Skip to main content

Risk-Hedging Strategies and Portfolio Management

  • Chapter
Book cover Econometric Analysis of Carbon Markets
  • 1872 Accesses

Abstract

This chapter considers first the risk factors impacting jointly the Clean Development Mechanism and the European Union Emissions Trading Scheme. Second, it provides an econometric modelling exercise of risk premia in CO2 allowance spot and futures prices under the EU ETS (based on Bessembinder and Lemmon, J. Finance 57:1347–1382, 2002), which takes into account the specificities of carbon allowances in terms of storage. Third, carbon price risks in the power sector are identified econometrically by analyzing the factors that influence fuel-switching. Fourth, a stylized portfolio management exercise is proposed by using mean-variance optimization in a broadly diversified portfolio composed of stocks, bonds, weather, energy and carbon assets. The Appendix details how to compute implied volatility series from options, which can then be used to represent the risk-neutral probability distribution of carbon prices.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 39.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 54.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 54.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    Note CERs traded on exchanges are precisely guaranteed secondary CERs (sCERs), but for simplicity we use the common denomination term of CERs throughout this chapter.

  2. 2.

    See http://www.cdmpipeline.org.

  3. 3.

    See Chap. 1 for the detailed calendar.

  4. 4.

    CDM credits can be issued by destroying HFC-23 (trifluoromethane), which is 11,700 times more potent as a greenhouse gas than CO2. It can be removed by installing gas scrubbers for instance.

  5. 5.

    Recall that each ton of HFC abated delivers 11,700 CERs.

  6. 6.

    The N2O global warming potential is 310 times higher than CO2.

  7. 7.

    For a more detailed time-series modeling of the convenience yield (especially by using intraday data) in the carbon market, see the analysis by Chevallier (2009, [17]).

  8. 8.

    According to the cost-of-carry relationship, and without storage costs for carbon allowances, the futures and spot prices are linked through S t =F T e r(Tt) with S t the spot price at time t, F T the futures prices of a contract with delivery in T, and r the interest rate [12, 43].

  9. 9.

    Note that a cointegration exercise between CO2 allowances spot and futures prices, in the spirit of the exercises studied in Chap. 4, can be found in Chevallier (2010, [19]).

  10. 10.

    The interested reader may refer to Chap. 2 for a full description of the fuel-switching mechanism in the power sector, in presence of carbon costs.

  11. 11.

    The data used for this section is not available for download.

  12. 12.

    1 therm=0.10550559 GJ.

  13. 13.

    The coal calorific value is equal to 24.9 MJ/kg.

  14. 14.

    Now, it is called the UK Department for Business, Innovation and Skills.

  15. 15.

    Note that we not include in the analysis the capital and operations and maintenance costs of coal vs. natural gas which may result in the unusually low spreads noted in Fig. 5.8. Hence we aim at capturing the short-term effect of introducing emissions trading on power producers’ fuel-switching behaviour (see Delarue et al. (2010, [24])). A longer term analysis of fuel substitution with additional costs associated with a retro-fit is not possible in this setting.

  16. 16.

    See Chap. 2 for structural break tests.

  17. 17.

    Note that the negative sign found in subsample #1 for the coefficient of the carbon price may be explained by confusing price signals sent to power producers during 2005–2007, as the carbon spot price geared towards zero due to the presence of banking restrictions between 2007 and 2008 (Alberola and Chevallier (2009, [1])).

  18. 18.

    Demand is negatively linked with Combined Cycle Gas Turbines (CCGT), and positively with coal. This is consistent with the fact that increasing demand would yield to a decrease in the number of gas-fired plants and in the fuel-switching opportunity. If the carbon price increases, the use of CCGT is encouraged and the use of coal is lower. The decrease in the use of coal is met partly with the use of gas, but it also encourages the use of other low-carbon technologies (such as nuclear or renewable energy).

  19. 19.

    This data is not reproduced for this chapter.

  20. 20.

    See https://www.rmetrics.org/.

  21. 21.

    At the market equilibrium, demand equals supply and the tangent portfolio coincides with the market portfolio.

References

  1. Alberola E, Chevallier J (2009) European carbon prices and banking restrictions: evidence from Phase I (2005–2007). Energy J 30:51–80

    Google Scholar 

  2. Alberola E, Chevallier J, Cheze B (2008) Price drivers and structural breaks in European carbon prices 2005-07. Energy Policy 36:787–797

    Article  Google Scholar 

  3. Alberola E, Chevallier J, Cheze B (2008) The EU emissions trading scheme: the effects of industrial production and CO2 emissions on European carbon prices. Int Econ 116:93–125

    Google Scholar 

  4. Alberola E, Chevallier J, Cheze B (2009) Emissions compliances and carbon prices under the EU ETS: a country specific analysis of industrial sectors. J Policy Model 31:446–462

    Article  Google Scholar 

  5. Barone-Adesi G, Engle RF, Mancini L (2008) A GARCH option pricing model with filtered historical simulation. Rev Financ Stud 21:1223–1258

    Article  Google Scholar 

  6. Berk J, DeMarzo P (2008) Corporate finance. Pearson International Edition, New York

    Google Scholar 

  7. Bessembinder H Lemmon ML (2002) Equilibrium pricing and optimal hedging in electricity forward markets. J Finance 57:1347–1382

    Article  Google Scholar 

  8. Blyth W, Bunn D, Kettunen J, Wilson T (2009) Policy interactions, risk and price formation in carbon markets. Energy Policy 37:5192–5207

    Article  Google Scholar 

  9. Blyth W, Bunn D (2011) Coevolution of policy, market and technical price risks in the EU ETS. Energy Policy 39:4578–4593

    Article  Google Scholar 

  10. Bodie Z, Kane A, Marcus AJ (2008) Investments, 7th edn. McGraw Hill, New York

    Google Scholar 

  11. Breeden DT (1980) Consumption risks in futures markets. J Finance 35:503–520

    Article  Google Scholar 

  12. Brennan M (1958) The supply of storage. Am Econ Rev 48:50–72

    Google Scholar 

  13. Broadie M, Chernov M, Johannes M (2007) Model specification and risk premia: evidence from futures options. J Finance 62:1453–1490

    Article  Google Scholar 

  14. Chen Y, Sijm J, Hobbs BF, Lise W (2008) Implications of CO2 emissions trading for short-run electricity market outcomes in northwest Europe. J Regul Econ 34:251–281

    Article  Google Scholar 

  15. Chevallier J (2009) Energy risk management with carbon assets. Int J Glob Energy Issues 32:328–349

    Article  Google Scholar 

  16. Chevallier J (2009) Carbon futures and macroeconomic risk factors: a view from the EU ETS. Energy Econ 31:614–625

    Article  Google Scholar 

  17. Chevallier J (2009) Modelling the convenience yield in carbon prices using daily and realized measures. Int Rev Appl Financ Issues Econ 1:56–73

    Google Scholar 

  18. Chevallier J (2010) Modelling risk premia in CO2 allowances spot and futures prices. Econ Model 27:717–729

    Article  Google Scholar 

  19. Chevallier J (2010) A note on cointegrating and vector autoregressive relationships between CO2 allowances spot and futures prices. Econ Bull 30:1564–1584

    Google Scholar 

  20. Chevallier J, Ielpo F, Mercier L (2009) Risk aversion and institutional information disclosure on the European carbon market: a case-study of the 2006 compliance event. Energy Policy 37:15–28

    Article  Google Scholar 

  21. Cootner PH (1960) Returns to speculators: Telser vs Keynes. J Polit Econ 68:396–404

    Article  Google Scholar 

  22. Delarue E, D’haeseleer WD (2007) Price determination of ETS allowances through the switching level of coal and gas in the power sector. Int J Energy Res 31:1001–1013

    Article  Google Scholar 

  23. Delarue E, Voorspools KR, D’haeseleer WD (2008) Fuel switching in the electricity sector under the EU ETS: review and prospective. J Sol Energy Eng 134:40–58

    Article  Google Scholar 

  24. Delarue E, Ellerman AD, D’haeseleer WD (2010) Short-term CO2 abatement in the European power sector: 2005–2006. Clim Change Econ 1:113–133

    Article  Google Scholar 

  25. Dusak K (1973) Futures trading and investor returns: an investigation of commodity market risk premiums. J Polit Econ 81:1387–1406

    Article  Google Scholar 

  26. Ellerman AD, Feilhauer S (2008) A top-down and bottom-up look at emissions abatement in Germany in response to the EU ETS. Working paper 2008-17, Centre for Energy and Environmental Policy Research, MIT, USA

    Google Scholar 

  27. Engle RF, Bollerslev T (1986) Modelling the persistence of conditional variances. Econom Rev 5:1–50

    Article  Google Scholar 

  28. Kaldor N (1939) Speculation and economic stability. Rev Econ Stud 7:1–27

    Article  Google Scholar 

  29. Kanen JLM (2006) Carbon trading and pricing. Environmental Finance Publications, London

    Google Scholar 

  30. Kwiatkowski DP, Phillips PCB, Schmidt P, Shin Y (1992) Testing the null hypothesis of stationarity against the alternative of the unit root: how sure are we that economic time series are non stationary? J Econom 54:159–178

    Article  Google Scholar 

  31. Lise W, Sijm J, Hobbs BF (2010) The impact of the EU ETS on prices, profits and emissions in the power sector: simulation results with the COMPETES EU20 model. Environ Resour Econ 47:23–44

    Article  Google Scholar 

  32. Longstaff FA, Wang A (2004) Electricity forward prices: a high-frequency empirical analysis. J Finance 59:1877–1900

    Article  Google Scholar 

  33. Markowitz H (1959) Portfolio selection: efficient diversification of investments. Wiley, New York

    Google Scholar 

  34. MacKinnon JG (1996) Numerical distribution functions for unit root and cointegration tests. J Appl Econom 11:601–618

    Article  Google Scholar 

  35. McGuinness M, Ellerman AD (2008) CO2 abatement in the UK power sector: evidence from the EU ETS trial period. Working paper 2008-04, Centre for Energy and Environmental Policy Research, MIT, USA

    Google Scholar 

  36. Nelson DB (1991) Conditional heteroskedasticity in asset returns: a new approach. Econometrica 59:347–370

    Article  Google Scholar 

  37. Pindyck R (2001) The dynamics of commodity spot and futures markets: a primer. Energy J 22:1–29

    Google Scholar 

  38. Sharpe WF (1964) Capital asset prices: a theory of market equilibrium under conditions of risk. J Finance 19:425–442

    Google Scholar 

  39. Sharpe WF (1966) Mutual fund performance. J Business 39:119–138

    Article  Google Scholar 

  40. Sijm JPM, Bakker SJA, Chen Y, Harmsen HW, Lise W (2006) CO2 price dynamics: a follow-up analysis of the implications of EU emissions trading for the price of electricity. Working paper 06-015, Energy Research Centre for the Netherlands, the Netherlands

    Google Scholar 

  41. Sijm JPM, Hers SJ, Lise W, Wetzelaer BJHW (2008) The impact of the EU ETS on electricity prices. Working paper 08-007, Energy Research Centre for the Netherlands, the Netherlands

    Google Scholar 

  42. Voorspools KR, D’haeseleer WD (2006) Modelling of electricity generation of large interconnected power systems: how can a CO2 tax influence the European generation mix. Energy Convers Manag 47:1338–1358

    Article  Google Scholar 

  43. Working H (1949) The theory of the price of storage. Am Econ Rev 39:1254–1262

    Google Scholar 

  44. Würtz D, Chalabi Y, Chen W, Ellis A (2009) Portfolio optimization with R/Rmetrics. Rmetrics Publishing, Zurich

    Google Scholar 

  45. Zakoian JM (1994) Threshold heteroskedastic models. J Econ Dyn Control 18:931–955

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Julien Chevallier .

Appendix: Computing Implied Volatility from Option Prices

Appendix: Computing Implied Volatility from Option Prices

In the financial economics literature, risk-hedging strategies may also be designed by resorting to option prices (see [20] for an application to EUAs by using a dataset of plain vanilla European option prices at-the-money). We briefly recall here how to derive implied volatility measures from option pricing.

Let C(τ,K) obs be the observed call option price, and C(τ,K,σ) BS the Black-Scholes (BS) price computed using the implied volatility σ. By definition, we have C(τ,K) obs =C(τ,K,σ) BS . The implied volatility of the strike price is obtained by numerically inverting the BS formula, which can be done by solving:

$$ \min_{\sigma} \bigl(C(\tau,K)_{obs} - C(\tau,K,\sigma)_{BS} \bigr)^2$$
(5.13)

Reference [20] shows that option prices on the carbon market lead to pricing errors that are usual for commodity or equity markets (see also [5]). Implied volatility series can then be used to represent the risk-neutral probability distribution of a given asset in financial economics.

5.1.1 Problems

Problem 5.1

(Calibrating GARCH Models for Carbon Prices)

  1. (a)

    Consider the descriptive statistics for the CO2 price series in Table 5.9: how well do they seem to fit the GARCH(p,q) models specifications?

    Table 5.9 Descriptive statistics for CO2 prices
  2. (b)

    Following the Box-Jenkins methodology, we configure the ARMA(p,q) processes that provide the best fit to the CO2 time-series. Then, we estimate the corresponding GARCH(p,q) model for the CO2 price series:

    $${{Y}_{t}}=\theta {{{X}'}_{t}}+{{\varepsilon }_{t}}$$
    (5.14)
    $$\sigma _{t}^{2}=\omega +\sum\limits_{i=1}^{p}{{{\alpha }_{i}}\varepsilon _{t-i}^{2}}+\sum\limits_{j=1}^{q}{{{\beta }_{j}}\sigma _{t-j}^{2}}$$
    (5.15)

    with \(\sigma_{t}^{2}\) the conditional variance, which is function of a constant term ω, the ARCH term \(\varepsilon^{2}_{t-i}\), and the GARCH term \(\sigma^{2}_{t-j}\).

    In Table 5.10, comment on:

    • the statistical significance of the parameters obtained in the mean and variance equations;

    • the value of the Ljung-Box test;

    • the value of the ARCH test.

    Table 5.10 GARCH estimates for CO2 prices

    In Fig. 5.10, comment on:

    • the plot of the standardized innovations of the GARCH(p,q) model;

    • the plot of the conditional standard deviations of the GARCH(p,q) model.

    Fig. 5.10
    figure 10

    Standardized innovations (left panel) and conditional standard deviations (right panel) of the GARCH(p,q) model

  3. (c)

    We consider other models than the standard GARCH(p,q) model with a Gaussian conditional probability distribution. First, we use the specification for the conditional variance proposed by Nelson (1991, [36]):

    $$\log(\sigma_t^2)=\omega+\sum_{i=1}^p \alpha_i \left|\frac{\varepsilon _{t-i}}{\sigma_{t-i}}\right|+\sum_{j=1}^q \beta_j \log (\sigma_{t-j}^2)+ \sum_{k=1}^r \gamma_k \frac{\varepsilon_{t-k}}{\sigma_{t-k}} $$
    (5.16)

    where γ tests for the presence of the leverage effect. Recall that the leverage effect implies a higher level of volatility associated to decreasing prices in the financial economics literature. The EGARCH model is estimated with a Student t distribution.

    Second, we use the asymmetric TGARCH model by Zakoian (1994, [45]):

    $$\sigma_t^{2}=\omega+ \sum_{i=1}^p \alpha_i \varepsilon_{t-i}^2+ \sum _{j=1}^q \beta_j \sigma_{t-j}^2 + \sum_{k=1}^r \gamma_k \varepsilon _{t-k}^2 \varGamma_{t-k} $$
    (5.17)

    where Γ t =1 if ε t <0, and 0 otherwise. ε ti >0 and ε ti <0 denote, respectively, good and bad news. The TGARCH model is estimated with a Generalized Error Distribution (GED).

    Consider the Tables 5.11 and 5.12: do you observe any improvement with the alternative specification structures in the variance equation?

    Table 5.11 EGARCH estimates for CO2 prices
    Table 5.12 TGARCH estimates for CO2 prices

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2012 Springer Science+Business Media B.V.

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Chevallier, J. (2012). Risk-Hedging Strategies and Portfolio Management. In: Econometric Analysis of Carbon Markets. Springer, Dordrecht. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-94-007-2412-9_5

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics