Skip to main content
Log in

Consumer education: why the market doesn’t work

  • Published:
European Journal of Law and Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

A growing literature studies the interactions between fully rational profit maximizing firms, on one side, and biased consumers, on the other side. Along these lines, this paper focuses on the consequences of quality misperception on the market equilibrium, by raising the following question: when quality bias affects consumer choice, do firms have incentives to educate their competitor’s customers in order to attract them? To tackle this issue, I incorporate consumer misperception in a Cournot-type duopoly model and consider the consequences on the market outcome. I focus on the two polar cases, when both firms either exploit consumer misperception, or educate completely their rival’s customers. I show that the market exerts conflicting forces on the firms’ incentives, such as a curse of debiasing might occur even in the presence of substitute goods. Consequently, the opportunity of a legal intervention to trigger consumer education is a key issue.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Among countless contributions, Akerlof (1970)’s seminal paper tackles the problem of asymmetric information on the second-hand car market.

  2. For a review of rationality biases and their legal implications, see Jolls et al. (1998).

  3. Ellison (2006) offers a review of the literature concerning consumer irrationalities. For a recent description of consumers’ cognitive biases and their implication on consumer law, with an emphasis on French law, see Gabaix et al. (2012).

  4. This specific issue has been addressed by Della-Vigna and Malmendier (2006).

  5. On this subject, see for example Spiegler and Piccione (2012).

  6. For an analysis of advertising as a means of enhancing consumer bias, see Zhou (2008).

  7. Gabaix and Laibson (2006)

  8. For a classification of consumer bias, see Huck and Zhou (2011).

  9. It is worth noting that the mere idea of consumers having true preferences is debated in the literature. Indeed, if consumer preferences are context dependent or time inconsistent, how can one decide which are the real preferences? In this perspective, Rizzo and Whitman (2009) insist on “the knowledge problem of paternalism” and question the relevance of debiasing. While this issue does deserve to be addressed, I contend that in the specific case of quality misperception rational consumer preferences can justifiably serve as a benchmark.

  10. For more details concerning the choice of this utility function, see Dixit (1979).

  11. See “Appendix” for details.

  12. For more technical details regarding this utility function, see Motta (2004).

  13. In this regards, a related yet different issue, studied for instance in Zhou (2008) could consist in investigating when firms have incentives to enhance consumer misperception in order to generate an underestimation of their competitors’ good.

  14. See “Appendix” for proof.

  15. See “Appendix” for details.

  16. See “Appendix” for details.

  17. On this issue, see for example Fisher and McGowan (1979) and Shapiro (1980).

  18. See “Appendix” for details.

  19. Contrary to the framing effect for instance, the object of such a legal policy is by no means to influence consumers’ decisions without their knowledge. In their influential book Nudge, Thaler and Sunstein (2008), explain how the framing effect can bend the individuals’ choices, precisely without them realizing that they are being manipulated.

  20. Jolls et al. (1998).

  21. For an example of firms voluntarily inducing switching costs in order to amplify the adverse consequences of consumer bias (namely time inconsistent preferences), see DellaVigna and Malmendier (2004).

  22. The notion of “investment good” stems from the distinction first drawn by Nelson (1970): in his seminal paper, Nelson (1970) identified the search qualities of a good, which the consumer can assess prior to buying the good, and the experience qualities, which can only be evaluated after using the good. One can consider that investment goods relate to the experience qualities, as originally defined by Nelson (1970).

  23. The concept of “credence goods” was first introduced by Darby and Karni (1973) and has now become standard in the Industrial Organization literature, as emphasized in Huck and Zhou (2011).

References

  • Akerlof, G. (1970). The market for ”lemons”: Quality uncertainty and the market mechanism. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 84(3), 488–500.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bar-Gill, O. (2008). The behavioral economics of consumer contracts. Minnesota Law Review, 92(3), 749–802.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bar-Gill, O., & Stone, R. (2009). Mobile misperception. Harvard Journal of Law and Technology, 23(1), 51–118.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bebchuk, L., & Posner, R. (2006). One-sided contracts in competitive consumer markets. Michigan Law Review, 104, 827–836.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ben-Shahar, O., & Posner, E. (2011). The right to withdraw in contract law. The Journal of Legal Studies, 40(1), 115–148.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Darby, M., & Karni, E. (1973). Free competition and the optimal amount of fraud. Journal of Law and Economics, 16(1), 67–88.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Della-Vigna, S., & Malmendier, U. (2006). Paying not to go to the gym. American Economic Review, 96(3), 694–719.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • DellaVigna, S., & Malmendier, U. (2004). Contract design and self-control: Theory and evidence. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 119(2), 353–402.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dixit, A. (1979). A model of duopoly suggesting a theory of entry barriers. The Bell Journal of Economics, 10(1), 20–32.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dixit, A., & Norman, V. (1978). Advertising and welfare. The Bell Journal of Economics, 9(1), 1–17.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ellison, G. (2006). Bounded rationality in industrial organization. In Blundell, Newey, & Persson (Eds.), Advances in economics and econometrics: Theory and applications, volume 2 of Ninth World Congress (pp. 142–219). Cambrige: Cambrige university Press. http://economics.mit.edu/files/904.

  • Faure, M., & Luth, H. (2011). Behavioral economics in unfair contract terms cautions and considerations. Journal of Consumer Policy, 34(3), 337–358. doi:10.1007/s10603-011-9162-9.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fisher, F., & McGowan, F. (1979). Advertising and welfare: Comment. The Bell Journal of Economics, 10(2), 126–127.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gabaix, X., & Laibson, D. (2006). Shrouded attributes, consumer myopia, and information suppresion in competitive markets. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 121(2), 505–540.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gabaix, X., Landier, A., & Thesmar, D. (2012). Consumer protection: Bounded rationality and regulation. Technical report, Conseil d’Analyse Economique, report no 101, September 2012. http://www.cae-eco.fr/La-protection-du-consommateur-rationalite-limitee-et-regulation.html.

  • Höppner, S. (2012). The unintended consequence of doorstep consumer protection: Surpirse, reciprocation and consistency. The European Journal of Law and Economics. doi:10.1007/s10657-012-9336-1.

  • Huck, S., & Tyran, J.-R. (2007). Reciprocity, social ties, and competition in markets for experience goods. Journal of Socio-Economics, 36(2), 191–203.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Huck, S., & Zhou, J. (2011). Consumer behavioral biases in competition: A survey. Office of Fair Trading, report no 134, London. http://www.oft.gov.uk/shared_oft/research/OFT1324.

  • Jolls, C., Sunstein, C., & Thaler, R. (1998). A behavioral approach to law and economics. Stanford Law Review, 50(5), 1471–1550.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman, D., & Tversky, A. (1974). Judgment under uncertainty: Heuristics and biases. Science, 185(4157), 1124–1131.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Karle, H., & Peitz, M. (2012). Competition under consumer loss aversion. University of Mannheim Working Paper Series, 12 2012. https://ub-madoc.bib.uni-mannheim.de/31642/1/Karle_%26_Peitz_08-12.

  • Motta, M. (2004). Competition policy: Theory and practice. Cambridge: Cambrige university Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Nelson, P. (1970). Information and consumer behavior. Journal of Political Economy, 78(2), 311–329.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rizzo, M., & Whitman, G. (2009). The knowledge problem of new paternalism. Brigham Young University Law Review, 4:904–968. http://digitalcommons.law.byu.edu/lawreview/vol2009/iss4/4/.

  • Shapiro, C. (1980). Advertising and welfare: Comment. The Bell Journal of Economics, 11(2), 749–752.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Singh, N., & Vives, X. (1984). Quantity competition in a differentiated duopoly. The RAND Journal of Economics, 15(4), 546–554.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sonnenschein, H. (1968). The dual of duopoly is complementary monopoly: or, two of Cournot’s theories are one. Journal of Political Economy, 76(2), 316–318.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Spiegler, R., & Piccione, M. (2012). Price competition under limited comparability. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 127, 97–135. doi:10.1093/qje/qjr053.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Thaler, R., & Sunstein, C. (2008). Nudge: Improving decisions about health, wealth and happiness. New Haven: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tversky, A., & Kahneman, D. (1986). Rational choice and the framing of decisions. The Journal of Business, 59(4), S251–S278.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zhou, J. (2008). Advertising, misperceived preferences, and product design. mimeo. https://sites.google.com/site/jidongzhou77/research.

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Sophie Bienenstock.

Additional information

I thank an anonymous referee for stimulating and enlightening comments. I also warmly thank Ilene Weismehl for her advice and meticulous reading. Finally, I am extremely grateful to Bertrand Crettez for his precious help, valuable suggestions and unflinching support.

Appendix

Appendix

1.1 The market outcome absent consumer education

The choice of focusing on price competition is consistent with the fact that I constrain the analysis to substitute goods. Indeed, Singh and Vives (1984) show that in the framework with substitute commodities, it is a dominant strategy for each firm to choose the quantity rather than the price. Nonetheless, the price competition model deserves to be mentioned. In the next paragraphs, I study the market outcome under quantity and then under price competition.

The market outcome under quantity competition: I study a duopoly where two competing firms \(1\) and \(2\) offer one commodity each. Let \(q_1\) and \(q_2\) represent the quantities of good offered repsectively by firms \(1\) and \(2\). In this framework, consumers maximize \(U(q_1, q_2)-\sum \limits _{i=1}^{2} p_i q_i\), where \(q_i\) is the amount of good \(i\) and \(p_i\) its price.

Each consumer has the following utility function: \(V=y+U(q_1, q_2)\), where \(y\) designates the composite good, whose price \(p_y\) satisfies \(p_y=1\). The consumer’s budgetary constraint can then be written as follows:

$$\begin{aligned} R=y+p_1q_1+p_2q_2 \end{aligned}$$
(15)

I specify the utility function:

$$\begin{aligned} U(q_1,q_2)=\hat{\alpha }_1q_1+\hat{\alpha }_2q_2-1/2(\beta q_1^2+\beta q_2^2+2\gamma q_1q_2) \end{aligned}$$

This function yields the system of linear inverse demands:

$$\begin{aligned} \left\{ \begin{array}{l} p_1=\hat{\alpha }_1-\beta q_1-\gamma q_2 \\ p_2=\hat{\alpha }_2-\beta q_2-\gamma q_1 \\ \end{array} \right. \end{aligned}$$
(16)

To study the case of quantity competition, I solve the following problem for \(i\,\mathrm{and} \,j \in (1,2) \,\mathrm{and} \, i \ne j\): \(\max _{q_i}\Pi _i^c=\max _{q_i}(\alpha _i-\beta q_i-\gamma q_j)q_i\). In equilibrium, one obtains the following prices and quantities:

$$\begin{aligned} q_i^c= \frac{2\beta \hat{\alpha }_i-\gamma \hat{\alpha }_j}{4\beta ^2-\gamma ^2} \,\mathrm{and} \,p_i^c=\frac{2\beta ^2\hat{\alpha }_i-\beta \gamma \hat{\alpha }_j}{4\beta ^2-\gamma ^2} \end{aligned}$$

The firms’ profits are then equal to:

$$\begin{aligned} \hat{\Pi }_i^c=\frac{\beta (2\hat{\alpha }_i\beta -\gamma \hat{\alpha }_j)^2}{(4\beta ^2-\gamma ^2)^2} \end{aligned}$$

The market outcome under price competition: Note that this model can easily be extended to a Bertrand-type price competition duopoly. The utility function \(U(q_1,q_2)=\hat{\alpha }_1q_1+\hat{\alpha }_2q_2-1/2(\beta q_1^2+\beta q_2^2+2\gamma q_1q_2)\) entails the following system of direct demand functions:

$$\begin{aligned} \left\{ \begin{array}{rcr} q_1 = \hat{a}_1-b p_1+gp_2 \\ q_2= \hat{a}_2-b p_2+gp_1\\ \end{array} \right. \end{aligned}$$

With:

$$\begin{aligned} \hat{a}_i=\frac{\beta \hat{\alpha }_i-\gamma \hat{\alpha }_j}{\beta ^2-\gamma ^2} \,; \,b=\frac{\beta }{\beta ^2-\gamma ^2} \,; \,g=\frac{\gamma }{\beta ^2-\gamma ^2} \end{aligned}$$

One can verify that at the symmetric equilibrium, the quantities and prices are equal to:

$$\begin{aligned} q_i^b=\frac{2b^2 \hat{a}_i + b g \hat{a}_j}{4b^2- g^2} \,\mathrm{and} \,p_i^b=\frac{2b \hat{a}_i+g \hat{a}_j}{4b^2-g^2}. \end{aligned}$$

Moreover, \(q_i^b\) and \(p_i^b\) yield the following profit :

$$\begin{aligned} \Pi _i^b=\frac{b(2b \hat{a}_i+g \hat{a}_j)^2}{(4b^2-g^2)^2}. \end{aligned}$$

However, the market outcome under price competition does not need to be calculated. Indeed, the duality of the quantity and price problems allows us to solve the latter by simply replacing \(\hat{\alpha }_i\) by \(\hat{a}_i, \beta\) by \(b\) and \(\gamma\) by \(-g\). This duality which was first pointed out by Sonnenschein (1968), is due to the fact that the firms’ problems under quantity and quality competition are the dual of each other: in the first case, the problem for firm \(I\) is \(\max _{q_i}\Pi _i^c=\max _{q_i}(\hat{\alpha }_i-\beta q_i-\gamma q_j)q_i\), whereas under price competition the problem is \(\max _{p_i}\Pi _i^b=\max _{p_i}(\hat{a}_i-b q_i+gq_j)p_i\).

While the duality between the price and the quantity models allows for a generalization of the results as far as the market outcome is concerned, the symmetry no longer holds when one turns to the issue of consumer education. When the goods are substitutes, firms have less capacity to raise their prices above marginal cost in Bertrand competition. This entails lower prices in Bertand than in Cournot, which could modify substantially the firms’ incentives to educate consumers. Indeed, one would expect consumer debiasing to be less likely in Bertrand competition, as firms would not reap any profit from such a strategy. However, this intuition could be challenged by the fact that the index \(\frac{\gamma }{\beta }\) has an ambiguous effect on the firms incentives. Although this paper focuses on the Cournot duopoly, the case of price competition is be worthy of further exploration.

1.2 Proof of propositions 1 and 2

In the presence of debiasing, and according to (8), \(\Pi ^c_i=\frac{\beta (2\beta \hat{\alpha }_i-\gamma \hat{\alpha }_j)^2}{(4\beta ^2-\gamma ^2)^2}-c_i\), for \(i \in (1,2)\). Recall that according to (17).

$$\begin{aligned} \left\{ \begin{array}{rcr} \,\hat{\alpha }_1= \mathrm{max} (\bar{\alpha }_1-ac_2 ; \underline{\alpha }_1) \\ \,\hat{\alpha }_2= \mathrm{max} ( \bar{\alpha }_2-dc_1 ; \underline{\alpha }_2) \\ \end{array} \right. \end{aligned}$$
(17)

Wherefrom, for \(i=1\):

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial \Pi _1}{\partial c_1}&= \frac{2d\beta \gamma }{(4\beta ^2-\gamma ^2)^2}(2\beta (\bar{\alpha }_1-ac_2) -\gamma (\bar{\alpha }_2-dc_1))-1 \end{aligned}$$
(18)
$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial ^2\Pi _1}{\partial c_1^2}&= 2\beta \left[ \frac{d\gamma }{(4\beta ^2-\gamma ^2)}\right] ^2 \end{aligned}$$
(19)

And for \(i=2\):

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial \Pi _2}{\partial c_2}&= \frac{2a\beta \gamma }{(4\beta ^2-\gamma ^2)^2}(2\beta (\bar{\alpha }_2-dc_1) -\gamma (\bar{\alpha }_1-ac_2))-1 \end{aligned}$$
(20)
$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial ^2\Pi _2}{\partial c_2^2}&= 2\beta \left[ \frac{a\gamma }{(4\beta ^2-\gamma ^2)}\right] ^2 \end{aligned}$$
(21)

As \(\frac{\partial ^2\Pi _i}{\partial c_i^2}\) is always positive, the profit function is convex with respect to costs. Therefore, if the profit function is strictly increasing (respectively decreasing) the firm’s best response will be to choose \(c_i=\bar{c}_i\) (respectively \(c_i=0\)). To finish the proof of propositions 1 and 2, I can now study the sign of the first derivative of the profit with respect to \(c_i\).

Proof of proposition 1

I begin with the proof of proposition 1, that is to say the symmetric Nash equilibrium with consumer education. I focus on the case when \(\frac{\partial \Pi _i}{\partial c_i}>0\). Let us focus first on \(i=1\).

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial \Pi _1}{\partial c_1}&> 0 \Leftrightarrow \frac{2d\beta \gamma }{(4\beta ^2-\gamma ^2)^2}(2\beta (\bar{\alpha }_1-ac_2) -\gamma (\bar{\alpha }_2-dc_1))>1 \end{aligned}$$
(22)
$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial \Pi _1}{\partial c_1}&> 0 \Leftrightarrow 2\beta (\bar{\alpha }_1-ac_2)-\gamma (\bar{\alpha }_2-dc_1) > \frac{(4\beta ^2-\gamma ^2)^2}{2d\beta \gamma } \end{aligned}$$
(23)

I want to define the conditions which guarantee a symmetric Nash equilibrium such as \(c_1= \bar{c}_1\). I suppose that firm 2 sets \(c_2\) at its maximal value and determine when firm 1’s best response is to adopt the same strategy. If the profit function it is strictly increasing with regards to the debiasing costs, then \(c_1\) necessarily equals \(\bar{c}_1\). For \(c_2=\bar{c}_2\), one can then write:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial \Pi _1}{\partial c_1}&> 0 \Leftrightarrow 4\beta (\bar{\alpha }_1-a\bar{c}_2)-2\gamma (\bar{\alpha }_2-d\bar{c}_1) > \frac{(4\beta ^2-\gamma ^2)^2}{d\beta \gamma } \end{aligned}$$
(24)
$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial \Pi _1}{\partial c_1}&> 0 \Leftrightarrow 4\beta \underline{\alpha }_1-2\gamma \underline{\alpha }_2 > \frac{(4\beta ^2-\gamma ^2)^2}{d\beta \gamma } \end{aligned}$$
(25)
$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial \Pi _1}{\partial c_1}&> 0 \Leftrightarrow 4\underline{\alpha }_1-2\frac{\gamma }{\beta }\underline{\alpha }_2 > \frac{\beta }{d}\frac{[4-(\frac{\gamma }{\beta })^2]^2}{\frac{\gamma }{\beta }} \end{aligned}$$
(26)

By symmetry, one can prove that for \(i=2\):

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial \Pi _2}{\partial c_2}>0 \Leftrightarrow 4\underline{\alpha }_2-2\frac{\gamma }{\beta }\underline{\alpha }_1 > \frac{\beta }{a}\frac{[4-(\frac{\gamma }{\beta })^2]^2}{\frac{\gamma }{\beta }} \end{aligned}$$
(27)

Whence, if the following conditions hold, a symmetric Nash equilibrium whereby both firms completely debias their competitor’s customers emerges:

$$\begin{aligned} \left\{ \begin{array}{rcr} \,4\underline{\alpha }_1-2\frac{\gamma }{\beta }\underline{\alpha }_2>\frac{\beta }{d}\frac{[4-(\frac{\gamma }{\beta })^2]^2}{\frac{\gamma }{\beta }} \\ \,4\underline{\alpha }_2-2\frac{\gamma }{\beta }\underline{\alpha }_1>\frac{\beta }{a}\frac{[4-(\frac{\gamma }{\beta })^2]^2}{\frac{\gamma }{\beta }}\\ \end{array} \right. \end{aligned}$$
(28)

Proof of proposition 2

Let us now turn to second symmetric Nash equilibrium, in which neither of the two firms educates customers. This equilibrium prevails if and only if the profit functions are strictly decreasing with regards to the debiasing costs. For \(i=1\), this is equivalent to:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial \Pi _1}{\partial c_1}&< 0 \Leftrightarrow \frac{2d\beta \gamma }{(4\beta ^2-\gamma ^2)^2}(2\beta (\bar{\alpha }_1-ac_2) -\gamma (\bar{\alpha }_2-dc_1))<1 \end{aligned}$$
(29)
$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial \Pi _1}{\partial c_1}&< 0 \Leftrightarrow 2\beta (\bar{\alpha }_1-ac_2)-\gamma (\bar{\alpha }_2-dc_1) < \frac{(4\beta ^2-\gamma ^2)^2}{2d\beta \gamma } \end{aligned}$$
(30)

So as to study firm \(1\)’s best response to its rival’s strategy, I suppose that \(c_2=0\) and search for the conditions which entail \(c_1=0\). With a similar argument as above, if the profit function is strictly decreasing with regards to the debiasing costs, then \(c_1=0\). Therefore, for \(c_2=0\) I have:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial \Pi _1}{\partial c_1}<0 \Leftrightarrow 2\beta \bar{\alpha }_1-\gamma \bar{\alpha }_2 < \frac{(4\beta ^2-\gamma ^2)^2}{2d\beta \gamma } \end{aligned}$$
(31)

Finally, I determine by symmetry a condition relative to \(c_2=0\). To conclude, there is a symmetric Nash equilibrium in which both firms choose not to educate consumers if:

$$\begin{aligned} \left\{ \begin{array}{l} \,4\bar{\alpha }_1-2\frac{\gamma }{\beta }\bar{\alpha }_2< \frac{\beta }{d}\frac{[4-(\frac{\gamma }{\beta })^2]^2}{\frac{\gamma }{\beta }}\\ \,4\bar{\alpha }_2-2\frac{\gamma }{\beta }\bar{\alpha }_1< \frac{\beta }{a}\frac{[4-(\frac{\gamma }{\beta })^2]^2}{\frac{\gamma }{\beta }} \end{array} \right. \end{aligned}$$
(32)

1.3 Welfare analysis

I want to determine when it is socially efficient to force firms to debias their rival’s customers. In practical terms, the issue is to define under which conditions a mandatory debiasing policy results in an increase in social welfare. To grasp the variation of social welfare ensuing from a debiasing policy, I choose to focus on the monetary savings freshly educated consumers make, ensuing from a debiasing scheme. In this perspective, I first calculate \(\bar{q}_i\), the quantity of good \(x_i\) a biased consumer buys. I then turn to the quantity \(\hat{q}_i\), which corresponds to the amount of good \(x_i\) a debiased consumer would buy at the same price. Comparing the two quantities allows me to measure the increase in consumer welfare resulting from debiasing. In order to express this welfare variation in monetary terms, I consider that prices remain unchanged and are equal to \(\bar{p}_i^c\). The choice of keeping \(\bar{p}_i^c\) constant throughout the welfare analysis is reasonable since it corresponds to the price consumers would actually pay absent any debiasing strategy.

Let us first remind that, for \(i \in (1,2), j \in (1,2)\) and \(i\ne j\):

$$\begin{aligned} \bar{q}_i= \frac{2\beta \bar{\alpha }_i-\gamma \bar{\alpha }_j}{4\beta ^2-\gamma ^2} \,\mathrm{and} \,\hat{q}_i = \frac{2\beta \hat{\alpha }_i-\gamma \hat{\alpha }_j}{4\beta ^2-\gamma ^2}. \end{aligned}$$

Moreover, according to (17), \(\hat{\alpha }_1=\bar{\alpha }_1-ac_2\) and \(\hat{\alpha }_2=\bar{\alpha }_2-dc_1\).

Consequently, one can show that a general consumer education scheme results in a demand decrease \(\Delta q_i\), such as:

$$\begin{aligned} \Delta q_1= \frac{2\beta ac_2-\gamma dc_1}{4\beta ^2-\gamma ^2} \,\mathrm{and} \,\Delta q_2= \frac{2\beta dc_1 - \gamma a c_2}{4\beta ^2-\gamma ^2} \end{aligned}$$
(33)

Let us then denote \(G(q_i)\) the increase in consumer welfare ensuing from a lesser consumption of good \(i\). As I want to evaluate in monetary terms the savings educated consumers could enjoy, I naturally obtain \(G(q_i)= \Delta q_i \bar{p}_i^c\). According to (33), for \(i=1\) this is equivalent to:

$$\begin{aligned} G(q_1)=\frac{2\beta ac_2-\gamma dc_1}{4\beta ^2-\gamma ^2} \bar{p}_1^c \end{aligned}$$
(34)

Similarly, one can see that for \(i=2\):

$$\begin{aligned} G(q_2)=\frac{2\beta dc_1-\gamma ac_2}{4\beta ^2-\gamma ^2} \bar{p}_2^c \end{aligned}$$
(35)

Finally, when both firms educate simultaneously their rival’s customers, consumers globally enjoy a welfare increase \(\Delta W\) such as:

$$\begin{aligned} \Delta W&= \frac{2\Delta \alpha _i-\frac{\gamma }{\beta } \Delta \alpha _j}{\beta -\frac{\gamma }{\beta }\gamma } \bar{p}_1^c + \frac{2 \Delta \alpha _j-\frac{\gamma }{\beta } \Delta \alpha _i}{\beta -\frac{\gamma }{\beta }\gamma } \bar{p}_2^c \end{aligned}$$
(36)
$$\begin{aligned} \Delta W&= \frac{2ac_2-\frac{\gamma }{\beta }dc_1}{\beta -\frac{\gamma }{\beta }\gamma } \bar{p}_1^c + \frac{2dc_1-\frac{\gamma }{\beta } ac_2}{\beta -\frac{\gamma }{\beta }\gamma } \bar{p}_2^c \end{aligned}$$
(37)

I next want to determine when debiasing is socially efficient, that is to say when the benefits exceeds the costs. The welfare condition can be written :

$$\begin{aligned} c_1 + c_2 < \frac{2ac_2-\frac{\gamma }{\beta }dc_1}{\beta -\frac{\gamma }{\beta }\gamma } \bar{p}_1^c + \frac{2dc_1-\frac{\gamma }{\beta } ac_2}{\beta -\frac{\gamma }{\beta }\gamma } \bar{p}_2^c \end{aligned}$$
(38)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Bienenstock, S. Consumer education: why the market doesn’t work. Eur J Law Econ 42, 237–262 (2016). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10657-014-9446-z

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10657-014-9446-z

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation