series can be estimated from an arithmetic mean of the data Davis and Nelson (1937). If one defines f as frequencies, or occurrences of the data, and x as the values of the series, then the arithmetic mean is

$$ A = \frac{{{f_1}{x_1} + {f_2}{x_2} + {f_3}{x_3} + \ldots + {f_t}{x_t}}}{T} $$
(1.22)

where \( T = {f_1} + {f_2} + {f_3} + \ldots + { }{f_t}. \)

$$ A = \frac{{\Sigma {f_i}{x_i}}}{T}. $$

Alternatively,

$$ \frac{{\Sigma {f_i}({x_i} - x)}}{T} $$
$$ A{ = }x{ +}\frac{{\Sigma {f_i}{(}{x_i} - x)}}{T}. $$
(1.23)

The first moment, mean, is

$$ A{ =}\frac{{\Sigma {f_i}{x_i}}}{T} = \frac{{{m_1}}}{{{m_0}}} $$
$$ {m_0} = \sum {f_i} = T,{ }{m_1} = \sum {f_i}{x_i}. $$

If x = 0, then

$$ {\sigma^2} = \frac{{\Sigma {f_i}x_i^2}}{T} - {A^2} $$
$$ {\sigma^2} = \frac{{{m_2}}}{{{m_{\mathrm{o}}}}} - \frac{{m_1^2}}{{m_{\mathrm{o}}^2}} = ({m_0}{m_2} - m_1^2)m_0^2. $$
(1.24)

Time series models often involve trend, cycle seasonal, and irregular components, Brown (1963). An upward-moving or increasing series over time could be modeled as

$$ {x_t} = a + bt, $$
(1.25)

where a is the mean and b is the trend, or rate at which the series increases over time, t. Brown (1963, p. 61) uses the closing price of IBM common stock as his example of an increasing series. One could use a quadrant term, c. If c is positive, then the series

$$ {x_t} = a + bt + c{t^2} $$
(1.26)

trend is changing toward an increasing trend, whereas a negative c denotes a decreasing rate of trend, from upward to downward.

In an exponential smoothing model, the underlying process is locally constant, x t  = a, plus random noise, ε t .

$$ {x_t} = a{\varepsilon_t}. $$
(1.27)

The average value of ε = 0.

A moving average can be estimated over a portion of the data:

$$ {M_t} = \frac{{{x_1} + {x_{t - 1}} + \ldots + {x_{t - N}} + 1}}{N}, $$
(1.28)

where M t is the actual average of the most recent N observations.

$$ {M_t} = {M_{t - {1}}} + \frac{{{x_t} - {x_{t - N}}}}{N}. $$
(1.29)

An exponential smoothing forecast builds upon the moving average concept.

$$ {s_t}{(}x{)} = \alpha {x_t} + ({1} - \alpha ){ }{s_{t - {1}}}(x), $$

where α = smoothing constant, which is similar to the fraction \( {{1} \left/ {T} \right.} \) in a moving average.

$$ \begin{array}{cc}{s_t}{(}x{)} = \alpha {x_t} + ({1} - \alpha )[\alpha {x_{t - {1}}} + ({1} - \alpha ){s_{t - {2}}}{(}x{)}] \hfill \\ = \alpha \Sigma_{ko}^{t - 1}{(1 - \alpha )^k}{x_{t - k}} + {(1 - \alpha )^t}{x_{\mathrm{o}}}, \end{array}$$
(1.30)

where s t (x) is a linear combination of all past observations. The smoothing constant must be estimated. In a moving average process, the N most recent observations are weighted (equally) by 1/N and the average age of the data is

$$ k = \frac{{0 + 1 + 2 + \ldots + N - 1}}{N} = \frac{{N - 1}}{2}. $$

An N-period moving average is equivalent to an exponential smoothing model having an average age of the data. The one-period forecast for an exponential smoothing model is

$$ {F_{t + {1}}} = {F_t} +\alpha ({y_t}-{F_t}), $$
(1.31)

where α is the constant, 0 < α < 1.

Intuitively, if α is near zero, then the forecast is very close to the previous value’s forecast. Alternatively,

$$ \begin{array}{lll} {F_{t + {1}}} = \alpha {y_t} + ({1} - \alpha ) {F_t} \hfill \\{F_{t + {1}}} = \alpha {y_t} + \alpha ({1} - \alpha ){ }{y_{t - {1}}} + ({1} - \alpha ){2}{F_{t - {1}}}. \hfill \\ \end{array} $$
(1.32)

Makridakis, Wheelwright and Hyndman (1998) express F t−1 in terms of F t−2 and, over time,

$$ \begin{array}{llll} {F_{t - {1}}} = \ \alpha {y_t} + \alpha ({1} - \alpha ){ }{y_{t - {1}}} + \alpha {(a - \alpha )^2}{y_{t - {2}}} + a{({1} - \alpha )^3}{y_{t - {3}}} \hfill \cr \qquad \qquad + \alpha {({1} - \alpha )^4}{y_{t - {4}}} + \alpha {({1} - \alpha )^5}{y_{t - {5}}} + \ldots\cr \qquad \qquad + \alpha {({1} - \alpha )^{t - {1}}}{y_t} + {({1} - \alpha )^t}{F_1}. \hfill \\ \end{array} $$
(1.33)

Different values of α produce different mean squared errors. If one sought to minimize the mean absolute percentage error, the adaptive exponential smoothing can be rewritten as

$$ {F_{t + {1}}} = \alpha {y_t} + ({1} - \alpha ){F_t} $$
(1.34)
$$ \alpha t + {1} = \left| {\frac{{{A_t}}}{{{M_t}}}} \right|, $$

\({\rm where } \qquad \qquad \qquad \qquad \begin{array}{lll} {A_t} = \beta {E_t} + ({1} - \beta ){ }{A_{t - {1}}} \hfill \\{M_t} = \beta |{E_t}| + ({1} - \beta ){ }{M_{t - {1}}} \hfill \\{E_t} = {y_t} - {F_t}. \hfill \\ \end{array} \)

A t is a smoothed estimate of the forecast error and a weighted average of A t−1 and the last forecast error, E t .

One of the great forecasting models is the Holt (1957) model that allowed forecasting of data with trends. Holt’s linear exponential smoothing forecast is

$$ \begin{array}{llll} \quad \ {L_t} = \alpha {y_t} + ({1} - \alpha ){(}{L_{t - {1}}} + {b_{t - {1}}}) \hfill \\ \quad \ {b_t} = \beta ({L_t}-{L_{t - {1}}}) + ({1} - \beta ){b_{t - {1}}} \hfill \\{F_{t + m}} = {L_t} + {b_t}m. \hfill \\ \end{array} $$
(1.35)

L t is the level of the series at time t, and b t is the estimate of the slope of the series at time t. The Holt model forecast should be better forecasts than adaptive exponential smoothing models, which lack trends. Makridakis et al. (1998) remind the reader that the Holt model is often referred to as “double exponential smoothing.” If α = β, then the Holt model is equal to Brown’s double exponential smoothing model.

The Hold (1957) and Winters (1960) seasonal model can be written as

$$ {\text{(Level)}}\quad {L_t} = \alpha \frac{{{y_t}}}{{{s_{t - s}}}} + (1 - \alpha )({L_{t - {1}}} + {b_{t - {1}}}) $$
$$ ({{Trend}})\quad {b_t} + \beta ({L_t}-{L_{t - {1}}}) + (a - \beta ){b_{t - {1}}} $$
$$ ({{Seasonal}})\quad {s_t} = \gamma \frac{{{y_t}}}{{{L_t}}} + (a - \gamma ){s_{t - s}} $$
$$ ({{Forecast}})\quad {F_{t + m}} = ({L_t} + {b_t}m){ }{S_{t - s + m}}. $$

Seasonality is the number of months or quarters, L t is the level of the series, b t is the trend of the series, and s t is the seasonal component.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2013 Springer Science+Business Media New York

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Guerard, J.B. (2013). Forecasting: Its Purpose and Accuracy. In: Introduction to Financial Forecasting in Investment Analysis. Springer, New York, NY. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-1-4614-5239-3_1

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics