Skip to main content

Studying Electoral Engineering via a Double-Barrelled Natural Experiment: Comparing the Long Run Consequences of 1990s Electoral Reform in Italy and Japan

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Italy and Japan: How Similar Are They?

Part of the book series: Perspectives in Business Culture ((PEPIBC))

  • 1055 Accesses

Abstract

Drawing on a comparison of the origins and effects of the electoral reforms in Italy and Japan in the early 1990s that led to the implementation of a mixed election system in both countries, we look at the extent to which changes in electoral systems are mere paper tigers in terms of having important impacts on party systems and ways of doing political business.

This chapter contains generous borrowings of ideas from the contributions in Daniela Giannetti and Bernard Grofman (eds.) 2011, A Natural Experiment on Electoral Law Reform: Evaluating the Long Run Consequences of 1990s Electoral Reform in Italy and Japan. New York: Springer. The listing of authors is alphabetical.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 84.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    See the Appendix in Giannetti and Grofman (2011) for a brief description of the 1993 and 2006 electoral law changes in Italy.

  2. 2.

    Earlier work along these lines, sponsored by the Center for the Study of Democracy at the University of California, Irvine, and involving different teams of scholars, compares SNTV systems in Japan, Korea and Taiwan (Grofman et al. 1999), STV systems in Australia, Ireland and Malta (Bowler and Grofman 2000), mixed systems in a variety of countries (Shugart and Wattenberg 2001a), list PR systems in the Nordic nations (Grofman and Lijphart 2002), single member district plurality systems in Canada, India, the UK and the U.S. (Grofman et al. 2008a), and runoff methods (Grofman 2008b).

  3. 3.

    Wuffle (personal communication, 2001), in comments at a panel on Japanese elections at the 2001 American Political Science Association, likened a mixed member system to a train with engines at both ends, both in operation simultaneously. At the session s/he quipped: “Without more information as to which engine was the more powerful, it is hard to know in which direction the train is going”.

  4. 4.

    In the view of the public and the media after the first elections [under the 1994 electoral rules], this ability to ‘rise from the dead’—to win a PR seat even after constituents in the SMD rejected the candidate in favor someone else—made the legislator what was called a ‘zombie’ Diet member.” Though this term dropped out of common usage, the fact that an SMD candidate could do so badly in the SMD to lose her deposit and yet win a PR seat remained embarrassing. The law was revised to eliminate this possibility after the 2000 election.

  5. 5.

    Another important detail is whether or not voters have one ballot to cast that determines both the SMD outcome and that candidate’s party or coalition share of the PR tally, or have separate ballots for the SMD and PR components of the mixed system (as in Germany), but that distinction is relevant only for true MMP systems, and so is not relevant here. In MMM systems, voters normally are given two separate ballots, and this is true for both Japan and Italy. A much more extensive inventory of different features of mixed member systems and useful ways of classifying those differences is found in Shugart and Wattenberg (2001b).

  6. 6.

    For example, in systems where there are separate presidential elections, the nature of the linkage between presidential and legislative elections can significantly affect the number of political parties (Cox 1997, p. 219; Mozaffar and Vengroff 2002).

  7. 7.

    For example, parties that do not well nationally may survive because of local pockets of strength that give then power in local or regional elections.

  8. 8.

    Parties that wish to increase their PR vote may for purposes of visibility and greater support in the PR component, run candidates in SMD constituencies that they have no hope of capturing, thus increasing ENP in such constituencies; while the perceived need to have sufficiently concentrated political support to win a plurality in at least some SMD constituencies will discourage some parties from forming, thus decreasing ENP in the PR component of the mixed system. Moreover, strategic calculations are not just at the level of parties: voters who see a party as not viable at the SMD level may be less willing to support that party at the PR level since they may, for strategic reasons, have deserted that party at the SMD level and given their SMD support to a candidate of another party—at least in systems where voters have a separate ballot for the PR and the SMD components of the mixed system.

  9. 9.

    For a much more comprehensive examination of the question of the degree to which changes in Japanese and Italian politics were anticipated by those who made/advocated/opposed the early 1990s reforms in those countries see Scheiner and Tronconi (2011).

  10. 10.

    The 1994 election in Italy exhibited the greatest change in party vote and seat shares from the precious election ever recorded in (modern) Italy, far higher than what is the norm in most Western democracies.

  11. 11.

    For example, the continuity between the mixed system put in place in Italy in 1993 and the PR system with bonus for the largest party that replaced it in 2005 seems quite high.

  12. 12.

    See also Scheiner (2008).

References

  • Bawn K (1993) The logic of institutional preferences—German electoral law as a social choice outcome. Am J Polit Sci 37(4):965–989

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carlson MM (2006) Electoral reform and the costs of personal support in Japan. J East Asian Stud 6(2):233–258

    Google Scholar 

  • Bowler S, Grofman B (2000) Introduction: STV as an embedded system. In: Bowler S, Grofman B (eds) Elections in Australia, Ireland and Malta under the single transferable vote: reflections on an embedded system. University of Michigan Press, Ann Arbor, pp 1–14

    Google Scholar 

  • Chiaramonte A (2002) Il voto proporzionale: verso la nazionalizzazione della competizione?. In: R. D’Alimonte, S. Bartolini. Maggioritario finalmente? La transizione elettorale 1994–2001. P 165–198, Il Mulino, Bologna

    Google Scholar 

  • Christensen R (1998) Putting new wine in old bottles: the effect of electoral reform on campaigning in Japan. Asian Surv 3:986–1004

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cox KE, Schoppa LJ (2002) Interaction effects in mixed-member electoral systems: theory and evidence from Germany, Japan and Italy. Comp Polit Stud 35(9):1027–1053

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • D’Alimonte R (2005) Italy: a case of fragmented bipolarism. In: Gallagher M, Mitchell P (eds) The politics of electoral systems. Oxford University Press, Oxford, pp 253–276

    Google Scholar 

  • Di Virgilio A (2006) Dal cambiamento dei partiti all’evoluzione del sistema partitico. In: L. Morlino and M. Tarchi (eds.), Partiti e caso italiano, Bologna, il Mulino, pp 173–206

    Google Scholar 

  • Di Virgilio A, Kato J (2011) Party competition under new electoral rules in Italy and Japan, 1994–2009. In: Giannetti D, Grofman B (eds) A natural experiment on electoral law reform. Springer, New York, pp 13–34

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Di Virgilio A, Reed SR (2011) Nominating candidates under new rules in Italy and Japan: you cannot bargain with resources you do not have. In: Giannetti D, Grofman B (eds) A natural experiment on electoral law reform: evaluating the long run consequences of 1990s electoral reform in Italy and Japan. Springer, New York, pp 61–76

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Donovan M (1995) The politics of electoral reform in Italy. Int Polit Sci Rev 16:47–64

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Downs A (1957) An economic theory of democracy. Harper and Row, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Duverger M (1955) Political parties: their organization and activity in the modern state. Wiley, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Ferrara F (2004) Electoral coordination and the strategic desertion of strong parties in compensatory mixed systems with negative vote transfers. Electoral Stud 23(3):391–413

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Giannetti D, Laver M (2001) Party system dynamics and the making and breaking of Italian governments. Electoral Stud 20:529–553

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Giannetti D, Grofman B (eds) (2011) A natural experiment on Electoral Law reform: evaluating the long run consequences of 1990s electoral reform in Italy and Japan. Springer, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Giannetti D, Thies M (2011) Factional politics in Italy and Japan. In: Giannetti D, Grofman B (eds) A natural experiment on Electoral Law reform: evaluating the long run consequences of 1990s electoral reform in Italy and Japan. Springer, New York, pp 77–96

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Grofman B (1999) Preface: methodological steps toward the study of embedded institutions. In: Grofman B, Sung-Chull L, Winckler E, Woodall B (eds) Elections in Japan, Korea and Taiwan under the single non-transferable vote: the comparative study of an embedded institution. University of Michigan Press, Ann Arbor, pp ix–xvii

    Google Scholar 

  • Grofman B, Chiaramonte A, D’Alimonte R, Feld SL (2004) Comparing and contrasting the uses of two graphical tools for displaying patterns of multi-party competition: Nagayama diagrams and simplex representations. Party Polit 10(3):273–299

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grofman B, Lijphart A (2002) Electoral Laws and their political consequences. Agathon Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Grofman B, Sung-Chull L, Winckler E, Woodall B (eds) (1999) Elections in Japan, Korea and Taiwan under the single non-transferable vote: the comparative study of an embedded institution. University of Michigan Press, Ann Arbor

    Google Scholar 

  • Grofman B,  Blais A, Bowler S (2008a) The Duverger Law of plurality voting. Springer, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Grofman B (2008b) A taxonomy of runoff  methods. Electoral Stud 27(3):395–399

    Google Scholar 

  • Herron ES, Nishikawa M (2001) Contamination effects and the number of parties in mixed- superposition electoral systems. Electoral Stud 20:63–86

    Google Scholar 

  • Katz R (1995) The 1993 Parliamentary Electoral reform. In: Mershon C, Pasquino G (eds) Italian politics: ending the first republic. Westview, Boulder, CO

    Google Scholar 

  • Krauss ES, Pekkanen RJ (2011) The rise and fall of Japan’s LDP: political party organizations as historical institutions. Cornell University Press, Ithaca

    Google Scholar 

  • Lijphart (1999) Patterns of democracy. Yale University Press, New Haven

    Google Scholar 

  • Moser R, Scheiner E (2004) Mixed electoral systems and electoral system effects: controlled comparison and cross-national analysis. Electoral Stud 23(4):575–599

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Otake H (ed) (1998) How electoral reform boomeranged. Continuity in Japanese campaigning style. Japan Center for International Exchange, Tokyo

    Google Scholar 

  • Pierson P (2004) Politics in time, history, institutions, and social analysis. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Google Scholar 

  • Reed SR (2001) Duverger’s Law is working in Italy. Comp Polit Stud 34(3):312–327

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Reed SR (2005) Japan: haltingly toward a two-party system. In: Gallagher M, Mitchell P (eds) The politics of electoral systems. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Reed SR et al (eds) (2012) Japan decides 2012: the Japanese general election. Palgrave Macmillan, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Reed SR, Thies MF (2001) The causes of electoral reform in Japan. In: Shugart MS, Wattemberg MP (eds) Mixed-member electoral systems: the best of both worlds. Oxford University Press, New York, pp 152–172

    Google Scholar 

  • Renwick A, Hanretty C, Hine D (2009) Partisan self-interest and electoral reform: the new Italian Electoral Law of 2005. Electoral Stud 28(3):437–447

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mozaffar S, Vengroff R (2002) A ‘whole system’ approach to the choice of electoral rules in democratizing countries: senegal in comparative perspective. Electoral Stud 21(4):601–616

    Google Scholar 

  • Riker WH (1982) The two-party system and Duverger’s Law: an essay on the history of political science. Am Polit Sci Rev 76:753–766

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Scheiner E (2006) Democracy without competition in Japan: opposition failure in a one-party  dominant State. Cambridge University Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Scheiner (2008)  Does electoral system reform work? electoral system lessons from reforms of the 1990s. Am Polit Sci Rev 11:161–81

    Google Scholar 

  • Scheiner E, Tronconi F (2011) Electoral reform in Italy and Japan: unanticipated outcomes? In: Giannetti D, Grofman B (eds) A natural experiment on Electoral Law reform: evaluating the long run consequences of 1990s electoral reform in Italy and Japan. Springer, New York, pp 97–114

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Scheiner E  (2007) Clientelism in Japan: the importance and limits of Institutional Explanations. In: Herbert K, Steven IW (eds) Patrons, clients, and policies: patterns of democratic accountability and political competition. Cambridge University Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Shugart MS, Wattenberg MP (eds) (2001a) Mixed-member electoral systems: the best of both worlds? Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Shugart MS, Wattenberg MP (2001b) Mixed member electoral systems: a definition and typology. In: Shugart MS, Wattenberg MP (eds) Mixed member electoral systems: the best of both worlds?. Oxford University Press, New York, pp 9–51

    Google Scholar 

  • Tarrow S (2010) The strategy of paired comparison: toward a theory of practice. Comp Polit Stud 43(2):230–259

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Taagepera R (1999) Ignorance-based quantitative models and their practical implications. J Theor Polit 11(3):421–431

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Taagepera R (2005) Conservation of balance in the size of parties. Party Polit 11(3):283–298

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Taagepera R (2009) Predicting party sizes: the 2007 Johan Skytte prize lecture. Scand Polit Stud 32(2):240–246

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Taagepera R, Shugart MS (1989) Seats and votes. Yale University Press, New Haven

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Daniela Giannetti .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Appendix

Appendix

This brief overview of the basic features of electoral law changes in Italy and Japan over the past two decades is taken from Giannetti and Grofman (2011).

Electoral Reform in Italy, 1993

The 1993 reform replaced Italy’s previous PR system (with preferential voting) with a mixed system. For electing the lower Chamber (630 members) Italy was divided into 26 multi-member constituencies (plus the small region of Valle D’Aosta which always has only one seat). In turn, each constituency was divided into a number of single member districts approximately equal to 75 % of the seat assigned to them. The remaining 25 % of the seats were allocated on the basis of party lists and by PR using the LR-Hare formula.

Candidates could run in both tiers. All SMD candidates had to be endorsed by one or more PR list. The reverse was not true, as PR lists did not need to endorse SMD candidates. Voters can cast two ballots: the first for a candidate in their district, the second for a list in their constituency. No preferential voting was allowed in the PR tier. The allocation of PR seats was a two stage process, as it took place first at the national level. In order to get seats, parties had to receive at least 4 % of the national vote. Subsequently, seats were allocated to each party in the different constituencies. The plurality and PR tiers were linked in several ways. The most important of them was a mechanism of negative vote transfers (scorporo). With this vote re-apportioning mechanism for each plurality seat won a party saw its PR total vote at the constituency level reduced by the number of votes (plus one) received by the second placed candidate in the single member district where the party had won a seat. Only after the scorporo had been implemented were votes allocated into seats.

For electing the Senate, Italy was divided into 20 regional constituencies, two of which had no PR seats (Valle D’Aosta and Molise). Unlike the Chamber, the only candidates were those running in the 232 SMDs. Voters cast only one vote for an SMD candidate, and the eighty-three PR seats were assigned by means of a repêchage mechanism on a regional basis. Each party’s share of the list seats in a regional constituency was allocated to the ‘best losers’ among its SMD candidates. The PR seats were assigned at the constituency level using the d’Hondt formula. While there was no legal threshold for participating in the distribution of PR seats, the d’Hondt formula combined with the small district magnitude of most constituencies made it hard for small or medium-sized parties or coalitions to gain PR seats. The scorporo re-allocation rule also operated in Senate elections, where it was used through subtracting from a group’s total vote all the votes received by those candidates affiliated to the group who had won SMD seats in a constituency. Thus there was a greater correction compared to the Chamber of the disproportionality associated with the plurality formula.

The main differences among the rules for electing members to the Chamber and Senate had to do with to the ballot structure, the allocation of PR seats, and the mechanism of negative vote transfer.

Electoral Reform in Italy, 2005

The 2005 electoral reform abolished SMDs by introducing closed list PR for the entire parliament, but now with a seat bonus. For electing the Chamber, Italy is divided into 26 multimember constituencies encompassing the whole national territory. A number of seats proportional to the population are assigned to each constituency, yielding a total of 617 seats (one additional seat in the small Valle d’Aosta regional constituency is allocated by plurality and the remaining 12 seats are allocated by PR in the newly established Overseas Constituencies). To obtain seats, the following thresholds must be passed on a national basis:

  • minimum 4 % for a party list;

  • minimum 10 % for a coalition;

  • minimum 2 % for a party joining a coalition that passes the 10 % threshold. However, the best loser is also assigned seats.

Coalitions are formed by party lists that registered a common electoral platform and indicated a coalition leader (Article 14 of the Electoral Law). In short, to gain seats parties have to pass a lower threshold if they join pre-electoral coalitions.

The mechanism for seat allocation works as follows. First, the total vote share of coalitions and independent party lists are calculated at the national level and seats are allocated proportionally to them. If a coalition or a party list obtains 340 or more seats, no seat bonus will be given. If a coalition or party list obtains a plurality, but has less than 340 seats, it will be assigned additional seats to reach this number, corresponding roughly to a 54 % majority. The remaining 277 seats are allocated proportionally to other coalitions and party lists.

After the number of seats due to a coalition has been established, seats are allocated proportionally among coalition partners. Only party lists that obtained at least 2 % of the votes are assigned seats (seats are also assigned to the “best loser”). Candidates are elected according to the order they appear on party lists (no preference voting is allowed).

In short, the mechanism described above checks first if a coalition or a party list has obtained an absolute majority of about 54 %. If this is not the case, a seat bonus is allocated to generate such a majority.

The electoral system for the Senate works in a similar way in all of the seventeen regional constituencies (in three regions different systems are used). The procedure is like the one for electing the Chamber, with important differences. Seats are allocated proportionally to coalitions and party lists that pass the relevant vote thresholds. These thresholds are (a) 20 % for coalitions (b) 3 % for parties joining a coalition whose total vote share is at least 20 %, and (c) an 8 % threshold, if a party decides to run independently or joins a coalition that does not pass the 20 % threshold. The main difference between electing the Chamber and the Senate is that seats for electing the Senate are allocated to coalitions and party lists at the regional level, and the seat bonus is attributed on a regional basis. The most important consequence of this provision is that there is no guarantee for a coalition or party list obtaining the largest number of votes at the national level to obtain an absolute majority of the seats in the Senate.

Electoral Reform in Japan, 1994

The Japanese Diet has two chambers, the House of Representatives (the Lower House) elected for a four year term, and the House of Councillors (the Upper House) made of 232 members elected for a six year term with elections for half of the Councillors held every three years. The electoral law changes in 1994 applied only to the House of Representatives, replacing the Single Non-Transferable Vote (SNTV) system formerly in use (in primarily 3 seat constituencies) in that body.

The electoral system approved in 1994 changed the rules for electing members of the House of Representatives. It combined 300 seats from an equivalent number of Single Member Districts (SMDs) and 200 seats elected by PR from party lists in eleven regional multimember constituencies (this provision was modified in 2000, by reducing the number of PR seats from 200 to 180). Constituency magnitude varies from seven to thirty-three seats. Voters cast two votes: a candidate vote in an SMD, and a vote for a party that registers a list of candidates in the region. The allocation of plurality and PR seats proceeds independently: each party receives its ‘proportional’ share in each list-tier district, plus as many SMDs seats as it wins outright. For allocating PR seats the D’Hondt formula is used.

The only connection between the two tiers is double candidacy. That is, a candidate may run simultaneously in an SMD and on a party list provided that the SMD is within the PR constituency. A candidate who fails to win in the SMDs might still earn a seat if ranked high enough on the PR list. This opens up various strategic possibilities for candidates and parties (Reed and Thies 2001; Di Virgilio and Reed 2011). For example parties can nominate several double candidates as the same rank of the PR list, where the tie is broken by a ‘best loser’ calculation, i.e. awarding PR seats to those candidates who come closest to winning their SMDs. All dual candidates who share the same list position and who lose in their SMDs are re-ranked on the party list according to the ratio of their plurality vote total to their SMDs winner’s vote total. A candidate’s chances of being saved in the list tier, is therefore a direct function of how close the candidate came to winning the SMD outright.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2014 Springer-Verlag Italia

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Giannetti, D., Grofman, B., Reed, S.R. (2014). Studying Electoral Engineering via a Double-Barrelled Natural Experiment: Comparing the Long Run Consequences of 1990s Electoral Reform in Italy and Japan. In: Beretta, S., Berkofsky, A., Rugge, F. (eds) Italy and Japan: How Similar Are They?. Perspectives in Business Culture. Springer, Milano. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-88-470-2568-4_10

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics