Skip to main content

Theory of Monetary Policy

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Book cover Monetary Economics in Globalised Financial Markets
  • 1977 Accesses

Semper aliquid haeret.

– Francis Bacon to adapt Plutarch

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 109.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 139.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 179.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    Knight’s emphasis on uncertainty decoupled him from the predominant economic theory of the time, which emphasized decision-making under conditions of perfect certainty or under the established laws of probability.

  2. 2.

    Note, however, that those Central and Eastern European EU economies currently in the waiting room for entering the European Monetary Union (the so-called members with a derogation, a bulk off them being members of the ERM II) might strive to converge with the euro area economy before they will enter it as full members. For instance, they adapt their monetary policy strategies to that of the ECB and money demand might become more stable. Hence, the probability of structural breaks due to the entry of new members should be significantly lower than at the start of EMU.

  3. 3.

    See Kydland and Prescott (1977). The earlier literature focused on time inconsistency leading to the well-known inflation bias and on means of overcoming policy imperfections. More recently, time inconsistency issues have attracted renewed attention due to the large influence of the New Keynesian theoretical framework. See, for instance, Calvo (1978) and Clarida, Gali, and Gertler (1999).7See in this context, for instance, Dennis (2003).

  4. 4.

    The proper perspective for addressing such issues is found in the principal-agent literature. See, for instance, Persson and Tabellini (1993).

  5. 5.

    OECD (2005) applies a consistent procedure to derive policy priorities to foster growth across OECD countries and identifies labour market reforms as being particularly important in, e.g., the Euro area. However, this does not at all imply that reforms in other areas are unimportant. Hence, we analyze a variety of different reform measures in the empirical part of this section.

  6. 6.

    van Poeck and Borghijs (2001) argue that the prospect of qualifying for EMU should provide as big an incentive for labour-market reform as EMU membership itself. They conclude that EMU countries did not reform more than other countries and, unlike elsewhere, their progress on reform seemed unrelated to the initial level of unemployment. For a period from the early nineties up to 1999, Bertola and Boeri (2001) only focus on cash transfers to people of working age, e.g. unemployment benefits, and on job protection. They arrive at exactly opposite conclusions, i.e. reforms accelerated more in the euro area than outside.

    The IMF (2004) looks at the impact of a range of factors including macroeconomic conditions, political institutions, reform design and variables aimed to capture attitudes towards structural reform on different policy areas across OECD countries from the mid-1970s up to the late 1990s. It finds that EU membership leads to faster moves towards liberalization of product markets. However, it does not clarify whether this represents an effect of EMU and/or policies to prepare for EMU. See also Duval and Elmeskov (2005, p. 10).

  7. 7.

    For a recent survey of the arguments see Duval and Elmeskov (2005) and Hochreiter and Tavlas (2005).

  8. 8.

    See Alogoskoufis (1994), Calmfors (1997), Duval and Elmeskov (2005,p. 6), Mélitz (1997), and Sibert and Sutherland (1997).

  9. 9.

    See, Bean (1998), Calmfors (1998, p. 28), Duval and Elmeskov (2005, p. 5), and Saint-Paul and Bentolila (2000).

  10. 10.

    The analytical framework was initially developed by Barro and Gordon (1983a, 1983b), Kydland and Prescott (1977), Sibert and Sutherland (1997), and Svensson (1997).

  11. 11.

    Alternatively, labour market reforms might contain the reduction of unemployment benefits, the rise of the efficiency of labour market policy, the substitution of collective by individual wage negotiations, lower minimum wages for young employees, the revision of the laws of wage negotiations (increasing the negotiation power of employees) and the reduction of both taxes and employment protection in general reform reduce equilibrium unemployment. See for instance, Buscher et al. (2005). Daveri & Tabellini (2000), Lindbeck and Snower, and Nicoletti and Scarpetta (2005). For the interrelation of product and labour market reforms see Ebell and Haefke (2003), Kugler and Pica (2004) and Nicoletti and Scarpetta (2005).

  12. 12.

    McCallum (1995) and Jensen (1997) both refer to the problem that the combination of “delegation and proper incentive schemes” is not able to eliminate the inflation bias completely as long as a discretionary national stabilization policy is maintained.

  13. 13.

    Concerning the structure of the game, the expected loss function should be minimized. But for clarity of exposition, the expectations operator is left out.

  14. 14.

    Strictly speaking, the monetary rule can in this case simply be expressed as a k-percent rule without feedback component.

  15. 15.

    An increase of nominal rigidities intensifies the credibility problem of monetary policy. Hence, the incentive of politicians to reduce the increasing credibility problem by more labour market reforms expands. However, this effect should be – and actually is according to the extensive calibrations by Belke and Kamp (1999a, 1999b), Sect. 4.3 – less relevant in reality if the nominal rigidities are diminished by market-oriented reforms, resulting in higher wage flexibility.

  16. 16.

    See Lohmann (1992). The Lohmann trade-off describes the trade-off between the utility of a monetary policy rule by commitment and the costs by the loss in flexibility.

  17. 17.

    See Alogoskoufis, Lockwood, and Philippopoulos (1992, p. 1384) and Ellis and Thoma (1990, pp. 17 and 24).

  18. 18.

    See Alesina and Roubini (1992, pp. 673–674), Alogoskoufis and Philippopoulos (1992, p. 397), Alogoskoufis et al. (1992, pp. 1370–1371), and Annett (1993, pp. 25 and 33).

  19. 19.

    See Simmons (1994, p. 59), Ellis and Thoma (1990) estimate rational partisan theory approaches for open economies. In their study, party-specific inflation rates lead to party specific differences in exchange rate movements.

  20. 20.

    Crowe and Meade (2007) survey and quantify the trends in two major areas of central bank governance: independence and transparency. We document the steady progress toward greater central bank independence and transparency in a large number of industrial and developing countries over the past 10–15 years and discuss the effects of these aspects of governance on inflation. See also Neumann (2002).

  21. 21.

    The notion that the central bank might be subject to an inflation bias has its roots in the literature on the time inconsistency, problem which is developed in Sect. 6.3 above.

  22. 22.

    An efficient decision making is given in this context, if no unnecessary delays occur in monetary policy making and the decisions are made at minimal costs.

  23. 23.

    This advantage can also be understood as a handicap of our approach because voting situation in the ECB Governing Council is not displayed with all its particularities. This argument will be considered shortly in the conclusions, where we show up possibilities for further research.

  24. 24.

    The characteristic function is a function, denoted v, that associates a number, denoted v(C) with every subset C (coalition) of N (player set). The number v(C) is interpreted as the value created when the members of C cooperate.

  25. 25.

    Additionally, the following conditions should hold: The set of all players forms a winning coalition, the set of zero players represents a losing coalition and the addition of players to a coalition cannot turn it from winning to losing.

  26. 26.

    Widgrén (1994) also calculates both indices for the Council of Ministers of the European Community. Nevertheless he interprets the Shapley-Shubik index despite the fact that the analyzed council decides over public goods. His main argument is the high level of communication within the committee.

  27. 27.

    The assumption of nationally biased voting behaviour of national central bank presidents has also been applied in Bindseil (2001) and de Grauwe (2003, p. 21).

  28. 28.

    The consideration of the Executive Board as one player also significantly simplifies the calculations. Power Indices can be calculated exactly for games with approximately not more than 27 players. This restriction results of the time of calculation which doubles when adding one new player.

  29. 29.

    Tables 6.6 and 6.7 reveal the relative voting frequencies that have been used in the calculation of power indices.

  30. 30.

    Remember that in our setup power indices identify the voting power of every player according to his influence on the voting outcome. Most of these indices start from the idea of a swing: a player i has a swing when his exit out of a winning coalition C turns it to a losing one. Player i is then decisive for the coalition C. See extensively our above section on how to apply the power index concept.

  31. 31.

    If the Banzhaf index is considered instead, the differences are even larger. In this case, the Executive Board has 14 to 70 times more power at its disposal.

  32. 32.

    The development of the Banzhaf index reveals significant breaks at similar stages of the euro-area enlargement process as the Shapley index does (Fig. 7.13).

  33. 33.

    For a review of such paradoxes see Holler and Kellermann (1978, p. 107).

  34. 34.

    The numbers refer to the calculated Shapley values.

  35. 35.

    The exact results are summarised in Belke and Styczynska (2006), Annex, Table A.3.

  36. 36.

    See the discussion of the assumptions in our above section on how to apply the power index concept.

  37. 37.

    The Shapley index is normally closer to the voting rights than the Banzhaf index, as discussed in Sutter (2001, p. 341).

  38. 38.

    The explanation is that the indices can always be summed up to one and the Banzhaf indices were higher for the Executive Board.

  39. 39.

    See ECB (2003, p. 75). See also Bofinger (2003, p. 3) and Gros (2003).

  40. 40.

    See also Belke and Styczynska (2006), Table A.2; using this definition, we closely follow Berger (2002, p. 12) and Gros (2003, p. 125).

References

  • Abiad, A., & Mody, A. (2005). Financial reform: What shakes it? What shapes it? American Economic Review, 95(1), 66–88.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Akerlof, G., Dickens, W., & Perry, G. (1996). The macroeconomics of low inflation. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 27, 1–59.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alesina, A., & Rosenthal, H. (1989). Partisan cycles in congressional elections and the macroeconomy. American Political Science Review, 83, 373–398.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alesina, A., & Roubini, N. (1992). Political cycles in OECD economies. Review of Economic Studies, 59, 663–688.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alesina, A., & Summers, L. (1993). Central bank independence and macroeconomic performance. Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, 25(2), 157–162.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alogoskoufis, G. S. (1994). On inflation, unemployment and the optimal exchange rate regime. In F. van der Ploeg (Ed.), The handbook of international macroeconomics (pp. 192–223). Cambridge, Oxford: Blackwell.

    Google Scholar 

  • Alogoskoufis, G. S., Lockwood, B., & Philippopoulos, A. (1992). Wage inflation, electoral uncertainty and the exchange rate regime – theory and UK evidence. Economic Journal, 102, 1370–1394.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alogoskoufis, G. S., & Philippopoulos, A. (1992). Inflationary expectations, electoral uncertainty and the exchange rate regime – Greece 1958–1989. European Journal of Political Economy, 8(3), 375–399.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Amend, T. (2003). Mittel- und Osteuropa: Auf dem Weg zum Euro. In HBSC Trinkhaus und Burkhardt (Hrsg.) (pp. 20–23). Währungen 2003/2004.

    Google Scholar 

  • Annett, A. M. (1993). Elections and macroeconomic outcomes in Ireland – 1948–1991. The Economic and Social Review, 25, 21–47.

    Google Scholar 

  • Arellano, M., & Bond, S. (1991). Some tests of specification for panel data: Monte Carlo evidence and an application to employment equations. Review of Economic Studies, 58, 277–297.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arellano, M., & Bover, O. (1995). Another look at the instrumental variables estimation of error-component models. Journal of Econometrics, 68, 29–51.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Backus, D., & Driffill, J. (1985). Inflation and reputation. American Economic Review, 75(3), 530–538.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bade, R., & Parkin, M. (1982). Central bank laws and monetary policy. Unpublished manuscript, Department of Economics, University of Western Ontario, Canada.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bade, R. and M. Parkin. (1984). Central Bank Laws and Monetary Policy. Department of Economics, University of Western Ontario, Canada.

    Google Scholar 

  • Baltagi, B. (1995). Econometric analysis of panel data. Chichester: John Wiley & Sons.

    Google Scholar 

  • Banzhaf, J. F. (1965). Weighted voting doesn’t work: A mathematical analysis. Rutgers Law Review, 19, 317–343.

    Google Scholar 

  • Barro, R. J. (1996, May/June). Inflation and growth. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, Economic Review, 28(3), 153–169.

    Google Scholar 

  • Barro, R. J., & Gordon, D. B. (1983a). Rules, discretion and reputation in a model of monetary policy. Journal of Monetary Economics, 12(1), 101–121.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barro, R. J., & Gordon, D. B. (1983b). A positive theory of monetary policy in a natural rate model. Journal of Political Economy, 91(4), 589–610.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bean, C. (1998). The interaction of aggregate-demand policies and labor-market reform. Swedish Economic Policy Review, 5, 353–382.

    Google Scholar 

  • Beck, T., Clarke, G., Groff, A., Keefer, P., & Walsh, P. (2001). New tools in comparative political economy: The database of political institutions. World Bank Economic Review, 15(1), 165–176.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beetsma, R., & Bovenberg, L. (1998, September). The optimality of a monetary union without a fiscal union (CEPR Discussion Paper 1975) London.

    Google Scholar 

  • Belke, A. (2002). Towards a Balanced Policy Mix under EMU: Co-ordination of Macroeconomic Policies and ‘Economic Government’?. in: Journal of Economic Integration, Vol. 17(1), pp. 21–53.

    Google Scholar 

  • Belke, A. (2003). The rotation model is not sustainable. Intereconomics: Review of European Economic Policy, 38, 119–124.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Belke, A., & Goecke, M. (1999). A simple model of hysteresis in employment under exchange rate uncertainty. Scottish Journal of Political Economy, 46(3), 260–286.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Belke, A., & Goecke, M. (2005). Real options effects on employment: Does exchange rate uncertainty matter for aggregation? German Economic Review, 6(2), 185–203.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Belke, A., & Gros, D. (1999). Estimating the costs and benefits of EMU: The impact of external shocks on labor markets. Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv, 135, 1–48.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Belke, A., & Gros, D. (2007). Instability of the Eurozone? In M. Heise, R. Tilly, P. J. J. Welfens (Eds.), 50 Years of EU dynamics – Integration, financial markets and innovations (pp. 75–108). Berlin: Springer

    Google Scholar 

  • Belke, A., Herz, B., & Vogel, L. (2006a). Reforms, exchange rates and monetary commitment: A panel analysis for OECD countries. Open Economies Review, 18, 369–388.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Belke, A., Herz, B., & Vogel, L. (2006b). Beyond trade – is reform effort affected by the exchange rate regime? A panel analysis for the world versus OECD countries. Économie Internationale, 107, 29–58.

    Google Scholar 

  • Belke, A., Herz, B., & Vogel, L. (2006c). Exchange rate regimes and reforms – a panel analysis for the world versus OECD countries. International Finance, 9(3), 317–342.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Belke, A., Herz, B., & Vogel, L. (2007). Structural reforms and European monetary union: What can a panel analysis for the world versus OECD countries tell us? In D. Cobham (Ed.), The travails of the eurozone: Economic policies and economic developments (pp. 179–204). Houndmills, Basingstoke, UK: Palgrave Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Belke, A., & Kamp, A. (1999a). When do labor market reforms achieve a double dividend under EMU? Discretionary versus rule based monetary policy revisited. Journal of Economic Integration, 14(4), 572–605.

    Google Scholar 

  • Belke, A., & Kamp, M. (1999b). Doppelte ‘Dividende’ oder nur doppelte ‘Funktion’ von Arbeitsmarktreformen bei diskretionärer Geldpolitik? Anmerkungen zum Calmfors-Modell. Jahrbücher für Nationalökonomie und Statistik, 218(5+6), 543–555.

    Google Scholar 

  • Belke, A., Schnable, G., & Zemanek, H. (2009). Current Account Imbalances and Structural Adjustment in the Euro Area: How to Rebalance Competitiveness, forthcoming IZA Discussion Paper, Bonn.

    Google Scholar 

  • Belke, A., & Styczynska, B. (2006). The allocation of power in the enlarged ECB Governing Council – an assessment of the ECB rotation model. Journal of Common Market Studies, 44(5), 865–895.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Berger, H. (2002). The ECB and euro area enlargement (IMF Working Paper, No. 02/175) Washington/DC.

    Google Scholar 

  • Berger, H., de Haan, J., & Inklaar, R. (2002, September 13–14). Should the ECB be restructured, and if so, how? Paper presented at the CESifo Delphi conference on Managing EU Enlargement, Munich.

    Google Scholar 

  • Berthold, N., & Fehn, R. (1996). The positive economics of unemployment and labor market inflexibility. Kyklos, 49, 583–613.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Berthold, N., & Fehn, R. (2006). Unemployment in Germany – reasons and remedies, In M. Werding (Ed.), Unemployment in Europe, CESifo seminar series. Cambridge: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bertola, G., & Boeri, T. (2001, March 21–22, April 27). EMU labor markets two years on: Microeconomic tensions and institutional evolution. Paper presented at the Workshop on “The Functioning of EMU: Challenges of the Early Years”. Brussels: Directorate General for Economic and Financial Affairs, European Commission, p. 498.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bilbao, J. M., Fernandez, J. R., Jimenez, N., & Lopez, J. J. (2002). Voting power in the European union enlargement. European Journal of Operational Research, 143, 181–96.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bindseil, U. (2001). A coalition-form analysis of the one country-one vote rule in the Governing Council of the European central bank. International Economic Journal, 15, 141–64.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blackburn, K., & Christensen, M. (1989). Monetary policy and policy credibility: Theory and evidence. Journal of Economic Literature, 27, 1–45.

    Google Scholar 

  • Blanchard, O. (2006). European unemployment – the evolution of facts and ideas. Economic Policy, 45, 5–47.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blanchard, O., Dornbusch, R., Dreze, J., Giersch, H., Layard, R., & Monti, M. (1986). Employment and growth in Europe – a two-handed approach. In O. Blanchard, R. Dornbusch, & R. Layard (Eds.), Restoring Europe’s prosperity (pp. 95–124). Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Blanchard, O., & Giavazzi, F. (2003). Macroeconomic effects of regulations and deregulation in goods and labour markets. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 118(3), 879–907.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blattner, T., Catenaro, M., Ehrmann, M., Strauch, R., & Turunen, J. (2008, March). The predictability of Monetary Policy ECB Occasional Paper Series, No. 83 Frankfurt/Main.

    Google Scholar 

  • Blundell, R., & Bond, S. (1998). Initial conditions and moment restrictions in dynamic panel data models. Journal of Econometrics, 87, 115–143.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bofinger, P. (2003). Consequences of the modification of the Governing Council rules. Briefing Paper for the committee for monetary and economic affairs (ECON) of the European Parliament, Brussels.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bräuninger, T., & König, T. (2001). Indices of power IOP 2.0 [Computer Programme]. University of Konstanz. Retrieved from http://www.uni-konstanz.de/FuF/Verwiss/koenig/IOP.html, 12 June 2004.

  • Buscher, H., Dreger, C., Ramos, R., & Surinach, J. (2005). The impact of institutions on the employment performance in European labour markets (IZA Discussion Paper 1732). Bonn: Institute for the Study of Labor.

    Google Scholar 

  • Calmfors, L. (1997). Unemployment, labor-market reform and EMU (IIES Seminar Paper 639). Stockholm: Institute for International Economic Studies.

    Google Scholar 

  • Calmfors, L. (1998). Macroeconomic policy, wage setting and employment – what difference does the EMU make? Oxford Economic Policy Review, 14, 125–151.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Calmfors, L. (2001). Unemployment, labor-market reform and monetary union. Journal of Labor Economics, 19(2), 265–289.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Calmfors, L., & Holmlund, B. (2000). Unemployment and economic growth: A partial survey. Swedish Economic Review, 7, 107–153 (Update of Calmfors, 1997).

    Google Scholar 

  • Calvo, G. A. (1978). On the time consistency of optimal policy in a monetary economy. Econometrica, 46(6), 1411–1428.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Campillo, M., & Miron, J. (1997). Why does inflation differ across countries? In C. D. Romer & D. H. Romer (Eds.), Reducing inflation: Motivation and strategy (pp. 335–357). Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Carey, K. (1997). “High Unemployment in the OECD. Does the Diagnosis of the 1980s Apply to the 1990s?,” American University, Washington, mimeo.

    Google Scholar 

  • Castrén, O., Takalo, T., & Wood, G. (2004, November). Labor market reform and the sustainability of exchange rate pegs (ECB Working Paper Series No. 406). Frankfurt, Main: European Central Bank.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cecchetti, S. G., & Rich, R. W. (1999, March 15). Structural estimates of the U.S. sacrifice ratio. New York: Federal Reserve Bank of New York, Research and Market Analysis Group.

    Google Scholar 

  • Clarida, R. Gali, J., & Gertler, M. (1999). The science of monetary policy: A new Keynesian perspective. Journal of Economic Literature, 37(4), 1661–1707.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coe, D. T., & Snower, D. (1997). Policy complementarities: The case for fundamental labor market reform. IMF Staff Papers, 44(1), 1–35.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Connolly, E., & Kohler, M. (2004). News and interest rate expectations: A study of six central banks (Reserve Bank of Australia Research Discussion Paper, 10).

    Google Scholar 

  • Crowe, C., & Meade, E. E. (2007). The evolution of central bank governance around the world. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 21(4), 69–90.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cukierman, A. (1992). Central bank strategy, credibility, and independence: Theory and evidence. Cambridge, MA: The MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cukierman, A., Webb, S. B., & Neyapti, B. (1992). Measuring the independence of central banks and its effects on policy outcomes, The World Bank Economic Review, 6, 353–398.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Daily Telegraph. (2007, December 31). Cyprus and Malta Tip Euro balance, by Ambrose Evans-Pritchard, http://www.telegraph.co.uk/money/main.jhtml?xml=/money/2007/12/31/cceuro131.xml

  • Daveri, F., & Tabellini, G. (2000). Unemployment, growth and taxation in industrial countries. Economic Policy, 15, 47–104.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De Grauwe, P. (2003, 4 April). The challenge of enlargement of Euroland. Paper presented at the Spring Meeting of Young Economists, Leuven.

    Google Scholar 

  • Debelle, G., & Fischer, S. (1994). How independent should a central bank be? In J. C. Fuhrer (Ed.), Goals, guidelines and constraints facing monetary policymakers (pp. 195–221). Boston: Federal Reserve Bank of Boston.

    Google Scholar 

  • De Haan, J., Masciandaro, D., & Quintyn, M. (2008). Does central bank independence still matter? European Journal of Political Economy, 24, 717–721.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dennis, R. (2003, April 11). Time-inconsistent monetary policies: Recent research. FRBSF Economic Letter, 2003–10.

    Google Scholar 

  • Deutsche Bundesbank. (2004, June). Monetary policy under uncertainty. Monthly Bulletin, 15–28.

    Google Scholar 

  • Drazen, A., & Easterly, W. (2001). Do crises induce reform? Simple empirical tests of conventional wisdom. Economics and Politics, 13, 139–157.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dreyer, J., & Schotter, A. (1980). Power relationship in the International Monetary Fund: The consequences of quota changes. Review of Economics and Statistics, 62, 97–106.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Duval, R., & Elmeskov, J. (2005). The effects of EMU on structural reforms in labor and product markets (OECD Economics Department Working Papers 438). Paris: Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ebell, M., & Haefke, C. (2003). Product market deregulation and labour market outcomes (Swiss National Bank Working Papers 02, 08).

    Google Scholar 

  • Ehrmann, M., & Fratzscher, M. (2005). Communication and decision-making by central bank committees: Different strategies, same effectiveness? (ECB Working Paper, 488). Frankfurt, Main: European Central Bank.

    Google Scholar 

  • Eichengreen, B., & von Hagen, J. (1996). Federalism, fiscal restraints and European monetary union. American Economic Review, 86, 134–138.

    Google Scholar 

  • Eijffinger, S., & de Haan, J. (1996). The political economy of central-bank independence (Special Papers in International Economics, No. 19). Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ellis, C. J., & Thoma, M. A. (1990). The implications for an open economy of partisan political business cycles: Theory and evidence (Department of Economics Working Paper 90/2), University of Oregon.

    Google Scholar 

  • Emerson, M., Gros, D., Italianer, A., Pisani-Ferry, J., & Reichenbach, H. (1992). One market, one money. An evaluation of the potential benefits and costs of forming an economic and monetary union. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • European Central Bank. (1999, May). The implementation of the stability and growth pact. Monthly Bulletin, Frankfurt/Main: European Central Bank.

    Google Scholar 

  • European Central Bank. (2003, May). The adjustment of voting modalities in the Governing Council. In Monthly bulletin (pp. 73–83). Frankfurt, Main: European Central Bank.

    Google Scholar 

  • European Central Bank. (2004). ECB annual report. Frankfurt, Main: European Central Bank.

    Google Scholar 

  • European Central Bank. (2006, January). The predictability of the ECB’s monetary policy. In ECB monthly bulletin (pp. 51–61). Frankfurt, Main: European Central Bank.

    Google Scholar 

  • Eurostat. (2003a, September 23) The GDP of the acceding countries. Retrieved from http://europa.eu.int/comm/eurostat/, catalogue number: KS-NJ-03-047-DE-N.

  • Eurostat. (2003b, September 23) The GDP. Retrieved from http://europa.eu.int/comm/eurostat/, catalogue number: KS-NJ-03-035-DE-N.

  • Fahrholz, C., & Mohl, P. (2004, June 1). EMU-enlargement and the reshaping of decision-making within the ECB Governing Council: A voting-power analysis (Ezoneplus Working Paper, No. 23). Berlin (draft version).

    Google Scholar 

  • Feldstein, M. (1999). The costs and benefits of price stability. National Bureau of Economic Research, Conference Report.

    Google Scholar 

  • Felsenthal, D. S., & Machover, M. (1998). The measurement of voting power: Theory and practice, problems and paradoxes. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fischer, B., Lenza, M., Pill, H., & Reichlin, L. (2006, November 9–10). Money and monetary policy: ECB 1999–2006. Paper prepared for the Fourth ECB Central Banking Conference on “The Role of Money: Money and Monetary Policy in the Twenty-First Century”. Frankfurt, Main: European Central Bank.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fisher, I. (1929). The purchasing power of money (2nd ed.). New York: Macmillan, 1911, New York: Macmillan, 1913, New ed., New York: Macmillan, p. 486.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fisher, S. (1990). Rules versus discretion in monetary policy. In B. Friedman & F. H. Hahn (Eds.), Handbook of monetary economics, II (pp. 1155–1184). Amsterdam, North Holland: Elsevier Science Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Freytag, A. (2005). The credibility of monetary reform: New evidence. Public Choice, 124(3), 391–409.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Friedman, M. (1961). The lag in effect of monetary policy. Journal of Political Economy, 69, 447–466.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Friedman, M. (1994). Money mischief. San Diego, CA: Harcourt Brace & Company.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fuhrer, J. (1997, January). Central bank independence and inflation targeting: Monetary policy paradigms for the next millenium? New England Economic Review, Federal Reserve Bank of Boston, January 19–36.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gordon, R. (1996). “Macroeconomic Policy in the Presence of Structural Maladjustments,” Paper presented at the OECD Proceedings on Interactions between Structural Reform, Macroeconomic Policies and Economic Performance, Paris.

    Google Scholar 

  • Grilli, V., Masciandaro, D., & Tabellini, G. (1991). Political and monetary institutions and public financial policies in the industrial countries. Economic Policy, 6, 341–392.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gros, D. (2003). Reforming the composition of the ECB Governing Council in view of enlargement: An opportunity missed!, Intereconomics. Review of European Economic Policy, 38, 124–29.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gros, D., & Thygesen, N. (1998). European monetary integration – From the European monetary system to economic and monetary union (2nd ed.). Longman, Harlow: Addison Wesley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gros, D., Mayer, T., & Ubide, A. (2005, June). EMU at risk, 7th annual report of the CEPS macroeconomic policy group. Brussels: Centre for European Policy Studies (CEPS).

    Google Scholar 

  • Gruener, H. P. (1998). On the role of conflicting national interests in the ECB-Council (CEPR Discussion Paper No. 2216) London: Centre for Economic Policy Research.

    Google Scholar 

  • Grüner, H. S., & Hefeker, C. (1996). Militant labor and inflation aversion – The impact of EMU on labor union interaction (SFB 303 Discussion Paper A-539), University of Bonn.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gwartney, J., & Lawson, R. (2003). The concept and measurement of economic freedom. European Journal of Political Economy, 19, 405–430.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gwartney, J., Lawson, R., Park, W., & Skipton, C. (2003). Economic freedom of the world: 2003 annual report. Vancouver: Fraser Institute.

    Google Scholar 

  • Haffner, R. C. G., Nickell, S., Nicoletti, G., Scarpetta, S., & Zoega, G. (2000). European integration, liberalisation and labor market performance: Report for the Fondazione Rodolfo De Benedetti.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hango, B., & Hefeker, C. (2002). Reconsidering Central Bank Independence, European Journal of Political Economy, 78, 653–674.

    Google Scholar 

  • Heinemann, F. (2004). Explaining reform deadlocks. Applied Economics Quarterly Supplement, 55, 9–26.

    Google Scholar 

  • Heinemann, F. (2005). How distant is Lisbon from Maastricht? The Short-run Link Between Structural Reforms and Budgetary Performance, mimeo, prepared for the DG ECFIN workshop ‘Budgetary implications of structural reforms’, Brussels, 2 December 2005.

    Google Scholar 

  • Helbling, T., Hakura, D., & Debrun, X. (2004). Fostering structural reforms in industrial countries. In World economic outlook 2004 (chap. III, pp. 103–146). Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund.

    Google Scholar 

  • Henisz, W. (2000). The institutional environment for economic growth. Economics and Politics, 12(1), 1–31.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Henisz, W. (2002). The institutional environment for infrastructure investment. Industrial and Corporate Change, 11(2), 355–389.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Herrendorf, B., & Neumann, M. J. M. (2003). The political economy of inflation, labour market distortions, and central bank independence. The Economic Journal, 113, 43–64.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Herz, B., & Vogel, L. (2005). Determinants of market-oriented policy reforms: An empirical analysis. Mimeo.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hochreiter, E., & Tavlas, G. S. (2005). The two roads to the euro: The monetary experiences of Austria and Greece. In S. Schadler (Ed.), Euro Adoption in Central and Eastern Europe – Opportunities and Challenges (pp. 187–201). Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund.

    Google Scholar 

  • Holler, M. J., & Kellermann, J. (1978). Die a-priori-Abstimmungsstärke im europäischen Parlament. Kyklos, 31, 107–111.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hsiao, C. (2003). Analysis of panel data. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • IMF (2003). International financial statistics. CD-ROM. Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund.

    Google Scholar 

  • IMF (2004). Fostering structural reforms in industrial countries. Chapter III in World Economic Outlook, Advancing Structural Reforms, International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC.

    Google Scholar 

  • Issing, O. (2002, December 9). Monetary policy in a world of uncertainty. Fondation Banque de France Centre d’Etudes Prospectives et d.Informations Internationales CEPII Université Aix-Marseille IDE, Paris, http://www.banque-france.fr/gb/fondatio/telechar/issing.pdf

  • Jensen, H. (1997). Credibility of optimal monetary delegation. American Economic Review, 87, 911–920.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jimeno, J. (2005, June). Comments on Duval, R., & Elmeskov, J. The effects of EMU on structural reforms in labor and product markets. Paper prepared for the Conference on “What Effects is EMU Having on the Euro Area and its Member Countries?”, Frankfurt, Main: European Central Bank.

    Google Scholar 

  • Johansson, A. (1998, April). The interaction between labor market policy and monetary policy: An analysis of time inconsistency, Mimeo. Paper presented at the Institute for International Economic Studies Seminar, Stockholm.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jonsson, G. (1997). Monetary politics and unemployment persistence. Journal of Monetary Economics, 39(2), 303–325.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Katzenstein, P. (1985). Small states in world markets. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Keynes, J. M. (1936). The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money, New York: Harcourt, Brace.

    Google Scholar 

  • Knight, F. (1964, 1921), Risk, Uncertainty and Profit, New York: Century Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Krugman, P., & Obstfeld, M. (2003). International economics – Theory and policy. Boston, Mass.: Addison Wesley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kugler, A., & Pica, G. (2004, June). Effects of employment protection and product market regulation on the Italian labor market. Paper presented at the CEPR/ECB Workshop.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kydland, F., & Prescott, E. (1977). Rules rather than discretion: The inconsistency of optimal plans. Journal of Political Economy, 87, 473–492.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lane, J.-E., & Maeland, R. (2000). Constitutional analysis: The power index approach. European Journal of Political Research, 37, 31–56.

    Google Scholar 

  • Layard, R., Jackman, R., & Nickell, S. (1991). Unemployment. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Layard, R, Jackman, R., & Nickell, S. (1994). The unemployment crisis. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Leech, D. (2001a). Members voting power in the governance of the international monetary fund (CSGR Working Paper No. 68/01), University of Warwick.

    Google Scholar 

  • Leech, D. (2001b). Fair re-weighting of the votes in the EU Council of Ministers and the choice of majority requirement for qualified majority voting during successive enlargements (Warwick Economic Research Paper No. 587), University of Warwick.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lindbeck, A. (1992). Macroeconomic theory and the labor market. European Economic Review, 36(2–3), 209–235.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lindbeck, A., & Snower, D. (1997). Centralized bargaining, multi-tasking and work incentives (CEPR Discussion Paper 1563). London: Center for Economic Policy Research.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lohmann, S. (1992). “The Optimal Degree of Commitment: Credibility and Flexibility,” American Economic Review 82; pp. 273–286.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lohmann, S. (1993). Electoral cycles and international policy coordination. European Economic Review, 37(7), 1373–1391.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lommatzsch, K., & Tober, S. (2003). Voting rules in the ECB Governing Council following enlargement of the euro area. Economic Bulletin, 40, 91–94.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lora, E. (2000). What makes reforms likely? Timing and sequencing of structural reforms in latin America (Inter-American Development Bank Working Papers, 424), Washington, DC.

    Google Scholar 

  • McCallum, B. (1995, May). Two fallacies concerning central bank independence. American Economic Review, Papers and Proceedings, 85(2), 207–211.

    Google Scholar 

  • Meade, E. E. (2003a, July 28). EU enlargement and ECB decision making. Online Article, Project syndicate. Retrieved from http://www.project-syndicate.org

  • Meade, E. E. (2003b). A (critical) appraisal of the ECB’s voting reform, intereconomics. Review of European Economic Policy, 38, 129–131.

    Google Scholar 

  • Meade, E. E. (2003c, July 28). How independent is the ECB? Online Article, Project syndicate. Retrieved from http://www.project-sydicate.org

  • Meade E. E., & Sheets, D. N. (2002). Regional Influences on U.S. Monetary Policy: Some Implications for Europe, CEP Discussion Paper, No. 523 London.

    Google Scholar 

  • Meade, E. E., & Sheets, D. N. (2005). Regional influences on FOMC voting patterns. Journal of Money Credit and Banking, 33, 661–678.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mélitz, J. (1997). The evidence about the costs and benefits of EMU. Swedish Economic Policy Review, 4(2), 191–234.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mundschenk, S., & von Hagen, J. (2002). The political economy of policy coordination in Europe. Swedish Review of Economic Policy, 8, 11–41.

    Google Scholar 

  • Neumann, M. J. M. (2002). Transparency in monetary policy. Atlantic Economic Journal, 30(4), 353–364.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nickell, S. (1997). Unemployment and European labor market rigidities – Europe versus North America. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 11, 55–74.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nickell, S. (2005, June). Comments on Duval, R., & Elmeskov, J. The effects of EMU on structural reforms in labor and product markets, Mimeo. Paper prepared for the Conference on “What Effects is EMU Having on the Euro Area and its Member Countries?” Frankfurt, Main: European Central Bank.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nicoletti G., Golub, S., Hajkova, D., Mirza, D., & Yoo, K.-Y. (2003). Policies and international integration: Influences on trade and foreign direct investment (OECD Economics Department Working Papers 359).

    Google Scholar 

  • Nicoletti, G., & Scarpetta, S. (2005). Product market reforms and employment in OECD countries (OECD Economics Department Working Paper 472), Paris: OECD = Organisation for Economic Cooperation and Development.

    Google Scholar 

  • OECD. (2005). Economic policy reforms, going for growth. Paris: OECD = Organisation for Economic Cooperation and Development.

    Google Scholar 

  • Orphanides, A. (2003). The quest for prosperity without inflation. Journal of Monetary Economics, 50(3), 633–663.

    Google Scholar 

  • Orszag, M., & Snower, D. (1998). Anatomy of policy complementarities. Swedish Economic Policy Review, 5(2), 303–345.

    Google Scholar 

  • Owen, G. (1977). Values of games with a priori unions. In R. Hein & O. Moeschlin (Eds.), Essays in mathematical economics and game theory. Berlin: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Owen, G. (1995). Game theory (3rd ed.). Orlando: Academic Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ozkan, F. G., Sibert, A. C., & Sutherland, A. (1997, November). Monetary union, entry conditions and economic reform (CEPR Discussion Paper 1720), Center for Economic Policy Research, London.

    Google Scholar 

  • Persson, T., & Tabellini, G. (1990). Macroeconomic policy, credibility and politics, fundamentals of pure and applied economics. Chur: Harwood Academic Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Persson, T., & Tabellini, G. (1993). Designing institutions for monetary stability. Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, 39, 53–84.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Persson, T., & Tabellini, G. (1994). Monetary and fiscal policy, Volume 2: Politics. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pitlik, H. (2004). Are Less Constrained Governments Really More Successful in Executing Market-Oriented Policy Changes?, Diskussionsbeiträge aus dem Institut für Volkswirtschaftslehre der Universität Hohenheim 255/2005, University Hohenheim, Stuttgart.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pitlik, H., & Wirth, S. (2003). Do crises promote the extent of economic liberalization? European Journal of Political Economy, 19(3), 565–581.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Posen, A. (1993). Why central bank independence does not cause low inflation: There is no institutional fix for politics. In R. O’Brien (Ed.), Finance and the international economy 7 (pp. 40–65). Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Reinhart, C. M., & Rogoff, K S. (2002). The modern history of exchange rate regime arrangements: A reinterpretation (NBER Working Paper 8963). Cambridge, Mass.: National Bureau of Economic Research.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rodrik, D. (1996). Understanding economic policy reform. Journal of Economic Literature, 34(1), 9–41.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rogoff, K. S. (1985). The optimal commitment to an intermediate monetary target. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 100, 1169–1189.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Saint-Paul, G. (1993). On the political economy of labor market flexibility. NBER Macroeconomics Annual, 78, 151–187.

    Google Scholar 

  • Saint-Paul, G. (1996). Exploring the political economy of labor market institutions. Economic Policy, 23, 265–315.

    Google Scholar 

  • Saint-Paul, G., & Bentolila, S. (2000, April). Will EMU increase eurosclerosis? International macroeconomics and labor economics (CEPR Discussion Paper 2423), Center of Economic Policy Research, London.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schulze, L. (2005). Reform der Abstimmungsregeln und Inflationspräferenz im EZB-Rat. Wirtschaftsdienst, 85, 724–730.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shapley, L. S. (1997). A value on n-person games. In H. W. Kuhn (Ed.), Classics in game theory. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shaw, E. S. (1958). Money supply and stable economic growth. In United States monetary policy (pp. 49–71). New York: American Assembly.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sibert, A. C., & Sutherland, A. (1997, November). Monetary regimes and labor market reform (CEPR Discussion Paper 1731), London.

    Google Scholar 

  • Simmons, B. A. (1994). Who adjusts? – Domestic sources of foreign economic policy during the interwar years. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Simons, H. C. (1948). Rules versus authorities in monetary policy. In Economic policy for a free society (pp. 40–77). Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Straffin, P. (1980). Topics in the theory of voting. Boston: Birkhauser.

    Google Scholar 

  • Straffin, P. (1988). The Shapley-Shubik and Banzhaf power indices as probabilities, In A. E. Roth (Ed.), The shapley value: Essays in honor of Lloyd S. Shapley. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sutter, M. (2001). Messung der Abstimmungsmacht und Anwendung auf den EU-Ministerrat. Wirtschaftliches Studium, 6, 339–341.

    Google Scholar 

  • Svensson, L. (1997). Optimal inflation targets, “conservative” central banks, and linear inflation contracts. American Economic Review, 87, 98–114.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tootell, G. M. B. (1996, November). Whose monetary policy is it, anyway? Boston: Mimeo, Federal Reserve Bank of Boston.

    Google Scholar 

  • van Poeck, A., & Borghijs, A. (2001). EMU and labor market reform: Needs, incentives and realisations. Oxford: Blackwell Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Von Hagen, J. (2003). EMU: Monetary policy issues and challenges, In M. Baimbridge (Ed.), Economic and monetary union in europe. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Walsh, C. E. (1995). Optimal contracts for central bankers. American Economic Review, 85, 150–167.

    Google Scholar 

  • Walsh, C. E. (2003). Monetary theory and policy (2nd ed.). Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Widgrén, M. (1994). Voting power in the EC decision-making and the consequences of two different enlargements. European Economic Review, 38, 1153–1170.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wilhelmsen, B.-R., & Zaghini, A. (2005, July). Monetary policy predictability in the euro area: An international comparison (ECB Working Paper No 504). Frankfurt, Main: European Central Bank.

    Google Scholar 

  • Woodford, M. (2006, November 9–10). How important is money in the conduct of monetary policy, Columbia University. Paper prepared for the Fourth ECB Central Banking conference on The Role of Money: Money and Monetary Policy in the Twenty-First Century. Frankfurt, Main: European Central Bank.

    Google Scholar 

  • World Bank. (2002). World development indicators. Washington, DC: World Bank Publications.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Ansgar Belke .

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2009 Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Belke, A., Polleit, T. (2009). Theory of Monetary Policy. In: Monetary Economics in Globalised Financial Markets. Springer, Berlin, Heidelberg. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-540-71003-5_6

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-540-71003-5_6

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Springer, Berlin, Heidelberg

  • Print ISBN: 978-3-540-71002-8

  • Online ISBN: 978-3-540-71003-5

  • eBook Packages: Business and EconomicsEconomics and Finance (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics