Skip to main content

Electricity Generation and Wholesale Markets

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Regulation of the Power Sector

Part of the book series: Power Systems ((POWSYS))

Abstract

The generalized worldwide process of restructuring and liberalization of the electric power sector has primarily concerned the generation activity. Although liberalization and restructuring of the power industry has not been universally adopted, it is undoubtedly the prevalent framework in most countries.

The market is not an invention of capitalism. It has existed for centuries. It is an invention of civilization.—Mikhail Gorbachev

The author wants to thank Pablo Rodilla, Michel Rivier, and Ignacio Pérez-Arriaga for their support in the development of this chapter.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 259.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 329.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 329.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    See also the textbook conditions proposed by Joskow [18].

  2. 2.

    This is a necessary condition for the full liberalization, but it is not required for the implementation of a market mechanism at generation level.

  3. 3.

    The last step, the liberalization of the retail business, is analyzed in Chap. 9.

  4. 4.

    Corporatization refers to the transformation of state assets or agencies into state-owned corporations in order to introduce corporate management techniques to their administration. Corporatization is sometimes a precursor to partial or full privatization (see more in Wikipedia).

  5. 5.

    They were called “exempt wholesale generators” in the Act.

  6. 6.

    This section is based on [8].

  7. 7.

    In the Chilean scheme generators also participated in a capacity market, whose results were similar to the capacity payments later adopted in a number of Latin American countries.

  8. 8.

    See Batlle et al. [5] for a description of the expansion of electricity systems in Latin America.

  9. 9.

    In the schemes more open to competition that are presented later, the roles of the SO and MO differ from what is presented here.

  10. 10.

    For instance, the European Commission [13] defines the tasks of the Independent System Operator stating that ‘is responsible for granting and managing third-party access, including the collection of access charges, congestion charges, and payments under the inter-TSO compensation mechanism (…) is also responsible for operating, maintaining, and developing the transmission system. (…) has full responsibility for ensuring the long-term ability of the system to meet reasonable demand through investment planning (…) is responsible for planning, including obtaining the necessary authorizations and for the construction and commissioning of new infrastructure’.

  11. 11.

    In their role of retailers of the consumers under regulated tariffs.

  12. 12.

    It was a heuristic model named GOAL, later replaced by another one that was based on Lagrangian relaxation.

  13. 13.

    This description was written by Prof. Pérez-Arriaga.

  14. 14.

    Currently NordPool (www.nordpool.com), owned by the national grid companies Fingrid, Energinet.dk, Statnett, Svenska Kraftnät, provides a marketplace for trading both physical and financial contracts in Finland, Sweden, Denmark, and Norway.

  15. 15.

    These deviations may be due to several reasons. For instance, a thermal unit could have bid expecting to produce in four consecutive hours the day after, but in the final DAM schedule it has been committed in eight hours. If the unit just counts on fuel for the expected four hours, the generator will require a way to readjust the schedule, in order to purchase the committed supply in the four hours in excess.

  16. 16.

    Default or credit risk is the risk that a counterparty will be unable to meet its obligations, i.e., the risk that the counterparty will default on its contract over the life of the obligation.

  17. 17.

    Basis risk in finance is the risk associated with imperfect hedging using futures. It may arise due to the difference between the price of the asset that is to be hedged and the asset underlying the derivative, or to a mismatch between the futures expiration date and the price of the actual selling date of the asset (www.wikipedia.com).

  18. 18.

    See for instance www.omip.pt.

  19. 19.

    As pointed out by Boisseleau [7], this model has been mainly the result of a public initiative and the participation has been usually mandatory (or highly encouraged). In some cases these markets are not strictly but de facto compulsory, since generators with capacity obligations are required to submit bids to the day-ahead market. At the time of this writing (end of 2011), some of the main compulsory pools left were the ones implemented in Ireland, Alberta, Australia, and New Zealand.

  20. 20.

    See for instance the web page of the European Power Exchange, www.epexspot.com.

  21. 21.

    The discussion that follows is based on Rodilla et al. [29].

  22. 22.

    Turn Down Ratio is defined as the ratio of economic maximum MW to economic minimum MW.

  23. 23.

    It can also be observed how in this market at that time a 180 EUR/MWh price cap was in force.

  24. 24.

    The term “discriminatory” should not have here any derogatory interpretation; it just means that the pricing rule results in different charges or payments for the several agents.

  25. 25.

    A very closed-related technique is the alternative one proposed by O’Neill et al. [26]. This approach entails considering start (and other non-convex) costs as additional commodities different from energy, and thus, needing to be priced independently from this latter.

  26. 26.

    These prices in the vast majority of cases correspond to the variable fuel cost of the most expensive unit committed in each time interval.

  27. 27.

    http://www.mercatoelettrico.org

  28. 28.

    Part of this discussion is taken from ERGEG [11].

  29. 29.

    See UCTE [38] for a collection of operating principles and rules for transmission system operators in continental Europe.

  30. 30.

    As explained in Chap. 1, electric power systems have regulation mechanisms to keep frequency within an acceptable range around the nominal value. The aim of such controls is to maintain the equilibrium between the mechanical power delivered to the generators and the electric power demanded by the system.

  31. 31.

    Tertiary reserve is sometimes classified under a different heading, “balancing energy”. Its inclusion in the upper hierarchical level of the process that controls system frequency is believed to be preferable, for this also avoids confusion with the balancing market explained below.

  32. 32.

    As we shall see later, interventionist changes in the market rules—i.e., new rules that limit the freedom of the market agents, like a price cap—do mitigate market power. But this happens in detriment of the freedom of the market that it was intended to promote, in the first place.

  33. 33.

    Take for instance the case of France, in which EDF remains under the Government control and whose market share in the French wholesale market can be qualified as huge, above 85 % according to Eurostat [14], and the case of Vattenfall, still state-owned and whose market share is larger than 40 % in Sweden according to the same source, Needless to say that these market shares cannot be only judged in the context of the national market. The Nordpool in which Vattenfall is embedded turns to be a rather competitive and liquid regional market while the interconnection capacity of the French system with its neighboring markets is still far from being enough to deter the local market power of EDF.

  34. 34.

    The market share of Enel in Italy, still under the control of the Government (who owns more than 30 % of the shares) has evolved from 70 % in 1999 (the year in which it sold 15 GW) to below 30% [14], In Belgium, the market share of Electrabel, owned by GDF Suez, is above 75 %, while in Chile the market share of Enersis, bought by Endesa now part of the Enel group, as for 2010 was around 35 %.

  35. 35.

    An excellent review of market power issues in the US is provided by Helman [16]. An easy to read, tutorial text is authored by Rose [30]; another useful reference is The Brattle Group [35]. FERC Order 697-A establishes the conditions to allow market-based rates, depending on market power mitigation issues. Although very technical in legal terms, this document illustrates the terminology and the issues involved when examining market power in actual systems.

  36. 36.

    See The Brattle Group [35] and Adib and Hurlbut [1] for two good descriptions of the role and function of market monitoring units, mostly from the US perspective.

References

  1. Adib P, Hurlbut D (2008) Market power and market monitoring. In: Sioshansi FP (ed) Competitive electricity markets—design, implementation, performance. Elsevier, Amsterdam

    Google Scholar 

  2. AEMO (2010) An introduction to Australia’s National Electricity Market

    Google Scholar 

  3. AIP (2007) The bidding code of practice. A response and decision paper. AIP-SEM-07-430. www.allislandproject.org. Accessed 30 July 2007

  4. Baíllo A, Cerisola S, Fernández-López JM, Bellido R (2006) Strategic bidding in electricity spot markets under uncertainty: a roadmap. Power Engineering Society, IEEE general meeting, 2006

    Google Scholar 

  5. Batlle C, Barroso LA, Pérez-Arriaga IJ (2010) The changing role of the state in the expansion of electricity supply in Latin America. Energy Policy 38(11):7152–7160. doi: 10.1016/j.enpol.2010.07.037

    Google Scholar 

  6. Barker J, Tenenbaum B, Woolf F (1997) Governance & regulation of power pools & system operators. An international comparison. Papers 382, World Bank—Technical Papers

    Google Scholar 

  7. Boisseleau F (2004) The role of power exchanges for the creation of a single European electricity market: market design and market regulation. PhD Thesis, University of Paris IX Dauphine, Delft University Press

    Google Scholar 

  8. Bogas JD (1998) La convergencia de gas y electricidad en el mercado energético global (Gas and electricity convergence in the global energy market, in Spanish). Economía industrial, ISSN 0422-2784, no 321, pp 111–122

    Google Scholar 

  9. EFET European Federation of Energy Traders (2007) General agreement concerning the delivery and acceptance of electricity. www.efet.org. Accessed 21 Sept 2007

  10. Energy Market Authority (2011) Vesting contracts. http://www.ema.gov.sg

  11. ERGEG European Regulators’ Group for Electricity and Gas (2006) ERGEG Guidelines of good practice for electricity balancing markets integration. Ref: E05-ESO-06-08. www.ergeg.org. Accessed 6 Dec 2006

  12. ETSO European Transmission System Operators (2003) Current state of balance management in Europe. Balance management task force. Available at www.etso-net.org. Accessed Dec 2003

  13. European Commission (2010) Interpretative note on Directive 2009/72/EC concerning common rules for the internal market in electricity and Directive 2009/73/EC concerning common rules for the internal market in natural gas. The unbundling regime. Commission staff working paper. Brussels, 22 Jan 2010

    Google Scholar 

  14. Eurostat (2012) Electricity market indicators. Available via http://epp.eurostat.ec.europa.eu

  15. Green R (2010) Are the British electricity trading and transmission arrangements future-proof? Util Policy 18(4):186–194

    Google Scholar 

  16. Helman U (2006) Market power monitoring and mitigation in the US wholesale power markets. Energy 31:877–904

    Article  Google Scholar 

  17. Hope E (2005) Market dominance and market power in electric power markets: a competition policy perspective. Norwegian School of Economics, Bergen

    Google Scholar 

  18. Joskow PL (2008) Lessons Learned from Electricity Market Liberalization. Energ J, Special Issue in Honor of David Newbery, pp 9–42

    Google Scholar 

  19. López-Velarde R, Valdez A (2008) “Mexico”. In: O’Donnell EH (ed) Electricity regulation in 31 jurisdictions worldwide. Published by Getting the Deal Through. www.gettingthedealthrough.com

  20. Milligan M, Donohoo P, Lew D, Ela E, Kirby B et al (2010) Operating reserves and wind power integration: an international comparison. Preprint. Conference Paper NREL/CP-5500-49019 Oct 2010

    Google Scholar 

  21. Newbery DM (1997) Pool reform and competition in electricity. DAE Working Paper 9734, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  22. Newbery DM, Pollitt MG (1997) The restructuring and privatisation of Britain’s Cegb. Was it worth it? J Ind Econ 45(3):269–303

    Article  Google Scholar 

  23. Newbery D, Green R, Neuhoff K, Twomey P (2004) A review of the monitoring of market power, for the European Transmission System Operators, ETSO, Nov 2004

    Google Scholar 

  24. New York Independent System Operator (2012) Ancillary Services Manual. Available at www.nyiso.com

  25. O'Neill R, Helman U, Hobbs B, Baldick R (2006) Independent system operators in the United States: History, lessons learned, and prospects. In: Sioshansi FP, Pfaenberger W (eds) International Experience in Restructured Electricity Markets: What works, what does not, and why? Elsevier, 2006

    Google Scholar 

  26. O'Neill RP, Sotkiewicz PM, Hobbs BF, Rothkopf MH, Stewart WR Jr (2005) Efficient market-clearing prices in markets with nonconvexities. Eur J Oper Res 164(1):269–285. doi:10.1016/j.ejor.2003.12.011

    Google Scholar 

  27. Pérez-Arriaga IJ, Meseguer C (1997) Wholesale marginal prices in competitive generation markets. IEEE Trans Power Syst 12(2):710–717

    Google Scholar 

  28. PJM (2012). PJM Manual 11: energy & ancillary services market operations. Revision: 51. www.pjm.com. 8 Aug 2012

  29. Rodilla P, Vázquez S, Batlle C (2012) Auction bidding, clearing and pricing schemes in day-ahead electricity markets: a comprehensive review. IIT Working Paper IIT-012-073A

    Google Scholar 

  30. Rose K (1999) Electricity competition: market power, mergers and PUHCA. NRRI, Ohio State University, 1999

    Google Scholar 

  31. Smith A (1776) An inquiry into the nature and causes of the wealth of nations. In: Cannan E (ed) 1904 Methuen and Co., Ltd., London. 5th edn. www.econlib.org/library/Smith/smWNCover.html

  32. Schweppe FC, Caramanis MC, Tabors RD, Bohn RE (1988) Spot pricing of electricity. ISBN 0-89838-260-2, Kluwer Academic Publishers, Boston

    Google Scholar 

  33. Single Electricity Market Committee (2011) Directed contracts—2011/2012. Quantification and pricing. Decision Paper. SEM-11-045. www.allislandproject.org. Accessed 17 June 2011

  34. Stoft S, Belden T, Goldman C, Pickle S (1998) Primer on electricity futures and other derivatives. Ernest Orlando Lawrence Berkeley National Laboratory, LBNL-41098, UC-1321, University of California, Jan 1998

    Google Scholar 

  35. The Brattle Group (2007) Review of PJM’s Market Power Mitigation Practices in Comparison to Other Organized Electricity Markets. Prepared for PJM Interconnection, LLC. September 14, 2007

    Google Scholar 

  36. The Electricity Pool (2001) The electricity pool. www.elecpool.com

  37. Thomas S (2006) The British model in Britain: failing slowly. Energy Policy 34:583–600

    Article  Google Scholar 

  38. UCTE Union for the Co-ordination of Transmission of Electricity (2004) UCTE operation handbook. Version 2.5, level E. www.ucte.org. Accessed 24 June 2004

  39. U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (2010) Electric generation ownership, market concentration and auction size. Technical Support Document (TSD) for the Transport Rule. Docket ID No. EPA-HQ-OAR-2009-0491. www.epa.gov. Accessed July 2010

  40. Wolak FA (1999) An empirical analysis of the impact of hedge contracts on bidding behavior in a competitive electricity market. Fourth Annual POWER Research Conference, March 5, 1999

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Carlos Batlle .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2013 Springer-Verlag London

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Batlle, C. (2013). Electricity Generation and Wholesale Markets. In: Pérez-Arriaga, I. (eds) Regulation of the Power Sector. Power Systems. Springer, London. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-1-4471-5034-3_7

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-1-4471-5034-3_7

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Springer, London

  • Print ISBN: 978-1-4471-5033-6

  • Online ISBN: 978-1-4471-5034-3

  • eBook Packages: EnergyEnergy (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics