Skip to main content

Cartels

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
  • 4790 Accesses

Part of the book series: Springer Texts in Business and Economics ((STBE))

Abstract

We have seen in previous chapters how equilibrium price is substantially higher in monopoly than in perfectly competitive markets. In this chapter, we begin to investigate how price and output are determined in oligopoly markets that lie between these polar extremes. There are two types of oligopoly models, those that assume cooperative behavior and those that assume noncooperative behavior. In this chapter, we focus on cooperative settings or cooperative games. In the next two chapters we discuss noncooperative models.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution.

Buying options

Chapter
USD   29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD   54.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD   69.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD   109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Learn about institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    It is sometimes called conscious parallelism, as firms make strategic moves in concert without being formal members of a cartel. Concert actions do not necessarily imply collusion, however, as competitive firms may behave in unison as well. For further discussion, see Scherer and Ross (1990, Chap. 9).

  2. 2.

    These data derive from Hammond (2005, 2010).

  3. 3.

    This problem is identical to that of a multiplant monopolist, except that 1 and 2 refer to production plants, not firms, in the multiplant monopoly problem.

  4. 4.

    We can see this by considering a more general model, where the objective is to maximize Π = p(Q) · Q − TC1 − TC2 with respect to q 1 and q 2, where TC i is firm i’s total cost. The first-order conditions are

    $$ \frac{{\partial \Pi }}{{\partial {q_1}}} = p + \frac{{\partial p}}{{\partial {q_1}}}Q - {\hbox{M}}{{\hbox{C}}_1} = 0, $$
    $$ \frac{{\partial \Pi }}{{\partial {q_2}}} = p + \frac{{\partial p}}{{\partial {q_2}}}Q - {\hbox{M}}{{\hbox{C}}_2} = 0, $$

    where MC i is firm i’s marginal cost. These conditions imply that the marginal revenue for the industry must equal marginal cost of production, whether produced by firm 1 or firm 2. Notice how the first-order condition for an individual firm that maximizes its own profit is different from the first equation above. For firm 1, the difference is that the second term within the equal signs in the first equation above would be multiplied by q 1 instead of Q. This means that when firm 1 considers increasing q 1, it pays attention to the effect that this has on the total revenue of the entire industry, rather than just its own total revenue, when it is a member of the cartel. Because ∂p/∂q 1 and Q > q 1, the firm’s marginal benefit of producing an additional unit of output is less under a cartel. Thus, each firm will produce less output in a cartel setting.

  5. 5.

    This equation maps out a curve that is much like an indifference curve in consumer theory and an isoquant in production theory. For an isoprofit function, profit is held constant rather than utility (in an indifference curve) or firm production (in an isoquant). For a review of indifference curves and isoquants, see Bernheim and Whinston (2008), Pindyck and Rubenfield (2009), or Varian (2010).

  6. 6.

    In a price war, each firm has an incentive to undercut the price of its competitor, which can lead to competitive pricing. We discuss the details of price undercutting in the next chapter.

  7. 7.

    That is, when q 1 = 4 and q 2 = 3, firm 1’s profit equals (12 − q 1 − q 2)q 1 = 20 and firm 2’s profit equals (12 − q 1 − q 2)q 2 = 15.

  8. 8.

    In the next chapter, we will see that this is a special type of Nash equilibrium, first investigated by Cournot (1838).

  9. 9.

    In this case, firms play a game with antitrust authorities, which may cause them to limit price below the joint profit-maximizing level to avoid antitrust scrutiny.

  10. 10.

    This is sometimes called a most-favored-nation clause (Salop 1986).

  11. 11.

    Chen and Liu (2011) point out that there may be other reasons for implementing a most-favored-customer clause. In their study of electronics retailers, they found that Best Buy introduced such a clause in order to gain market share from its chief competitors.

  12. 12.

    See Salop (1986) for more detailed discussion.

  13. 13.

    Normally, firm i is assumed to revert to a Nash equilibrium price or output strategy once firm j cheats.

  14. 14.

    The reason is that with homogeneous goods, all consumers will buy from the low-priced producer. Thus, that firm will sell approximately the monopoly output and its competitors will sell nothing. This is consistent with a Bertrand outcome, which we will discuss in Chap. 10.

  15. 15.

    Note that when D is less than 1, the left-hand side of the inequality does not sum to infinity.

  16. 16.

    For more extensive reviews, see Scherer and Ross (1990, Chaps. 6–9), Waldman and Jensen (2006, Chaps. 9 and 10), and Levenstein and Suslow (2006).

  17. 17.

    The notable exception is the study by Asch and Seneca (1975), which found that colluding firms earned lower profits than noncolluding firms. Their empirical model does not control for industry differences or other important determinants of profitability, however. Another potential concern is that cartels may form in less profitable industries.

  18. 18.

    For a review of auction theory and a discussion of eBay auctions, see Hasker and Sickles (2010).

  19. 19.

    Eckbo (1976) also finds that cartel success is more likely when demand is sufficiently inelastic. This implies few close substitutes for the cartelized product and a greater gain in profits when moving from a competitive to a cartel outcome.

  20. 20.

    Alternatively, Rotemberg and Saloner (1986) argue that price cuts are more likely during boom periods, because the benefit from price cutting is greater during a boom.

  21. 21.

    This discussion borrows from Adams and Mueller (1990) and Scherer (1996).

  22. 22.

    These include Carnegie Steel, Federal Steel, American Steel and Wire, American Plate, American Steel Hoop, American Bridge Company, and Lake Superior Consolidated Iron Mines.

  23. 23.

    United States v. United States Steel Corporation et al., 251 US 417 (1920). Although this behavior would be considered illegal today, the Supreme Court acquitted US Steel because the government challenged the monopoly status of the company (under Section 2 of the Sherman Act) rather than its collusive behavior (under Section 1). The government could not make a strong enough case that US Steel had monopolized the market because its market share had fallen from 65% to 52% from 1907 to 1915.

  24. 24.

    This discussion borrows from Scherer (1996), Martin (2005), Mufson (2007), Perry (2007), El-Tablawy (2008), Samuelson (2008), and Jahn (2009).

  25. 25.

    Ecuador, Gabon, and Indonesia also joined OPEC but later left.

  26. 26.

    OPEC’s stated objective “is to co-ordinate and unify petroleum policies among Member Countries, in order to secure fair and stable prices for petroleum producers; an efficient, economic and regular supply of petroleum to consuming nations; and a fair return on capital to those investing in the industry.” Available at http://www.opec.org, accessed May 15, 2010.

  27. 27.

    This discussion borrows from the Department of Justice (May 21, 1999), Europa (2001), and Bush et al. (2004).

  28. 28.

    To illustrate, consider a cartel that increases profits by $10 billion and has a probability of being successfully caught and convicted of 50%. In this case, the expected gain from forming a cartel is $10 billion minus 0.5 · f, where f is the amount of the fine. For the fine to successfully deter a cartel, the expected gain must be negative. For this to be true, f must exceed $20 billion.

References

  • Bush D, et al. (2004) How to block cartel formation and price-fixing. AEI-Brookings Joint Center for Regulatory Studies, April 2004

    Google Scholar 

  • Chen J, Liu Q (2011) The effect of most-favored customer clauses on prices. J Ind Econ 59(3):343–371

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Connor JM (2003) Private international cartels: effectiveness, welfare, and anticartel enforcement. Working paper, Social Science Research Network, 2003, http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=611909

  • Connor JM, Lande RH (2005) How high do cartels raise prices? Implications for optimal cartel fines. Tulane Law Rev 80(513):1–55

    Google Scholar 

  • Connor JM, Lande RH (2006) The great global vitamins conspiracy: sanctions and deterrence. Working paper, Purdue University, February 24, 2006

    Google Scholar 

  • Cournot A (1838) Researches into the mathematical principles of the theory of wealth. L. Hachette, Paris

    Google Scholar 

  • El-Tablawy T (2008) OPEC divisions again on display heading to Algeria. AP Worldstream, December 14, 2008

    Google Scholar 

  • Europa (2001) Commission imposes fines on vitamin cartels. Press Release, November 21, 2001. Europa is the official website of the European Union, available at http://europa.eu.

  • Federal News Service (1999) Press Conference with Attorney General Janet Reno and Joel Klein, Assistant Attorney General, Antitrust Division May 20, 1999

    Google Scholar 

  • Fraas AG, Greer DF (1977) Market structure and price collusion: an empirical analysis. J Ind Econ 26(1):21–44

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Friedman JW (1971) A noncooperative equilibrium for supergames. Rev Econ Stud 28(1):1–12

    Google Scholar 

  • Green EJ, Porter RH (1984) Noncooperative collusion under imperfect price information. Econometrica 52(1):87–100

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Griffin JM (1989) Previous cartel experience: any lessons for OPEC? In: Klein LR, Marquez J (eds) Economics in theory and practice: an eclectic approach. Kluwer Academic, Dordrecht, pp 179–206

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Hammond SD (2005) Criminal enforcement program. Department of Justice, November 16, 2005, at http://www.justice.gov/atr

  • Hammond SD (2010) The evolution of criminal antitrust enforcement over the last two decades. Department of Justice, February 25, 2010, at http://www.justice.gov/atr/public/speeches/255515.htm

  • Hasker K, Sickles RC (2010) eBay in economic literature: analysis of an auction marketplace. Rev Ind Organ 37(1):3–42

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hay GA, Kelley D (1974) An empirical survey of price fixing conspiracies. J Law Econ 17(13):13–38

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jahn G (2009) OPEC oil keeps output steady. AP Worldstream, May 28, 2009

    Google Scholar 

  • Kwoka JE Jr (1997) The price effect of bidding conspiracies: evidence from real estate knockouts. Antitrust Bull 42(503):503–516

    Google Scholar 

  • Levenstein MC, Suslow VY (2004) Contemporary international cartels and developing countries: economic effects and implications for competition policy. Antitrust Law J 71(3):801–852

    Google Scholar 

  • Levenstein MC, Suslow VY (2006) What determines Cartel success? J Econ Lit 44:43–95

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Martin S (2005) Petroleum. In: Adams W, Brock JW (eds) The structure of American industry. Person Prentice Hall, Upper Saddle River, NJ

    Google Scholar 

  • Mufson S (2007) Uncertainty hovers over OPEC summit: Cartel contends with politics, prices and its future. The Washington Post, November 16, 2007

    Google Scholar 

  • New York Times (1983) Blunt talk on the phone. February 23, 1983, Section D, p. 4

    Google Scholar 

  • Pate RH (2004) International anti-cartel enforcement. Antitrust Division of the U.S. Department of Justice, November 21, 2004

    Google Scholar 

  • Perry W (2007) OPEC struggles to maintain control. Middle East Economic Digest, November 23, 2007

    Google Scholar 

  • Pindyck RS, Rubenfield DL (2009) Microeconomics. Pearson Prentice Hall, Upper Saddle River, NJ

    Google Scholar 

  • Rotemberg JJ, Saloner G (1986) A supergame-theoretic model of price wars during booms. Am Econ Rev 76(3):390–407

    Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson RJ (2008) OPEC’s triumph: acting like a true cartel – with America’s help. The Washington Post, March 12, 2008

    Google Scholar 

  • Scherer FM (1996) Industry structure, strategy, and public policy. Harper Collins College Publishers, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Scherer FM, Ross D (1990) Industrial market structure and economic performance. Houghton Mifflin Co., Boston

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith A (1776) An inquiry into the nature and causes of the wealth of nations

    Google Scholar 

  • Stigler GJ (1964) A theory of oligopoly. J Polit Econ 72(1):44

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • U.S. Department of Justice (2008) LG, Sharp, Chunghwa agree to plead guilty, pay total of $585 million in fines for participating in LCD price-fixing conspiracies. November 12, 2008, www.usdoj.gov

  • U.S. Department of Justice (2009) Taiwan LCD producer agrees to plead guilty and pay $220 million fine for participating in LCD price-fixing conspiracy. December 9, 2009, www.usdoj.gov

  • Varian HR (2010) Intermediate microeconomics: a modern approach. W.W. Norton, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Waldman DE, Jensen EJ (2006) Industrial organization: theory and practice. Person Addison-Wesley, Boston

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2012 Springer Science+Business Media, LLC

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Tremblay, V.J., Tremblay, C.H. (2012). Cartels. In: New Perspectives on Industrial Organization. Springer Texts in Business and Economics. Springer, New York, NY. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-1-4614-3241-8_9

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics