Skip to main content

Health, Lifestyle and Growth

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Book cover Social Exclusion

Part of the book series: AIEL Series in Labour Economics ((AIEL))

Abstract

In this article, I attempt to explain why lifestyle may have a positive impact on economic growth. First, I consider the ways in which health affects a consumer’s utility, and I then define a Health Production Function for which health is the output and consumer good is the input. In this approach, the Lifestyle Return to Scale (LRS) parameter is defined. The first result is that an increase in a consumer’s personal income may have a positive or a negative effect on health. That is, health may be a normal or an inferior good, depending on the Lifestyle Return to Scale value. According to this result, I compute a health multiplier and then modify the Solow Growth Model in which health is labour-augmenting. The result is a model in which the Lifestyle Return to Scale positively affects per capita income and per capita income growth.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 84.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    Financial Times Cash incentives seen as helping nation’s health, 11 April 2009.

  2. 2.

    The ancient Romans said “In Medio stat Virtus”. In the model that hypothesis doesn’t matter for each single good.

  3. 3.

    See for example Berger and Leigh (1989) and Kenkel (1991) for the relationship between schooling and health. See also Avitabile (2009) for the relationship between health and information.

  4. 4.

    This approach may be considered as a generalization of Wagstaff’s model (1986). See Appendix for details.

  5. 5.

    Three issues should be highlighted here. First, in this simple consumer model, choices are made between two commodities. In reality, a commodity may be not consumed for three reasons, the first two of which were outlined previously: (1) the consumer does not like a commodity; (2) even if a commodity is liked, the health damage caused by the commodity may be greater than the commodity’s utility, preventing consumption of the commodity; and (3) the relative price of a commodity may be greater than income, preventing consumption of the commodity. In the first two cases, the commodity is not consumed as a result of free choice. In the second case, this choice may be difficult. In the third case, price and income limits restrict access to the commodity. In this article, we consider only the case in which individuals consume both commodities.

References

  • Aristotle (2009) Nicomachean Ethics (trans: Ross WD). World Library Classical Books

    Google Scholar 

  • Avitabile C (2009) Does conditionality matter for adults’ health? Evidence from a randomized experiment. CSEF Working Paper 222

    Google Scholar 

  • Berger MC, Leigh JP (1989) Schooling, self-selection, and health. J Human Res 24(3):433–455 (Summer, 1989)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brillat Savarin JA (2004) The phisiology of taste. Kessinger Publishing, US

    Google Scholar 

  • Contoyannis P, Jones AM (2004) Socio-economic status, health and lifestyle. J Health Econ 23:965–995

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gravelle H, Rees R (1992) Microeconomics, 2nd edn. Longman Group UK Limited, England

    Google Scholar 

  • Grossman M (1972) On the concept of health capital and the demand for health. J Political Econ 80(2):223–255

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heshmati A (2001) On the causality between GDP and health care expenditure in augmented Solow growth model. SEE/EFI Working paper series in Economics and Finance 423

    Google Scholar 

  • Kenkel D (1991) Health behaviour, health knowledge and schooling. J Political Econ 99:287–305

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kip Viscussi W, Evans WN (1990) Utility function that depend on health status. Am Econ Rev 80(3):353–374

    Google Scholar 

  • Lòpez-Casasnovas et al (2005) Health and economic growth: findings and policy implications In: López-Casasnovas G, Rivera B, Currais L (eds) Cambridge MIT press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Maddison A (2003) The world economy: historical Statistics. Paris Development Centre of the Organisation for Economic Co operation and Development, Paris

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Mankiw NG, Romer D, Weil N (1992) Contribution to the empirics of economic growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics 107:407–437

    Google Scholar 

  • Marshall A (2006) Principles of Economics Cosmio Inc. original published (1890) by Prometheus Book

    Google Scholar 

  • Mas-Colell A, Whinston M, Green J (1995) Microeconomic theory. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Mill JS (1859) On liberty. Republished by Agora Publication inc (2003)

    Google Scholar 

  • Morand OF (2005) Economic growth, health, and longevity in the very long term: facts and mechanisms. In: López-Casasnovas G, Rivera B, Currais L (eds) Health and economic growth: findings and policy implications. Cambridge MIT press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Riley JC (2005) Estimates of regional and global life expectancy 1800–2001. Population Dev Rev 31(3):537–543

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rivera B, Currais L (1999a) Economic growth and health: direct impact or reverse causation? Appl Econ Lett 6(11):761–764

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rivera B, Currais L (1999b) Income variation and health expenditure: evidence for OECD countries. Rev Dev Econ 3(3):258–267

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sala-i-Martin X (2005) On the health–poverty trap. In: López-Casasnovas G, Rivera B, Currais L (eds) Health and economic growth: findings and policy implications. Cambridge MIT press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Sassi F, Hurst J (2008) The prevention of lifestyle related chronic diseases: an economic framework. OECD Publishing 32

    Google Scholar 

  • Solow R (1956) A contribution to the theory of economic growth. Q J Econ 70:65–94 (February)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Strauss J (1986) Does better nutrition raise farm productivity? J Political Econ 94(2):297–320

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Streeten P (1994) Human development: mean and ends. Am Econ Rev 84(2), In: Papers and Proceedings of the 106th annual meeting of the American Economic Association, May 1994, pp 232–237

    Google Scholar 

  • UNDP (2010) Human development report. Second printing Palgrave Macmillian, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Varian H (1992) Microeconomic analysis, 3rd edn. Norton, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Wagstaff A (1986) The demand for health: a simplified Grossman model. Bull Econ Res 38:1

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weil DN (2004) Economic growth. Addison-Wesley, Reading

    Google Scholar 

  • Weil DN (2005) Accounting for the effect of health on economic growth. NBER Working Paper w1145

    Google Scholar 

  • Zargosky J (2005) Health and wealth: the late-20th century obesity epidemic in the US. Econ Human Biol 3(2):296–313

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

I would like to thank seminar participants at the University of Salerno and the University of Pescara. I am grateful for many helpful comments, received during the course of those presentations. Thanks also to Adalgiso Amendola, Alberto Bennardo, Dimitrios Christelis, Floro Ernesto Caroleo, Marcello D’Amato, Sergio Destefanis, Fernanda Mazzotta, Niall O’Higghins, Carmen Pagliari and Giuliana Parodi for their very useful suggestions. The usual disclaimer applies.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Appendix

Appendix

1.1 A Generalization of Wagstaff’s Model

Starting with Michael Grossman’s Model (1972) and Wagstaff (1986) developed a one-period model of demand for health. The four hypotheses of the model include the following: (1) an individual’s health is determined by the consumption of health inputs \( h\left( x \right) = x^{\rho } ; \) (2) preferences are non-lexicographic: individuals desire health but not above everything else; (3) individuals also consume other commodities that have a positive cost for consumers, so \( U = u\left( {h,z} \right) \) with \( \frac{dU}{dh},\frac{dU}{dz} > 0 \) and \( \frac{{d^{2} U\left( {h,z} \right)}}{dh},\frac{{d^{2} U\left( {h,z} \right)}}{dz} < 0; \) and (4) consumers have limited economic resources or budget constraints: \( p_{x} x + p_{z} z = Y, \) where \( p_{x} \) and \( p_{z} \) are the prices of commodities x and z, respectively, and Y is the income.

Assuming a Cobb Douglas Utility function and a Health production function \( h\left( x \right) = x^{\rho } , \) the Wagstaff Model can be formulated with the following formulas:

$$ U\left( {h,z} \right) = h^{\alpha } z^{\delta } $$
(2.32)
$$ h\left( x \right) = x^{\rho } $$
(2.33)
$$ p_{x} x + p_{z} z = Y $$
(2.34)

where \( 0 < \alpha < 1 \) and \( 0 < \delta < 1 \) are the utility elasticities with respect to x and z, respectively, and \( 0 < \rho < 1 \) is the elasticity of h with respect to x.

This is a special case of the Consumer’s model (Sect. 2) with \( \beta = 0. \) The commodity x is not in the Consumer’s utility function with \( \left( {\gamma = 0} \right); \) thus, z does not affect health.

The solutions can be obtained from two different methods. The first was proposed by Wagstaff:

$$ \mathop {\max }\limits_{h,z} U\left( {h,z} \right) = h^{\alpha } z^{\delta } \,{\text{s}} . {\text{t}} .\,p_{x} h^{ - \rho } + p_{z} z = Y $$
(2.35)

In this case the Budget Constraint is not linear. The consumer chooses between health and z. The second possible solution is

$$ \mathop {\max }\limits_{x,z} U\left( {x,z} \right) = x^{\rho \alpha } z^{\delta } \,{\text{s}} . {\text{t}} .\,p_{x} x + p_{z} z = Y $$
(2.36)

The consumer chooses the quantities of x and z that maximize utility.

Both methods yield the same solutions:

$$ x = \frac{\alpha \rho }{\delta + \alpha \rho }\frac{Y}{{p_{x} }} $$
(2.37)
$$ z = \frac{\delta }{\delta + \alpha \rho }\frac{Y}{{p_{z} }} $$
(2.38)
$$ h = \left( {\frac{\alpha \rho }{\delta + \alpha \rho }\frac{Y}{{p_{x} }}} \right)^{\rho } $$
(2.39)

The main differences include the following: (1) in the Wagstaff model, Health can only be a normal good because \( \frac{dh}{dy} > 0 \) (conversely, in the model proposed in this paper, Health may also be an inferior good), and (2) this result depends on the lifestyle of the consumer.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2012 Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Coppola, G. (2012). Health, Lifestyle and Growth. In: Parodi, G., Sciulli, D. (eds) Social Exclusion. AIEL Series in Labour Economics. Physica, Heidelberg. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-7908-2772-9_2

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics