Skip to main content
Log in

Asymmetric Collusion with Growing Demand

  • Published:
Journal of Industry, Competition and Trade Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We characterize collusion sustainability in markets where demand growth triggers the entry of a new firm whose efficiency may be different from the efficiency of the incumbents. We find that the profit-sharing rule that firms adopt to divide the cartel profit after entry is a key determinant of the incentives for collusion (before and after entry). In particular, if the incumbents and the entrant are very asymmetric, collusion without side-payments cannot be sustained. However, if firms divide joint profits through bargaining and are sufficiently patient, collusion is sustainable even if firms are very asymmetric.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7
Fig. 8
Fig. 9
Fig. 10
Fig. 11
Fig. 12
Fig. 13

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. European Commission Decision of 22 July 1992, Case n. IV/M.190 - Nestlé/Perrier.

  2. The remaining firms were small local producers with significantly lower market shares.

  3. The Nestlé-Perrier merger was only approved when Nestlé committed itself to sell some brands and capacity of water to a competitor (with no connections to Nestlé or BSN), such that this competitor had at least 3000 million liters of water per year.

  4. Our assumptions fit quite well the French industry of bottled water after the Nestlé-Perrier merger. As Compte et al. (2002), we exclude the small local producers from the analysis.

  5. As explained in Section 7.2, this assumption is only reasonable if there is only one potential entrant. Otherwise, entry occurs when the discounted sum of profits covers the entry cost.

  6. This result was already found by Schmalensee (1987). He also concluded that, under the assumption of increasing marginal costs, less efficient cartel members have positive production levels.

  7. This is why we also refer to this profit-sharing rule as proportional rule. For some motivation, see Bos and Harrington (2010) and the references cited therein. For example, Vasconcelos (2005) assumes this profit-sharing rule in his model.

  8. In our model, the growth rate of profits is equal to the square of the demand growth rate.

  9. This occurs because, individual profits when there are two competing firms are higher than when there are three colluding firms.

  10. Shaffer (1995), Etro (2008) and Vasconcelos (2008) also study collusion with cartel leadership.

  11. In the model of Capuano (2002), entry occurs when the present discounted value of the profits of the new firm is positive. We follow Vasconcelos (2008) and assume that entry occurs when the discounted flow of the profits of the entrant is maximal.

  12. There are several theoretical contributions that study collusion between firms with asymmetric costs. See, for example, Patinkin (1947), Osborne and Pitchik (1983), Bae (1987), Schmalensee (1987), Harrington (1991), Compte et al. (2002), Vasconcelos (2005) and Ganslandt et al. (2012).

  13. In a recent contribution, Phillips et al. (2011) perform laboratory experiments to analyze the scope for collusion between two firms with asymmetric production costs. They find that less efficient firm has more incentives to comply with the collusive agreement; and its willingness to collude increases with its (relative) inefficiency.

  14. See Davidson and Deneckere (1984), Lambson (1995) and Compte et al. (2002).

  15. For further discussion on this topic, see, for example, Compte et al. (2002).

  16. Osborne and Pitchik (1983) assume that the two firms produce at a constant unit cost up to their capacities but have different capacities.

  17. According to the “balanced temptation rule”, all (asymmetric) firms have the same incentives to deviate. More precisely, the minimum discount factor that sustains collusion is the same for all firms.

  18. Capuano (2002) assumes a similar demand function.

  19. We consider a simplified version of the cost function proposed by Perry and Porter (1985).

  20. In Section 4.2, we carefully explain how we obtain the (optimal) entry period.

  21. This lower bound for F is derived in Appendix C.

  22. These information assumptions, despite relatively strong, are necessary for the sake of tractability.

  23. Appendix B derives the expressions for equilibrium profits.

  24. This assumption is only plausible if there is one single potential entrant in the market. Otherwise, entry occurs when the discounted flow of the profits of the new firm covers the fixed entry cost (even if, in the end, only one firm becomes active). This occurs because if one firm waits to enter until the discounted flow of its profits is maximal, another firm will enter beforehand. In Section 7.2, we discuss the case in which entry occurs when the present discounted value of the profits of the entrant becomes positive.

  25. Assumption 2 ensures that t͂ c ≥ 1.

  26. When perfect collusion is not possible, Vasconcelos (2008) considers that firms make a weaker collusive agreement in which their joint profits are lower than the monopoly profit. More precisely, Vasconcelos (2008) restrains quantities to satisfy the incentive compatibility constraints. To make a similar analysis in the context of our model would be very difficult, since the assumption of asymmetric firms complicates the expressions for profits.

  27. In Section 7.1, we analyze the case in which incumbents exclude the entrant from their agreement (partial collusion).

  28. To participate in the punishment is rational, because the best-response of one firm, if the other firms play the Cournot equilibrium actions, is to produce its own Cournot equilibrium action.

  29. The differences between their article and ours are clear, since they consider that the incumbents and the entrant are symmetric, supporting zero marginal production costs. They find that, in contrast to grim trigger strategies, optimal penal codes make collusion easier to sustain before entry than after.

  30. We derive the expression for t͂ m in Section 5.1.4.

  31. For more details, see Appendix B.2.2.

  32. A similar analysis can be done for the case in which incumbents are more efficient than the entrant.

  33. Davidson and Deneckere (1984), Lambson (1995) and Compte et al. (2002) also find that asymmetry hinders collusion.

  34. Rubinstein (1982) considers a dynamic version of the bargaining process. In each period, one player proposes an agreement that may be accepted or rejected by the other player. If players reach an agreement, the bargaining process stops; otherwise, there is another bargaining round. Building on this work, Binmore et al. (1986) incorporate imperfections in the bargaining process that make delays in the bargaining costly to players (either because players discount the future, or because there is an exogenous risk of players never reaching an agreement). As players become increasingly patient, the solution of this “alternating offers” game converges to the static Nash bargaining solution. O’Brien (2002) uses this kind of bargaining to analyze the effects of price discrimination in vertically integrated markets.

  35. An asymmetric version of this problem would correspond to the maximization of \(\left (\beta _{1t} \Pi _{t}^{m3}-\Pi _{1t}^{c3}\right )^{\theta }\) \(\left (\beta _{2t} \Pi _{t}^{m3}-\Pi _{2t}^{c3}\right )^{\theta } \left (\beta _{3t} \Pi _{t}^{m3}-\Pi _{3t}^{c3}\right )^{1-\theta }\), where a higher 𝜃 would give more relative bargaining power to the incumbents. We consider the particular case of \(\theta =\frac {1}{3}\). For further discussion on this subject, see, for example, Roth (1979) and Binmore et al. (1986).

  36. In a different setting, Osborne and Pitchik (1983) also find that when firms adopt the Nash bargaining rule to divide the monopoly profit, “the balance of forces is in favor to the small firm” (p. 60).

  37. Recall that we are assuming that the output allocation along the collusive path is the same with and without side-payments. Thus, if firms produce the same and receive different profits, there must exist side-payments to implement the Nash bargaining rule.

  38. This corresponds to a negative critical discount factor (Fig. 4).

  39. Analytical expressions for profit shares under competition and collusion with the Nash bargaining rule are, respectively, given in Eqs. 36 and 45. Shares under collusion without side-payments are equal to k i .

  40. The expression for t͂ m is greater than 1, since F satisfies Assumption 2.

  41. All steps necessary to obtain this inequality can be found in the proof of Lemma 1.

  42. See, for example, Neven et al. (1993), Motta (2000), Compte et al. (2002), Motta et al. (2003), Motta (2004), (Feuerstein 2005) or Olczak (2009).

  43. The European Commission requested Nestlé to sell some brands of the post-merged group in order to “facilitate the entry of a viable competitor with adequate resources [...] or the increase in the capacity of an existing competitor so that [...] such competitor could effectively compete on the French bottled water market with Nestlé and BSN” (recital 136). Another condition imposed was that Nestlé and Perrier should work under separate holding until the divestiture took place. As a result, in the periods that immediately followed the merger, Nestlé-Perrier and BSN-Volvic did not own equal capacities of water. They only became symmetric after the divestiture. Our model does not take this aspect into account, since the incumbents are symmetric in all periods before entry. This assumption simplifies the analysis because: (i) it trivializes the profit-sharing before entry; and (ii) capital shares (of the incumbents) are constant over time. Furthermore, our model does not capture that the entry of a new firm is a source of revenues to one of the incumbents.

  44. In recital 129 of the European Commission Decision, we can read “[l]ocal spring and mineral waters are too small and dispersed to constitute a significant alternative to the national waters.”

  45. In Fig. 9, we have assumed F = 1. This implies that, if μ = 1. 05 and δ = 0. 8, firm 3 enters the market at period t͂ N = 18 or t͂ c = 19. As we confirm in Appendix A, changes in F do not modify the qualitative results.

  46. Escrihuela-Villar (2009, 2011) also consider these two scenarios of partial collusion in an infinitely repeated game. These models are different from ours since they assume stable demand and no entry. Their aim is at studying the impact of cartel leadership on cartel formation and stability.

  47. Expressions for profits are derived in Appendix B.2.2.2.

  48. Here, V pc(t) denotes the present discounted value of the profits of the entrant if it enters in period t and its single-period profit is given by Eq. 24.

  49. In a model of mergers under price competition with differentiated goods, Deneckere and Davidson (1985) also found that cooperation may be more profitable to the outsiders than to the insiders.

  50. The expression for the one-shot deviation profit, \(\Pi _{it}^{pdc3}\), is derived in Appendix B.3.2.2.

  51. The optimal entry period along the punishment path is given by Eq. 6.

  52. For static analyses of cartel leadership, see Donsimoni (1985), Donsimoni et al. (1986), Shaffer (1995) and Escrihuela-Villar (2011).

  53. These expressions are derived in Appendix B.2.2.3.

  54. An alternative scenario for the punishment path could be to consider that, even though a deviation triggers non-cooperation between the incumbents, they do not lose leadership. This would imply that, in each period following a deviation, the incumbents’ output is chosen simultaneously but before the entrant makes its output decision. This scenario is, however, outside the scope of this paper and left for future research.

  55. Recall that t j would be the optimal entry period in market regime j ∈ {c, m} if time were a continuous variable.

  56. When addressing the potential coordinated effects of a proposed merger, antitrust authorities investigate whether the structural change implied by a merger creates more favorable conditions for collusion to arise between the remaining firms in the industry.

  57. In this case, the two profit-sharing rules coincide.

  58. This condition corresponds to ICC (26).

References

  • Abreu D (1986) Extremal equilibria of oligopolistic supergames. J Econ Theory 39(1):191–225

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bae H (1987) A price-setting supergame between two heterogeneous firms. Eur Econ Rev 31(6):1159–1171

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bain JS (1948) Output quotas in imperfect cartels. Q J Econ 62(4):617–622

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Benoit J-P, Krishna V (1987) Dynamic duopoly: prices and quantities. Rev Econ Stud 54(1):23–35

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Binmore K, Rubinstein A, Wolinsky A (1986) The Nash bargaining solution in economic modelling. RAND J Econ 17(2):176–188

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bos I, Harrington JE (2010) Endogenous cartel formation with heterogeneous firms. RAND J Econ 41(1):92–117

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brock WA, Scheinkman JA (1985) Price setting supergames with capacity constraints. Rev Econ Stud 52(3):371–382

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Capuano C (2002) Demand growth, entry and collusion sustainability. Fondazione Eni Enrico Mattei Working Paper 62

  • Compte O, Jenny F, Rey P (2002) Capacity constraints, mergers and collusion. Eur Econ Rev 46(1):1–29

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Correia-da-Silva J, Pinho J, Vasconcelos H (2013) Cartel stability and profits under different reactions to entry in markets with growing demand. FEP Working Papers 487

  • Davidson C, Deneckere R (1984) Horizontal mergers and collusive behavior. Int J Ind Organ 2(2): 117–132

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Davies S, Olczak M (2008) Tacit versus overt collusion firm asymmetries and numbers: what’s the evidence? ESRC Centre for Competition Policy Working Paper, (08–32)

  • Deneckere R, Davidson C (1985) Incentives to form coalitions with Bertrand competition. RAND J Econ 473–486

  • Donsimoni M-P (1985) Stable heterogeneous cartels. Int J Ind Organ 3(4):451–467

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Donsimoni M-P, Economides NS, Polemarchakis HM (1986) Stable cartels. Int Econ Rev 2(27):317–327

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Escrihuela-Villar M (2009) A note on cartel stability and endogenous sequencing with tacit collusion. J Econ 96(2):137–147

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Escrihuela-Villar M (2011) Does cartel leadership facilitate collusion. J Econ Resour 16:85–95

    Google Scholar 

  • Etro F (2008) Stackelberg competition with endogenous entry. Econ J 118(532):1670–1697

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Feuerstein S (2005) Collusion in industrial economics - a survey. J Ind Compet Trade 5(3–4):163–198

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Friedman JW (1971) A non-cooperative equilibrium for supergames. Rev Econ Stud 38(1):1–12

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ganslandt M, Persson L, Vasconcelos H (2012) Endogenous mergers and collusion in asymmetric market structures. Economica 79(316):766–791

    Google Scholar 

  • Grout P, Sonderegger S (2005) Predicting cartels. Office of Fair Trading, United Kingdom

    Google Scholar 

  • Harrington JE Jr (1991) The determination of price and output quotas in a heterogeneous cartel. Int Econ Rev 32(4):767–792

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ivaldi M, Jullien B, Rey P, Seabright P, Tirole J (2003) The economics of tacit collusion. IDEI Working Paper 186

  • Knittel CR, Lepore JJ (2010) Tacit collusion in the presence of cyclical demand and endogenous capacity levels. Int J Ind Organ 28(2):131–144

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lambson VE (1995) Optimal penal codes in nearly symmetric Bertrand supergames with capacity constraints. J Math Econ 24(1):1–22

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mason CF, Phillips OR (2002) In support of trigger strategies: experimental evidence from two-person noncooperative games. J Econ Manag Strategy 11(4):685–716

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Miklós-Thal J (2011) Optimal collusion under cost asymmetry. Econ Theory 46(1):99–125

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Motta M (2000) EC merger policy and the Airtours case. Eur Compet Law Rev 21(4):199–207

    Google Scholar 

  • Motta M (2004) Competition policy: theory and practice. Cambridge University Press

  • Motta M, Polo M, Vasconcelos H (2003) Merger remedies in the european union: an overview. In: Leveque F, Shelanski H (eds) Merger remedies in American and european union competition law. Edward Elgar Publishing, Northampton

  • Nash J (1953) Two-person cooperative games. Econometrica J Econ Soc 21(1):128–140

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Neven DJ, Nuttall R, Seabright P (1993) Merger in daylight: the economics and politics of European merger control. Centre for Economic Policy Research, London

    Google Scholar 

  • O’Brien D (2002) The welfare effects of third degree price discrimination in intermediate good markets: the base of bargaining. FTC Bureau of Economics Working Paper 245

  • Olczak M (2009) Unilateral versus coordinated effects: comparing the impact on consumer welfare of alternative merger outcomes. ESRC Centre for Competition Policy Working Paper

  • Osborne MJ, Pitchik C (1983) Profit-sharing in a collusive industry. Eur Econ Rev 22(1):59–74

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Patinkin D (1947) Multiple-plant firms, cartels, and imperfect competition. Q J Econ 61(2):173–205

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Perry MK, Porter RH (1985) Oligopoly and the incentive for horizontal merger. Am Econ Rev 75(1):219–227

    Google Scholar 

  • Phillips OR, Menkhaus DJ, Thurow JN (2011) The small firm in a quantity choosing game: some experimental evidence. Rev Ind Organ 38(2):191–207

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Roth A (1979) Axiomatic models of bargaining. Springer-Verlag, Berlin

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Rubinstein A (1982) Perfect equilibrium in a bargaining model. Econometrica J Econ Soc 50(1):97–109

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Salant SW, Switzer S, Reynolds RJ (1983) Losses from horizontal merger: the effects of an exogenous change in industry structure on Cournot-Nash equilibrium. Q J Econ 98(2):185–199

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schmalensee R (1987) Competitive advantage and collusive optima. Int J Ind Organ 5(4):351–367

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shaffer S (1995) Stable cartels with a Cournot fringe. South Econ J 61(3):744–754

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stigler GJ (1950) Monopoly and oligopoly by merger. Am Econ Rev 40(2):23–34

    Google Scholar 

  • Vasconcelos H (2005) Tacit collusion, cost asymmetries, and mergers. RAND J Econ 36(1):39–62

    Google Scholar 

  • Vasconcelos H (2008) Sustaining collusion in growing markets. J Econ Manag Strategy 17(4):973–1010

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

We are grateful to Paul Belleflamme, Pedro Pita Barros, Joseph Harrington, and, specially, João Correia-da-Silva for their helpful comments. We also thank the Editor, Michael Peneder, and three anonymous referees for their useful suggestions. We acknowledge the financial support from Fundação para a Ciência e Tecnologia (PTDC/IIM-ECO/5294/2012). We thank the participants in the 39th EARIE Annual Conference in Rome, the 6th Meeting of the Portuguese Economic Journal in Porto, the 6th Economic Theory Workshop in Vigo, the 2012 UECE Lisbon Meeting on Game Theory and Applications and a seminar at U. Vigo. Joana Pinho acknowledges the support from Fundação para a Ciência e Tecnologia (BPD/79535/2011).

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Joana Pinho.

Appendices

Appendix A: Model Simulations

In this Appendix, we study whether the distribution of the industry capital across firms, k, and the magnitude of the fixed entry cost, F, qualitatively affect the sustainability of collusion before and after entry.

Looking at ICC (9), we conclude that the magnitude of F has no direct impact on collusion sustainability after entry (regardless of the profit-sharing rule). Moreover, the magnitude of F only affects the incentives for collusion before entry if it changes the ability of incumbents to delay entry by disrupting the collusive agreement, i.e., to change t͂ c t͂ m , with m ∈ {N, p}. Using Eq. 31, we conclude that, if time were a continuous variable, the value of F would have no impact on incentives for collusion before entry (since t c t m does not depend on F). However, the magnitude of F may be relevant because time is discrete. Table 1 shows how many periods the entrant delays its entry if it expects to compete (rather than collude) with incumbents after entry.

Table 1 Difference between entry periods under competition and collusion with the Nash bargaining rule and without side-payments, \((\tilde {t}_c-\tilde {t}_{N},\tilde {t}_c-\tilde {t}_p)\), for k = 0.4

Regarding the value of k, there is no doubt that it affects conditions for collusion sustainability before and after entry. Analyzing Fig. 7, we conclude that: the more symmetric are the incumbents and the entrant, the more sustainable is the collusive agreement after entry. Furthermore, if firms are quite asymmetric, collusion is impossible in the absence of side-payments. It is not so straightforward to guess the impact of k on the ICC for collusion sustainability before entry, (22), since a change on k affects expressions for the profits and the entry periods. Using Eq. 31, we can show that the more efficient are the incumbents (i.e., the higher is the value of k), the higher is t c t m . Typically, the entry delay, t͂ c t͂ m , will also increase in k, which makes collusion more difficult to sustain.

1.1 A.1 Collusion with the Nash Bargaining Rule

If firms adopt the Nash bargaining rule to share their joint profits after entry, collusion after entry is sustainable for all values of k ∈, as long as the discount factor is sufficiently high.

Below, we plot the ICCs for collusion sustainability (before and after entry) when k = 0. 1, \(k=\frac {1}{3}\) and k = 0. 45, in order to cover three different scenarios: (i) the incumbents are significantly more efficient than the entrant; (ii) the three firms are symmetric;Footnote 57 and (iii) the entrant is significantly more efficient than the incumbents.

Analyzing in Fig. 14, we conclude that a significant increase in the fixed entry cost, F, has a small impact on conditions for collusion sustainability before and after entry. An increase in F only accentuates the erratic behavior of the critical discount factor for collusion sustainability before entry. In particular, there are some pairs (δ, μ), for which collusion is sustainable before entry with F = 10 but not sustainable with F = 1 (more evident when k = 0. 1).

Fig. 14
figure 14

Collusion sustainability when firm adopt the Nash bargaining rule after entry

We also find that a change of the distribution on industry capital, k, has a non-monotonic effect on collusion sustainability after entry, since the dashed line (corresponding to the ICC for collusion sustainability after entry) moves: (i) to the left, when k increases from 0. 1 to \(\frac {1}{3}\); and (ii) to the right, when k increases from \(\frac {1}{3}\) to 0. 45. This finding supports the evolution of the critical discount factor observed in Fig. 7. For parameters in regions E of Fig. 14a, b, collusion could be sustainable before entry, but the cartel would break down after entry. However, this only seems to happen when the entrant is significantly more efficient than the incumbents.

1.2 A.2 Collusion Without Side-Payments

Recall that collusion without side-payments is only possible after entry if k ∈ (0. 199, 0. 436). As, in Section 6, we considered k = 0. 4, we will only plot conditions for collusion sustainability when k = 0. 25 (Fig. 15).

Fig. 15
figure 15

Collusion sustainability when firms make no side-payments after entry (k = 0.25)

Simulations in this Appendix allow us to conclude that, as long as firms are not too asymmetric, collusion is sustainable before and after entry with both the profit-sharing rules (after entry). In addition, it is not possible to say whether collusion is easier to sustain before or after entry: it depends on the demand growth rate, the discount factor, the value of k and the profit-sharing rule after entry.

Appendix B: Determination of Profits

1.1 B.1 Cournot Competition

1.1.1 B.1.1 Before Entry

Suppose that, in period t before entry, the two incumbents are competing in quantities. In this case, incumbent i ∈ {1, 2} chooses the quantity that maximizes its individual profit:

$$\pi_{it}^{c2}(q_{it}, q_{jt})=[\mu^{t}-(q_{it}+q_{jt})]q_{it}-\frac{q_{it}^{2}}{2k} ,$$

with ji and j ∈ {1, 2}. The corresponding first-oder condition is:

$$ -2 q_{it}-\frac{q_{it}}{k}-q_{jt}+\mu ^t=0.$$
(32)

Similarly, the first-order condition of the maximization problem of firm j is:

$$ -2 q_{jt}-\frac{q_{jt}}{k}-q_{it}+\mu ^t=0.$$
(33)

Combining Eqs. 32 and 33, we obtain the equilibrium output incumbent i in period t:

$$q_{it}^{c2}=\frac{k}{1+3k}\mu ^{t} .$$

The corresponding profit is:

$$\Pi_{it}^{c2}=\frac{k(1+2 k)}{2(1+3 k)^{2}}\mu^{2t}.$$

1.1.2 B.1.2 After Entry

Suppose now that the incumbents and the entrant compete in quantities in period t. Incumbent i ∈ {1, 2} chooses the quantity that maximizes:

$$\pi_{it}^{c3}\left(q_{it},q_{jt}, q_{lt}\right)= \left[\mu^{t}- (q_{it}+q_{jt}+q_{lt})\right]q_{it}-\frac{q_{it}^{2}}{2k}.$$

The corresponding first-order condition is:

$$ -2 q_{it}-\frac{q_{it}}{k}-q_{jt}-q_{lt}+\mu^t=0 .$$
(34)

The profit function of the entrant is given by:

$$\pi_{3t}^{c3}\left(q_{it},q_{jt}, q_{3t}\right)= \left[\mu^{t}- (q_{it}+q_{jt}+q_{3t})\right]q_{3t}-\frac{q_{3t}^{2}}{2(1-2k)} .$$

Thus, the corresponding first-order condition is:

$$ -q_{it}-q_{jt}-2q_{3t}-\frac{q_{3t}}{1-2 k}+\mu ^t=0 .$$
(35)

Combining the best-reply functions of the three firms, we obtain:

$$q_{1t}^{c3}=q_{2t}^{c3}=\frac{2 (1-k) k }{3+3 k-8 k^{2}}\mu ^{t}\quad \text{and} \quad q_{3t}^{c3}=\frac{(1+k) (1-2 k) }{3+3 k-8 k^{2}} \mu ^t.$$

Market shares of incumbent i ∈ {1, 2} and the entrant are constant over time and, respectively, given by:

$$\lambda_{i}^{c3}=\frac{q_{it}^{c3}}{2q_{it}^{c3}+q_{3t}^{c3}}=\frac{2 (1-k) k}{1+3 k-6 k^{2}} \quad \text{and} \quad \lambda_{3}^{c3}=\frac{(1+k) (1-2 k)}{1+3 k-6 k^{2}}.$$
(36)

Finally, individual profits are:

$$ \Pi_{it}^{c3}=\frac{2k(1+2k)(1-k)^{2}}{\left(3+3k-8k^{2}\right)^{2}}\mu^{2 t} \quad \text{and} \quad \Pi_{3t}^{c3}=\frac{(1+k)^{2} \left(3-10k+8k^{2}\right) }{2 \left(3+3k-8k^{2}\right)^{2}}\mu^{2t} .$$
(37)

1.2 B.2 Collusion

1.2.1 B.2.1 Before Entry

If the incumbents collude in period t before entry, they produce the quantities that maximize:

$$ \pi_{t}^{m2}\left(q_{1t},q_{2t}\right)=\left[\mu^t-\left(q_{1t}+q_{2t}\right)\right](q_{1t}+q_{2t})-\left(\frac{{q_{1t}}^{2}}{2 k}+\frac{{q_{2t}}^{2}}{2k}\right) .$$
(38)

Solving the corresponding first-order conditions, we obtain:

$$\left\{ \begin{array}{l} \mu^t-2q_{1t}-2q_{2t}-\frac{q_{1t}}{k}=0 \\ \mu^t-2q_{1t}-2q_{2t}-\frac{q_{2t}}{k}=0 \end{array} \right . \quad \Leftrightarrow \quad q_{1t}^{m2}=q_{2t}^{m2}=\frac{k}{1+4k}\mu ^{t} .$$

Substituting these quantities in Eq. 38 and dividing it by two, we obtain the collusive profit of incumbent i:

$$\Pi_{it}^{m2}=\frac{k}{2(1+4k)} \mu^{2t}.$$

1.2.2 B.2.2 After Entry

B.2.2.1 Full collusion without side-payments

If the three firms maximize joint profits in period t, they produce quantities that maximize:

$$\pi_{t}^{m3}\left(q_{1t}, q_{2t}, q_{3t}\right)\,=\,\left[\mu^{t}\,-\,\left(q_{1t}\,+\,q_{2t}\,+\,q_{3t}\right)\right]\left(q_{1t}\,+\,q_{2t}\,+\,q_{3t}\right)\,-\,\left[\frac{{q_{1t}}^{2}}{2 k}\,+\,\frac{{q_{2t}}^{2}}{2k}\,+\,\frac{{q_{3t}}^{2}}{2(1\,-\,2k)}\right].$$
(39)

Solving the corresponding first-order conditions, we find the collusive output levels:

$$\left\{ \begin{array}{l} -2 q_{1t}-\frac{q_{1t}}{k}-2q_{2t}-2q_{3t}+\mu^t=0 \\ -2q_{1t}-2 q_{2t}-\frac{q_{2t}}{k}-2q_{3t}+\mu^t=0 \\ -2q_{1t}-2q_{2t}-2q_{3t}-\frac{q_{3t}}{1-2k}+\mu^t=0 \end{array} \right . \quad \Leftrightarrow \left\{ \begin{array}{l} q_{1t}^{m3}=q_{2t}^{m3}=\frac{k}{3}\mu ^{t} \\ q_{3t}^{m3}= \frac{1-2k}{3}\mu ^t\end{array} \right. . $$

Substituting them in Eq. 39, we obtain the profit of the cartel \(\Pi _{t}^{m3}=\frac {\mu ^{2t}}{6}\).

B.2.2.2 Partial collusion with simultaneous moves

Consider that the incumbents do not include the entrant in their agreement. Assume further that the cartel and the entrant simultaneously choose quantities. In this case, the incumbents set quantities such to maximize:

$$\pi_{t}^{pc3}\left(q_{1t},q_{2t}\right)=\left(\mu ^t-q_{1t}-q_{2t}-q_{3t}\right)\left(q_{1t}+q_{2t}\right)-\frac{q_{1t}^{2}}{2k}-\frac{q_{2t}^{2}}{2k},$$

while the entrant chooses the quantity that maximizes its individual profit:

$$\pi_{3t}^{pc3}(q_{3t})=\left(\mu ^t-q_{1t}-q_{2t}-q_{3t}\right)q_{3t}-\frac{q_{3t}^{2}}{2(1-2k)}.$$

Combining the best-response functions, we obtain:

$$\left\{ \begin{array}{l} -2 q_{1t}-\frac{q_{1t}}{k}-2 q_{2t}-q_{3t}+\mu^{t} =0 \\ -2 q_{1t}-2 q_{2t}-\frac{q_{2t}}{k}-q_{3t}+\mu ^t=0 \\ -q_{1t}-q_{2t}-2 q_{3t}-\frac{q_{3t}}{1-2 k}+\mu ^t=0 \end{array} \right. \Leftrightarrow \left\{ \begin{array}{l} q_{1t}=q_{2t}=\frac{2k(1-k) }{3 \left(1+2 k-4 k^{2}\right)}\mu ^{t} \\ q_{3t}=\frac{(1-2 k) (1+2 k)}{3 \left(1+2 k-4 k^{2}\right)}\mu ^{t} . \end{array} \right.$$

The corresponding profits of incumbent i ∈ {1, 2} and the entrant in period t are:

$$\Pi_{it}^{pc3}=\frac{2 k(1-k)^{2} (1+4 k)}{9 \left(1+2 k-4 k^{2}\right)^{2}} \mu^{2 t} \quad \text{and} \quad \Pi_{3t}^{pc3}=\frac{(1+2 k)^{2} \left(3-10 k+8 k^{2}\right)}{18 \left(1+2 k-4 k^{2}\right)^{2}} \mu^{2 t}.$$
(40)

B.2.2.3 Partial collusion with sequential moves

Consider that the incumbents do not include the entrant in the collusive agreement and the cartel behaves as a Stackelberg leader while the entrant is a follower. The entrant produces the quantity that maximizes:

$$\pi_{3t}^{ps3}\left(q_{1t}, q_{2t}, q_{3t}\right)=\left[\mu^t-\left(q_{1t}+q_{2t}+q_{3t}\right)\right]q_{3t}-\frac{q_{3t}^{2}}{2(1-2k)} .$$

Its best-response function to the output of the cartel (formed by the two incumbents) is:

$$q_{3t}\left(q_{1t},q_{2t}\right)=\frac{1-2 k}{3-4 k}\left(\mu^t-q_{1t}-q_{2t}\right) .$$
(41)

Incumbents choose quantities that maximize their joint profits, given the best-response function of firm 3:

$$\begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} \pi_{t}^{ps3}\left(q_{1t},q_{2t}\right) &=& \frac{2(1-k)}{3-4k}\left(\mu^t-q_{1t}-q_{2t}\right)\left(q_{1t}+q_{2t}\right)-\left(\frac{q_{1t}^{2}}{2k}+\frac{q_{2t}^{2}}{2k}\right). \end{array}$$

The corresponding first-order conditions are:

$$\left\{ \begin{array}{l} -q_{1t}-\frac{q_{1t}}{k}-q_{2t}+\left(-1+\frac{1-2 k}{3-4 k}\right) \left(q_{1t}+q_{2t}\right)+\mu ^t-\frac{1-2 k}{3-4 k}\left(-q_{1t}-q_{2t}+\mu ^{t}\right)=0 \\ -q_{1t}-q_{2t}-\frac{q_{2t}}{k}+\left(-1+\frac{1-2 k}{3-4 k}\right) \left(q_{1t}+q_{2t}\right)+\mu ^t-\frac{1-2k}{3-4k}\left(-q_{1t}-q_{2t}+\mu ^{t}\right)=0 , \end{array} \right .$$

whose solution is:

$$q_{1t}^{ps3}=q_{2t}^{ps3}=\frac{2k(1-k)}{3+4 k-8 k^{2}}\mu ^t.$$
(42)

Substituting these quantities in the best-response function of firm 3, we obtain:

$$q_{3t}^{ps3}=\frac{(1-2 k)\left(3-4 k^{2}\right)}{(3-4 k)\left(3+4 k-8 k^{2}\right)}\mu ^t.$$

As a result, the profit of the incumbent i ∈ {1, 2} and of the entrant in period t are, respectively:

$$\Pi_{it}^{ps3}=\frac{2k(1-k)^{2}}{9-40 k^2+32 k^{3}}\mu^{2t} \quad \text{and} \quad \Pi_{3t}^{ps3}=\frac{(1-2 k) \left(3-4 k^{2}\right)^{2}}{2 (3-4 k) \left(3+4 k-8 k^{2}\right)^{2}}\mu^{2 t} .$$

1.3 B.3 Deviation

1.3.1 B.3.1 Before Entry

If incumbent i ∈ {1, 2} deviates from the collusive agreement in period t, it produces the quantity that maximizes:

$$\pi_{it}^{d2}\left(q_{it}\right)=\left[\mu^{t}-\left(q_{it}+\frac{k}{1+4k}\mu ^{t} \right)\right]q_{it}-\frac{q_{it}^{2}}{2k} .$$
(43)

Solving the corresponding first-order condition, we obtain:

$$ -2 q_{it}-\frac{q_{it}}{k}+\mu ^t-\frac{k}{1+4 k}\mu ^t=0 \ \Leftrightarrow \ q_{it}^{d2}=\frac{k (1+3 k)}{1+6 k+8 k^{2}} \mu ^{t} .$$

Substituting this quantity in Eq. 43, we obtain:

$$\Pi_{it}^{d2}=\frac{k (1+3 k)^{2}}{2 (1+2 k) (1+4 k)^{2}} \mu^{2 t}.$$

1.3.2 B.3.2 After Entry

B.3.2.1 Full collusion

Consider that the three firms are colluding and firm i ∈ {1, 2, 3} defects in period t. It produces the quantity that maximizes:

$$\pi_{it}^{d3}(q_{it})=\left[\mu^{t}-\left(q_{it}+\frac{k_{j}}{3} \mu ^t+\frac{1-k_i-k_{j}}{3} \mu ^{t} \right)\right]q_{it}- \frac{q_{it}^{2}}{2 k_{i}} ,$$

with ji and j ∈ {1, 2, 3}. Solving the corresponding first-order condition, we find the deviating output:

$$-2 q_{it}+\mu ^t-\frac{q_{it}}{k_{i}}-\frac{1-k_i-k_{j}}{3} \mu ^{t} -\frac{k_{j}}{3} \mu ^{t} =0 \quad \Leftrightarrow \quad q_{it}^{d3}=\frac{ k_{i} \left(2+k_{i}\right)}{3 \left(1+2 k_{i}\right)} \mu ^t.$$

Thus, the deviating profit is:

$$\Pi_{it}^{d3}=\frac{k_{i}(2+k_i)^{2}}{18(1+2k_i)}\mu^{2t}.$$

B.3.2.2 Partial collusion with simultaneous moves

If incumbent i ∈ {1, 2} deviates in period t from the partial collusive agreement (under Cournot competition with the entrant), it produces the quantity that maximizes:

$$\pi_{it}^{pdc}(q_{it})= \left[\mu^t-q_{it}-\frac{2 (1-k) k}{3 \left(1+2 k-4 k^{2}\right)} \mu ^t-\frac{(1-2 k) (1+2 k)}{3 \left(1+2 k-4 k^{2}\right)}\mu ^{t}\right]q_{it}-\frac{q_{it}^{2}}{2 k}.$$

Solving the corresponding first-order condition, we obtain:

$$-2 q_{it}\,-\,\frac{q_{it}}{k}\,+\,\mu^{t}\,-\,\frac{2 (1\,-\,k) k}{3 \left(1\,+\,2 k\,-\,4 k^{2}\right)}\mu ^{t}\,-\,\frac{(1\,-\,2 k) (1\,+\,2 k) }{3 \left(1\,+\,2 k\,-\,4 k^{2}\right)}\mu ^{t}\,=\,0 \Leftrightarrow q_{it}\,=\,\frac{2 k \left(1\,+\,2 k\,-\,3 k^{2}\right)}{3 \left(1\,+\,4 k\,-\,8 k^{3}\right)} \mu ^t.$$

Therefore, the one-shot deviation profit is:

$$\Pi_{it}^{pdc3}=\frac{2 k \left(1+2 k-3 k^{2}\right)^{2} }{9 (1+2 k) \left(1+2 k-4 k^{2}\right)^{2}} \mu^{2 t}.$$
(44)

B.3.2.3 Partial collusion with sequential moves

Suppose that, in period t after entry, the incumbent i ∈ {1, 2} deviates. This firm makes its choice taking into account that the other incumbent will produce the collusive output level, but the entrant (playing after the incumbents) will play its best-response to the new level jointly produced by the incumbents. More precisely, if the incumbent i produces \(q_{it}^{ds3}\) and the other incumbent produces \(q_{jt}^{ps3}\), given by Eq. 42, the best-response function of the entrant is:

$$q_{3t}(q_{it})=\frac{1-2 k}{3-4k}\left(q_{it}+\frac{3+2k-6k^{2}}{3+4k-8 k^{2}} \mu^{t}\right).$$

The deviating incumbent maximizes its individual profit, given the best-reply function of the entrant and that the other incumbent produces \(q_{jt}^{ps3}\):

$$\pi_{it}^{dps3}(q_{it})=\left[\mu^t-q_{it}-\frac{2k(1-k)}{3+4 k-8 k^{2}}\mu ^t-\frac{1-2 k}{3-4k}\left(q_{it}+\frac{3+2k-6k^{2}}{3+4k-8 k^{2}} \mu^{t}\right)\right] q_{it}-\frac{q_{it}^{2}}{2k}.$$

Solving the corresponding first-order condition, we obtain:

$$q_{it}^{dps3}=\frac{2k(1-k) \left(3+2 k-6 k^{2}\right)\mu^{t}}{\left(3-4 k^{2}\right) \left(3+4 k-8 k^{2}\right)},$$

and the corresponding deviation profit is:

$$\Pi_{it}^{dps3}=\frac{2k(1-k)^{2}\left(3+2k-6 k^{2}\right)^{2}}{(3-4 k) \left(3-4k^{2}\right)\left(3+4 k-8k^{2}\right)^{2}}\mu^{2t}.$$

Appendix C: Proofs

1.1 Lower Bound for the Entry Cost (F)

Start by noticing that: if the entrant does not enter at t = 0 when incumbents are colluding, it does not enter at t = 0 if incumbents are competing. As a result, we only need to ensure that the present discounted value of the profits if entry occurs (under collusion) at period t = 1 exceeds the corresponding value at period t = 0. Using Eq. 17, we find that:

$$V^{m}(1)>V^{m}(0) \Leftrightarrow \beta_{3} \frac{\mu^{2} \delta}{1-\mu^{2} \delta} -\delta F > \beta_{3} \frac{1}{1-\mu^{2} \delta} - F \Leftrightarrow F> \frac{\beta_{3}}{1-\delta},$$

where β 3 denotes the share of the entrant in the monopoly profit. Looking at Fig. 6b, we conclude that β 3 > 0.9 −2k, ∀k. Substituting in the inequality above, we obtain:

$$F> \frac{0.9-2k}{1-\delta} = \frac{9-20k}{10(1-\delta)}.$$

Proof of Proposition 1

Firm 3 enters the market in the period that maximizes V c. If t was continuous, the optimal entry period would satisfy the following first-order condition:

$$\alpha_{33} \frac{\mu^{2t} \delta^{t}}{1-\mu^{2} \delta} ln {\left(\mu^{2} \delta\right)} -F \delta^{t} ln(\delta) =0 \ \Leftrightarrow \ t_c= \frac{1}{2 ln (\mu)} ln \left[ \frac{ln(\delta)}{ln\left(\mu^{2} \delta\right)} \frac{F\left(1-\mu^{2} \delta\right)}{\alpha_{33}}\right] .$$

As this expression may not be integer, the entrant must compare the value of V c in the two integers closest to t c . □

Proof of Proposition 2

The critical (adjusted) discount factor for incumbent i ∈ {1, 2} to abide by the collusive agreement is greater than one if:

$$\begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} \mu^{2}\tilde{\delta}_{ip}(k)>1 \Leftrightarrow \frac{\gamma_{3i}-\frac{k}{6}}{\gamma_{3i}-\alpha_{3i}} >1 \Leftrightarrow \frac{k \left(-3+18 k-3 k^2-72 k^3+64 k^{4}\right)}{6 \left(3+3k-8k^{2}\right)^{2}} <0 . \end{array}$$

As \(k \in \left (0, \frac {1}{2}\right )\), the last inequality is equivalent to f(k) ≡ − 3 + 18k − 3k 2 − 72k 3 + 64k 4 < 0. The roots of the first-order derivative of f are:

$$k_1=\frac{3-\sqrt{393}}{64}<0 \quad \vee \quad k_2= \frac{3+\sqrt{393}}{64} \quad \vee \quad k_3= \frac{3}{4}>\frac{1}{2} .$$

Thus, f ’ is positive for k ∈ (0, k 2) and negative for k ∈ (k 2, 1 / 2). This implies that f is strictly increasing in (0, k 2) and it (strictly) decreasing in (k 2, 1 / 2). Moreover,

$$f(0)<0, \quad f(k_2)>0 \quad \text{and} \quad f\left(\frac{1}{2}\right) > 0 .$$

As f is continuous, by the intermediate value theorem, there exists k ∈ (0, k 2) such that f(k ) = 0. As f is increasing in this domain, k is its unique root in (0, k 2). As f(k 2) > f(1 / 2) > 0 and f is strictly decreasing in (k 2, 1 / 2), f has no roots in this interval. Thus,

$$f(k)<0 \ \wedge \ k \in \left(0, \frac{1}{2}\right) \Leftrightarrow k \in (0, k^{\ast}) .$$

Using, for example, the bisection method we can find that k ≈ 0. 199.

Now, we make a similar analysis for the entrant:

$$\begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} \mu^{2}\tilde{\delta}_{3p}(k)>1 \Leftrightarrow \frac{\gamma_{33}-\frac{1-2k}{6}}{\gamma_{33}-\alpha_{33}} >1 \Leftrightarrow \frac{2 k (1-2 k) (3-6 k-9 k^{2}+16 k^{3})}{3 (3+3k-8k^{2})^{2}}<0 . \end{array}$$

As \(k \in \left (0, \frac {1}{2}\right )\), the last inequality is equivalent to g(k) ≡ 3 − 6k − 9k 2 + 16k 3 < 0. As g is continuous, g(0) > 0 and g(1 / 2) < 0, there is k ∗ ∗ ∈ (0, 1 / 2), such that g(k ∗ ∗) = 0. Let us now prove that k ∗ ∗is unique. The roots of the first-order derivative of g are:

$$k_4=\frac{3-\sqrt{41}}{16} <0 \quad \vee \quad k_5=\frac{3+\sqrt{41}}{16} >\frac{1}{2}.$$

Therefore, g′ is negative for \(k \in \left (0,\frac {1}{2}\right )\), which implies that g is strictly decreasing in this domain. As a result, k ∗ ∗ is unique and

$$g(k)<0 \ \wedge \ k \in \left(0, \frac{1}{2}\right) \Leftrightarrow k \in \left(k^{\ast\ast}, \frac{1}{2}\right) .$$

Once again, using the bisection method, we find that k ∗ ∗ ≈ 0. 436. □

Proof of Proposition 3

Using β 3t = 1 − β 1t β 2t , the first-order conditions corresponding to the maximization of the Nash product are:

$$\left\{ \begin{array}{l} \left[\left(1-\beta_{1t}-\beta_{2t}\right)\Pi_{t}^{m3}-\Pi_{3t}^{c3}\right]-\left[\beta_{1t} \Pi_{t}^{m3}-\Pi_{1t}^{c3}\right] =0\\ \left[\left(1-\beta_{1t}-\beta_{2t}\right)\Pi_{t}^{m3}-\Pi_{3t}^{c3}\right]-\left[\beta_{2t} \Pi_{t}^{m3}-\Pi_{2t}^{c3}\right] =0 \end{array} \right..$$

As\(\Pi _{1t}^{c3}\), it follows that:

$$\beta_{1t}=\beta_{2t}=\frac{\Pi_{t}^{m3}+\Pi_{1t}^{c3}-\Pi_{3t}^{c3}}{3\Pi_{t}^{m3}} \equiv \beta_t.$$

Substituting the expressions for profits, we find that β t is constant over time. The collusive profit of the incumbent i ∈ {1, 2} is:

$$\Pi_{it}^{N3} =\frac{1+6\alpha_{3i}-6\alpha_{33}}{18} \mu^{2t} = \frac{k \left(21-6 k-51 k^2+32 k^{3}\right) }{9 \left(3+3 k-8 k^{2}\right)^{2}}\mu^{2 t},$$

while:

$$\Pi_{3t}^{N3} =\frac{1-12\alpha_{3i}+12\alpha_{33}}{18} \mu^{2t} =\frac{27-30 k-93 k^2+60 k^3+64 k^{4} }{18 \left(3+3 k-8 k^{2}\right)^{2}}\mu^{2 t}.$$

Finally, the shares of incumbent i and entrant of the cartel profit are:

$$\begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} \lambda_{i}^{N3}&=&\frac{\Pi_{it}^{N3}}{2\Pi_{it}^{N3}+\Pi_{3t}^{N3}}=\frac{2 k \left(21-6 k-51 k^2+32 k^{3}\right)}{3 \left(3+3 k-8 k^{2}\right)^{2}} \notag \\ \lambda_{3}^{N3}&=&\frac{27-30 k-93 k^2+60 k^3+64 k^{4}}{3 \left(3+3 k-8 k^{2}\right)^{2}}. \end{array}$$
(45)

Proof of Lemma 1

Incumbent i ∈ {1, 2} abides by the collusive agreement in a period t < t͂ m before entry of firm 3 if the following inequality is satisfied:

$$\begin{array}{l} \beta_{2} \sum\limits_{s=t}^{\tilde{t}_m {\kern-1.5pt} -{\kern-1.5pt}1} (\mu^2\delta)^s {\kern-1.5pt}+{\kern-1.5pt} \beta_{3i} \sum\limits_{s=\tilde{t}_m}^{\infty} (\mu^2\delta)^s{\kern-1.5pt}\geq{\kern-1.5pt}\gamma_{2} (\mu^2\delta)^{t}{\kern-1.5pt} +{\kern-1.5pt} \alpha_{2} \sum\limits_{s=t{\kern-1.5pt}+{\kern-1.5pt}1}^{\tilde{t}_c{\kern-1.5pt}-{\kern-1.5pt}1} (\mu^2\delta)^s {\kern-1.5pt}+{\kern-1.5pt}\alpha_{3i} \sum\limits_{s=\tilde{t}_c}^{\infty} (\mu^2\delta)^s\ {\kern-1.5pt}\Leftrightarrow{\kern-1.5pt} \\ \beta_{2} \frac{(\mu^2\delta)^t{\kern-1.5pt}-{\kern-1.5pt}(\mu^2\delta)^{\tilde{t}_m}}{1{\kern-1.5pt}-{\kern-1.5pt}\mu^2\delta}{\kern-1.5pt}+{\kern-1.5pt}\frac{(\mu^2\delta)^{\tilde{t}_m}}{1{\kern-1.5pt}-{\kern-1.5pt}\mu^2\delta}{\kern-1.5pt}\geq{\kern-1.5pt}\gamma_{2} (\mu^2\delta)^{t} {\kern-1.5pt}+{\kern-1.5pt} \alpha_{2} \frac{ (\mu^2\delta)^{t{\kern-1.5pt}+{\kern-1.5pt}1}{\kern-1.5pt}-{\kern-1.5pt}(\mu^2\delta)^{\tilde{t}_c}}{1{\kern-1.5pt}-{\kern-1.5pt}\mu^2\delta} {\kern-1.5pt}+{\kern-1.5pt}\alpha_{3i} \frac{(\mu^2\delta)^{\tilde{t}_c}}{1{\kern-1.5pt}-{\kern-1.5pt}\mu^2\delta}. \end{array}$$
(46)

Multiplying both sides of the inequality by 1 − μ 2 δ, we obtain:

$$\begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} \beta_{2} \left[\left(\mu^{2}\delta\right)^t-\left(\mu^{2}\delta\right)^{\tilde{t}_{m}}\right]+\beta_{3i}\left[(\mu^{2}\delta)^{\tilde{t}_{m}}\right] \geq \notag && \gamma_{2} (\mu^{2}\delta)^{t} (1-\mu^{2}\delta) +\\ &&+ \alpha_{2} \left[ (\mu^{2}\delta)^{t+1}-(\mu^{2}\delta)^{\tilde{t}_{c}}\right] +\alpha_{3i} \left[(\mu^{2}\delta)^{\tilde{t}_{c}}\right] . \end{array}$$

Rearranging the terms of the inequality, we obtain:

$$\left(\mu^{2}\delta\right)^{t}\left(\beta_{2}-\gamma_{2}\right) +\left(\mu^{2}\delta\right)^{t+1}\left(\gamma_2-\alpha_{2}\right) +\left(\mu^{2}\delta\right)^{\tilde{t}_{m}}\left(\beta_{3i}-\beta_{2}\right) +\left(\mu^{2}\delta\right)^{\tilde{t}_{c}}\left(\alpha_2-\alpha_{3i}\right) \geq 0$$
(47)

Substituting t = t͂ m − 1 in the inequality, we obtain:

$$\left(\mu^{2}\delta\right)^{\tilde{t}_m-1}\left[\beta_{2}-\gamma_2 +\left(\gamma_2-\alpha_2+\beta_{3i}-\beta_{2}\right) \mu^{2}\delta +\left(\alpha_2-\alpha_{3i}\right) \left(\mu^{2}\delta\right)^{\tilde{t}_c-\tilde{t}_m+1}\right]\geq 0 .$$

As t͂ c t͂ m + 1 > 1 and μ 2 δ < 1, a sufficient condition for the ICC to be satisfied is:

$$A(\mu,\delta,k) \equiv \beta_{2}-\gamma_2 +\left(\gamma_2-\alpha_2+\beta_{3i}-\beta_{2}\right) \mu^{2}\delta +\left(\alpha_2-\alpha_{3i}\right) (\mu^{2}\delta)^{\tilde{t}_c-\tilde{t}_m+1} \geq 0 .$$
(48)

Consider now an arbitrary period before entry: t = t͂ m τ, with 1 ≤ τt͂ m . Substituting t = t͂ m τ in Eq. 47, we obtain:

$$\begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} &&\left(\mu^{2}\delta\right)^{\tilde{t}_{m}\,-\,\tau}(\beta_{2}\,-\,\gamma_{2}) \,+\,\left(\mu^{2}\delta\right)^{\tilde{t}_{m}\,-\,\tau\,+\,1}(\gamma_{2}\,-\,\alpha_2) \,+\,\left(\mu^{2}\delta\right)^{\tilde{t}_{m}}(\beta_{3i}\,-\,\beta_{2}) \,+\,\left(\mu^{2}\delta\right)^{\tilde{t}_{c}}(\alpha_{2}\,-\,\alpha_{3i}) \geq 0 {} \;\; \Leftrightarrow \quad \notag \\ &&\left(\mu^{2}\delta\right)^{\tilde{t}_{m}\,-\,\tau}\left[\beta_{2}\,-\,\gamma_{2} \,+\, (\gamma_{2}\,-\,\alpha_{2}) \mu^{2}\delta \,+\,(\beta_{3i}\,-\,\beta_{2}) \left(\mu^{2}\delta\right)^{\tau} \,+\,(\alpha_{2}\,-\,\alpha_{3i}) \left(\mu^{2}\delta\right)^{\tilde{t}_{c}\,-\,\tilde{t}_{m}\,+\,\tau}\right]\geq 0 {} \;\;\Leftrightarrow\quad \notag \\ &&\left(\mu^{2}\delta\right)^{\tilde{t}_{m}-\tau}\left[A(\mu,\delta,k)+(\beta_{2}-\beta_{3i})\mu^{2}\delta \left[1-\left(\mu^{2}\delta\right)^{\tau-1}\right]\right] \geq 0. \end{array}$$
(49)

Notice that if condition (48) holds and β 2β 3i > 0, the inequality (49) is also satisfied, since 1 − (μ 2 δ)τ − 1 > 1. Therefore, to conclude the proof it is only missing to show that β 2β 3i > 0.

The expressions for β 2 and for β 3i are given in Eqs. 20 and 13, respectively. Therefore,

$$\beta_2-\beta_{3i}=\frac{k \left(39+6 k-201 k^2-88 k^3+320 k^{4}\right)}{18 (1+4 k) \left(3+3 k-8 k^{2}\right)^{2}} .$$

As k > 0, the inequality β 2β 3i > 0 is equivalent to:

$$p(k)\equiv 39+6 k-201 k^{2}-88 k^{3}+320 k^{4} > 0 .$$

The first-order derivative of p is: p (k) = 6 − 402k − 264k 2 + 1280k 3, which is globally continuous. As a result,

$$\begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} &[p^{\prime}(-0.5) < \wedge p^{\prime}(-0.4) > 0]&\quad \Rightarrow \quad \exists k_{1} \in (-0.5,-0.4) : p^{\prime}(k_1)=0\\ &[p^{\prime}(0) < 0 \wedge p^{\prime}(0.1) > 0]&\quad \Rightarrow \quad \exists k_{2} \in (0,0.1) : p^{\prime}(k_2)=0 \\ &[p^{\prime}(0.6) < 0 \wedge p^{\prime}(0.7) > 0]&\quad \Rightarrow \quad \exists k_{3} \in (0.6,0.7) : p^{\prime}(k_3)=0 . \end{array}$$

As p is a polynomial of third degree, its only zeros are k 1, k 2 and k 3. We conclude, therefore, that p is increasing in (0, k 2) and decreasing in \(\left (k_{2},\frac {1}{2}\right )\). Thus, the minimum of p in the interval \(\left (0,\frac {1}{2}\right )\) must be achieved at one limit of this interval. As \(p(0) > p\left (\frac {1}{2}\right ) > 0\), we conclude that \(p(k) > 0 \ , \forall k \in \left (0,\frac {1}{2}\right )\). This ends the proof. □

Proof of Lemma 3

If the incumbents anticipate partial collusion with simultaneous moves after entry, they abide by the collusive agreement before entry if:Footnote 58

$$C+\zeta_{3i}\mu^{2} \delta +\left(\alpha_{2}-\alpha_{3i}\right) \left(\mu^{2}\delta\right)^{\tilde{t}_c-\tilde{t}_{pc}+1} \geq 0 ,$$
(50)

where \(C=\beta _{2}-\gamma _{2}+\left (\gamma _{2}-\alpha _{2}-\beta _{2}\right )\mu ^{2} \delta \). Similarly, if the incumbents anticipate partial collusion with sequential moves after entry, the ICC for collusion sustainability before entry is:

$$C+\sigma_{3i}\mu^{2} \delta +(\alpha_{2}-\alpha_{3i}) \left(\mu^{2}\delta\right)^{\tilde{t}_c-\tilde{t}_{ps}+1} \geq 0,$$
(51)

where σ 3i is given by Eq. 27. Below, we prove that if inequality (50) holds, inequality (51) is also satisfied. In other words, we prove that:

$$\begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} &&\sigma_{3i}\mu^{2} \delta +(\alpha_{2}-\alpha_{3i}) \left(\mu^{2}\delta\right)^{\tilde{t}_c-\tilde{t}_{ps}+1} > \zeta_{3i}\mu^{2} \delta +(\alpha_{2}-\alpha_{3i}) \left(\mu^{2}\delta\right)^{\tilde{t}_c-\tilde{t}_{pc}+1} \Leftrightarrow \\ && \left(\mu^{2}\delta\right)^{\tilde{t}_c-\tilde{t}_{ps}+1}-\left(\mu^{2}\delta\right)^{\tilde{t}_c-\tilde{t}_{pc}+1} > \frac{\zeta_{3i}-\sigma_{3i}}{\alpha_2-\alpha_{3i}}. \end{array}$$

Start by noticing that:

$$\sigma_{33}<\zeta_{33} \ \Leftrightarrow \ -\frac{8 (1-k)(1-2 k)^{2} k^{2} (9+18 k-44 k^2-36 k^3+56 k^4)}{9 (3-4 k) (1+2 k-4 k^2)^{2} (3+4 k-8 k^2)^{2}}<0,$$

which is satisfied for \(k\in \left (0,\frac {1}{2}\right )\), since 9 + 18k − 44k 2 − 36k 3 + 56k 4 > 6 in this domain. This means that the single-profit of the entrant is lower under sequential moves than under simultaneous moves. As a result, entry occurs later under sequential moves (t͂ ps > t͂ pc ), which implies that: \((\alpha _{2}-\alpha _{3i}) \left (\mu ^{2}\delta \right )^{\tilde {t}_c-\tilde {t}_{ps}+1}-(\alpha _{2}-\alpha _{3i}) \left (\mu ^{2}\delta \right )^{\tilde {t}_c-\tilde {t}_{pc}+1}>0.\).

Each incumbent profits more under sequential moves than under simultaneous moves, since:

$$\zeta_{3i}-\sigma_{3i}=-\frac{8 k^{3} (1-k)^{2} (1-2 k)^{2}}{9(3-4 k) (3+4 k-8 k^2)(1+2 k-4 k^2)^{2}}<0$$

This concludes the proof, since α 2α 3i > 0. □

Proof of Remark 5

The incumbent i ∈ {1, 2} profits more than the entrant if:

$$\Pi_{it}^{ps3} \geq \Pi_{3t}^{ps3} \Leftrightarrow -\frac{9-30 k-16 k^2+100 k^3-64 k^{4}}{2 (3-4 k) (3+4 k-8 k^2)^{2}} \geq 0.$$

In the domain \(\left (0,\frac {1}{2}\right )\), the last inequality is equivalent to p(k) ≡ 9 − 30k − 16k 2 + 100k 3 − 64k 4 ≤ 0. The first-order derivative of p is: p (k) = − 30 − 32k + 300k 2 − 256k 3, which is globally continuous. Moreover:

$$\begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} [ p^{\prime}(-0.3) > 0 \wedge p^{\prime}(-0.2)<0]&\quad \Rightarrow\quad \exists k_{1} \in (-0.3,-0.2) : p^{\prime}(k_1)=0,\\ \quad[p^{\prime}(0.5) < 0 \wedge p^{\prime}(0.6)>0]&\quad \Rightarrow \quad \exists k_{2} \in (0.5,0.6) : p^{\prime}(k_2)=0,\\ \quad[ p^{\prime}(0.8) > 0 \wedge p^{\prime}(0.9)<0 ]&\quad \Rightarrow \quad \exists k_{3} \in (0.8,0.9) : p^{\prime}(k_3)=0 . \end{array}$$

As p is a polynomial of third degree, its only roots are k 1, k 2 and k 3. Thus, p has no roots in the interval \(\left (0,\frac {1}{2}\right )\), which means that p is strictly decreasing in this interval. Therefore, the polynomial p can have, at most, one zero in the interval \(\left (0,\frac {1}{2}\right )\). As:

$$p(0.3415)>0 \quad \text{and} \quad p(0.3416)<0 ,$$

there is k ∈ (0. 3415, 0. 3416) such that p(k ) = 0. Thus, if \(k \in \left (k^{\ast },\frac {1}{2}\right )\), then p(k) ≤ 0. □

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Brandão, A., Pinho, J. & Vasconcelos, H. Asymmetric Collusion with Growing Demand. J Ind Compet Trade 14, 429–472 (2014). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10842-013-0171-z

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Revised:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10842-013-0171-z

Keywords

JEL Classifications

Navigation