Skip to main content
Log in

Are social preferences related to market performance?

  • Published:
Experimental Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper combines laboratory with field data from professional sellers to study whether social preferences are related to performance in open-air markets. The data show that sellers who are more pro-social in a laboratory experiment are also more successful in natural markets: They achieve higher prices for similar quality, have superior trade relations and better abilities to signal trustworthiness to buyers. These findings suggest that social preferences play a significant role for outcomes in natural markets.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Bowles et al. (2001) argue that there are different “predisposition(s) to truth-telling” and that truth-telling is an “incentive-enhancing” preference that attenuates tensions in principal-agent relationships.

  2. In this setting, there is free access to the fishing grounds and capital requirements for becoming a fisherman selling shrimp in markets are low.

  3. The vast majority uses modified plastic bottles to catch shrimp. Thus, there are no significant differences in equipment used.

  4. I tested the existence of incomplete/asymmetric information in a “guessing game” where buyers and sellers took part. In this game the most accurate guess about the average shrimp size in a pile was rewarded with a high monetary reward (worth several days’ income). The sellers guessed the average shrimp size in their pile and the buyers guessed the average shrimp size in a pile they were about to buy. It turned out that both sellers and buyers significantly overestimated the average shrimp size by on average 0.297 centimeters (t=2.29, p=0.027, that overestimates are equal to zero) and that buyers overestimated the average size considerably more than sellers (0.437 centimeters buyers vs. 0.243 centimeters sellers).

  5. There may be other ways to misrepresent quality or to cheat which I could not observe. For example, sellers often have the chance to cheat on the quantity of shrimp sold.

  6. I collected data on the average shrimp size over consecutive weeks from 24 sellers. As expected there is a significant correlation of average shrimp size across weeks (Spearman Rank Correlation, r=0.493, p=0.014), but considerable variance as well.

  7. Sellers do not always go to the market to sell shrimp. They also sometimes commission other sellers to sell their shrimp.

  8. Sellers color their shrimp red with natural or chemical substances to be suggestive to be tastier. I use a binary measure to assess the probability that a sample of shrimp was colored. This measure was derived from the experimenters’ estimation of the redness of shrimps.

  9. Participants earned significantly more than a typical daily income. They took also part in other experiments than the PGE and RAE (a stag-hunt experiment, competition experiment, time preference experiment, charity experiment). To minimize the risk that there are behavioral spillovers between experiments, participants did not know the behavior of the other participants before the end of all experiments. In addition, participants were told that they did not get to know whether their behavior in any experiment became payoff relevant before the end of all experiments because only two experiments were chosen for payment. The experimental instructions are available in an on-line appendix.

  10. Note that the group size in the PGE was four in one experimental session (N=16). The behavior in this session is very similar compared to all other sessions (average contribution in this session=3.75, in all other sessions=3.66; t=−0.12, p=0.90). Excluding this session from further analysis would not lead to systematic different results.

  11. Appendix Table 4 shows that there is a significant relationship between pro-sociality and shrimp price for both samples. The sample which uses prices that were directly collected at the market is highly significantly related to pro-sociality (p=0.007, N=47) and the other sample that uses prices which were collected outside the market is marginally significantly related to pro-sociality (p=0.096, N=91).

  12. Not specialized shrimp sellers sometimes temporarily only sell fish. This may explain why they have more problems keeping trade relations alive.

References

  • Andreoni, J. (1990). Impure altruism and donations to public goods: a theory of warm-glow giving? Economic Journal, 100(401), 464–477.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barr, A., Ensminger, J., & Johnson, J. (2009). Social networks and trust in cross-cultural economic experiments. In K. Cook, M. Levi, & R. Hardin (Eds.), Whom can we trust? New York: Russell Sage Foundation.

    Google Scholar 

  • Barr, A., & Serneels, P. (2009). Reciprocity in the workplace. Experimental Economics, 12, 99–112.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bolton, G., & Ockenfels, A. (2000). ERC: a theory of equity, reciprocity, and competition. American Economic Review, 90(1), 166–193.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bowles, S., Gintis, H., & Osborne, M. (2001). The determinants of earnings: a behavioral approach. Journal of Economic Literature, 39(4), 1137–1176.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brown, M., Falk, A., & Fehr, E. (2005). Relational contracts and the nature of market interaction. Econometrica, 72(3), 747–780.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Camerer, C. (2003). Behavioral game theory. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Carpenter, J., & Seki, E. (2010). Do social preferences increase productivity? Field experimental evidence from fishermen in Toyama Bay. Economic Inquiry, 49(2), 612–630.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Charness, G., & Rabin, M. (2002). Understanding social preferences with simple tests. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117, 817–869.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cox, J. C., Friedman, D., & Gjerstad, S. (2007). A tractable model of reciprocity and fairness. Games and Economic Behavior, 59, 17–45.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dohmen, T., Falk, A., Huffman, D., & Sunde, U. (2009). Homo reciprocans: survey evidence on behavioral outcomes. Economic Journal, 536, 592–612.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dufwenberg, M., & Kirchsteiger, G. (2004). A theory of sequential reciprocity. Games and Economic Behavior, 47(2), 268–298.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Falk, A., & Fischbacher, U. (2006). A theory of reciprocity. Games and Economic Behavior, 54(2), 293–315.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fehr, E., & Gächter, S. (2000). Cooperation and punishment in public goods experiments. American Economic Review, 90, 980–994.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fehr, E., Götte, L., & Zehnder, C. (2009). A behavioral approach to the labor market: the role of fairness concerns. Annual Review of Economics, 1, 355–384.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fehr, E., Kirchsteiger, G., & Riedl, A. (1993). Does fairness prevent market clearing? An experimental investigation. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 108(2), 437–459.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fehr, E., & Leibbrandt, A. (2011). A field study on cooperativeness and impatience in the tragedy of the commons. Journal of Public Economics, 95, 1144–1155.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fehr, E., & Schmidt, K. (1999). A theory of fairness, competition and cooperation. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 114(3), 817–868.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Güth, W., Schmittberger, R., & Schwarze, B. (1982). An experimental analysis of ultimatum bargaining. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 3, 367–388.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jin, G., & Kato, A. (2006). Price, quality, and reputation: evidence from an online field experiment. The Rand Journal of Economics, 37(4), 983–1005.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Karlan, D. (2005). Using experimental economics to measure social capital and predict financial decisions. American Economic Review, 95(5), 1688–1699.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • List, J. (2006). The behavioralist meets the market: measuring social preferences and reputation effects in actual transactions. Journal of Political Economy, 114(51), 1–37.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • López-Pérez, R. (2008). Aversion to norm-breaking: a model. Games and Economic Behavior, 64, 237–267.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rabin, M. (1993). Incorporating fairness into game theory and economics. American Economic Review, 83(5), 1281–1302.

    Google Scholar 

  • Roth, A. (1995). Bargaining experiments. In J. Kagel & A. Roth (Eds.), Handbook of experimental economics Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sobel, J. (2005). Interdependent preferences and reciprocity. Journal of Economic Literature, XLIII, 392–436.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weisbuch, G., Kirman, A., & Herreiner, D. (2000). Market organisation and trading relationships. Economic Journal, 110, 411–436.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Andreas Leibbrandt.

Appendix: Tables and figure

Appendix: Tables and figure

Table 3 Data overview
Table 4 Robustness checks for relationship between price and pro-sociality
Fig. 3
figure 3

Picture of shrimp market and shrimp piles

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Leibbrandt, A. Are social preferences related to market performance?. Exp Econ 15, 589–603 (2012). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10683-012-9315-y

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10683-012-9315-y

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation