Skip to main content

Globalization and Economic Geography

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Book cover International Trade Theory and Policy

Part of the book series: Springer Texts in Business and Economics ((STBE))

  • 109k Accesses

Abstract

Globalization is a much used and abused words. After clarifying its meaning, the present chapter examines the relations between location of production, cost of transport, and international trade in the context of both the traditional and the new theories of international trade. Particular attention is given to the core-periphery model, but other models are also examined, such as housing congestion, input-output linkages, footlose capital, etc.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 79.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 99.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 129.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    We use the terminology adopted in the early new economic geography literature. Clearly though, “region” should be understood as a geographical unit (region, country, or else) and “farmers” and “workers” as a geographically immobile and mobile factor, respectively.

  2. 2.

    See Ricci (1999) for an interesting extension where the marginal labor input, c, differs between countries.

  3. 3.

    See Sect. 23.2.1 for a formal derivation of demand functions from S-D-S preferences.

  4. 4.

    This migration mechanism implies that migration decisions are taken by comparing current real wage differentials and neglecting the future evolution of real wages. For extensions of the core-periphery model that explicitly take account of expectations on future real wage differentials see Krugman (1991b), Baldwin (2001), and Ottaviano (19992001).

  5. 5.

    More complex functional forms may be used for Eq. (16.6) but this simple form suffices for our expositional purposes. Note also that it suffices to write only one law of motion since \(\lambda _{2} = 1 -\lambda _{1}\) at any time.

  6. 6.

    The model determines the two values of τ that divide the set (0, 1) into the three segments corresponding to ‘high’, ‘intermediate’ and ‘low’ trade costs. See Baldwin, Forslid, Martin, Ottaviano, and Robert-Nicoud (2003) for an exhaustive treatment of this matter.

  7. 7.

    This is typical of many new economic geography models. See Ottaviano (2001) and Forslid and Ottaviano (2003) for explicitly solvable models. The appendix to this chapter provides an elementary guide to numerical solutions and calibrations.

  8. 8.

    We are informally using a topological method for stability analysis. For a formal treatment of such a method see Gandolfo (2009, chap. 21, sect. 21.3.1).

  9. 9.

    Since housing services are part of total consumption the cost of housing is part of the total cost of living. To keep terminology close to the literature, however, we continue to refer to the cost of living linkage as to the linkage driven by the price index of manufactures, P i . We refer instead to the cost of housing linkage as to the linkage driven by the price of housing, P i H.

  10. 10.

    See Alonso-Villar (2005) for an extension to this model where there are input-output linkages between two manufacturing industries and trade costs differ between industries.

  11. 11.

    See Nocco (2005) for an extension of this model where there are endogenous differences in technology levels due to interregional knowledge spillovers.

  12. 12.

    Capital exists in a fixed stock and cannot be accumulated. The number of varieties is constant too. See, e.g. Martin and Ottaviano (19992001) and Baldwin, Martin, and Ottaviano (2001) for interesting developments which link the new economic geography to endogenous growth theory.

  13. 13.

    The condition for both countries being producers of A in any geographic configuration is that industry M is small enough to fit in one country.

  14. 14.

    Perfect competition in the labor market makes it impossible for w to rise.

  15. 15.

    To solve the model note that aggregate operating profit in the world economy is N π o where the subscript i is suppressed since π 1 o = π 2 o. By virtue expression (16.14), N π o is equal to the fraction \((\mu -1)/\mu\) of world sales. World sales are equal to world expenditure which in turn is equal to world income. Furthermore, \(N = \overline{K}\). Therefore we have the equation \(\overline{K}\pi = \frac{\mu -1} {\mu } \gamma \left (L + \overline{K}\pi \right )\). From this equation we obtain π  ∗  and all the other endogenous variables.

References

  • Alonso-Villar, O. (2005). The effects of transport costs revisited.

    Google Scholar 

  • Andersson, F., & Forslid, R. (2003). Tax competition and economic geography.

    Google Scholar 

  • Annicchiarico, B., Orioli, F., & Trionfetti, F. (2012). National oligopoly and economic geography.

    Google Scholar 

  • Baldwin, Richard E. (2001). The core-periphery model with forward-looking expectations.

    Google Scholar 

  • Baldwin, Richard E., Forslid, R., Martin, P., Ottaviano, G. I. P., & Robert-Nicoud, F. (2003). Economic geography and public policy.

    Google Scholar 

  • Baldwin, Richard E., & Krugman, P. R. (2004). Agglomeration, integration and tax harmonisation.

    Google Scholar 

  • Baldwin, Richard E., Martin, P., & Ottaviano, G. I. P. (2001). Global economic divergence, trade and industrialisation: The geography of growth takeoffs.

    Google Scholar 

  • Beckmann, M. J. (1987). Location of economic activity.

    Google Scholar 

  • Behrens, K., & Robert-Nicoud, F. (2010). Tempora mutantur: In search of a new testament for neg.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brülhart, M., Carrère, C., & Trionfetti, F. (2012). How wages and employment adjust to improved market access: Evidence from Austria.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brülhart, M., & Jametti, M. (2008). Does tax competition tame the leviathan?

    Google Scholar 

  • Brülhart, M., Jametti, M., & Schmidheiny, K. (2012). Do agglomeration economies reduce the sensitivity of firm location to tax differentials?

    Google Scholar 

  • Brülhart, M., & Parchet, R. (2011). Alleged tax competition: The mysterious death of inheritance taxes in Switzerland.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brülhart, M., & Trionfetti, F. (2004). Public expenditure, international specialisation and agglomeration.

    Google Scholar 

  • Charlot, S., Gaigne, C., Robert-Nicoud, F., & Thisse, J.-F. (2006). Agglomeration and welfare: The core-periphery model in the light of bentham, kaldor, and rawls.

    Google Scholar 

  • Combes, P.-P. (1997). Industrial agglomeration under cournot competition.

    Google Scholar 

  • Combes, P.-P., & Lafourcade, M. (2011). Competition, market access and economic geography: Structural estimations and predictions for France.

    Google Scholar 

  • Crozet, M. (2004). Do migrants follow market potentials? An estimation of a new economic geography model.

    Google Scholar 

  • Davis, D. R., & Weinstein, D. E. (2002). Bones, bombs, and break points: The geography of economic activity.

    Google Scholar 

  • Davis, D. R., & Weinstein, D. E. (2008). A search for multiple equilibria in urban industrial structure.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dreher, A. (2006). Does globalization affect growth? Evidence from a new index of globalization.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dreher, A., Gaston, N., & Martens, P. (2008). Measuring globalization – gauging its consequences.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ellison, G., & Glaeser, E. L. (1997). Geographic concentration in U.S. manufacturing industries: A dartboard approach.

    Google Scholar 

  • Findlay, R. (1995). Factor proportions, trade, and growth (chap. 6).

    Google Scholar 

  • Forslid, R., & Ottaviano, G. I. P. (2003). An analytically solvable core-periphery model.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gabaix, X. (1999). Zipf’s law for cities: An explanation.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gandolfo, G. (2009). Economic dynamics.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gupta, S. D. (Ed.). (1997). The political economy of globalization.

    Google Scholar 

  • Helpman, E. (1998). The size of regions.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kind, H. J., Midelfart-Knarvik, K. H., & Schjelderup, G. (2000). Competing for capital in a ‘Lumpy’ world.

    Google Scholar 

  • Krugman, P. R. (1991a).  Geography and trade.

    Google Scholar 

  • Krugman, P. R. (1991b). History versus expectations.

    Google Scholar 

  • Krugman, P. R. (1991c). Increasing returns and economic geography.

    Google Scholar 

  • Krugman, P. R. (1993a). On the relationship between trade theory and location theory.

    Google Scholar 

  • Krugman, P. R., & Venables, A. J. (1995). Globalization and the inequality of nations.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lösch, A. (1954). Economics of location (English translation of 1940 German original).

    Google Scholar 

  • Ludema, R. D., & Wooton, I. (2000). Economic geography and the fiscal effects of regional integration.

    Google Scholar 

  • Martin, J. P., & Rogers, C. A. (1995). Industrial location and public infrastructure.

    Google Scholar 

  • Martin, P., & Ottaviano, G. I. P. (1999). Growing locations: Industry location in a model of endogenous growth.

    Google Scholar 

  • Martin, P., & Ottaviano, G. I. P. (2001). Growth and agglomeration.

    Google Scholar 

  • Neary, J. P. (2001). Of hype and hyperbolas: Introducing the new economic geography.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nocco, A. (2005). The rise and fall of regional inequalities with technological differences and knowledge spillovers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ohlin, B. (1933). Interregional and international trade.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ohlin, B., Hesselborn, P., & Wijkman, P. M. (Eds.). (1977). The international allocation of economic activity.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ottaviano, G. I. P. (1999). Integration, geography, and the burden of history.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ottaviano, G. I. P. (2001). Monopolistic competition, trade, and endogenous spatial fluctuations.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ottaviano, G. I. P., & Robert-Nicoud, F. L. (2006). The ‘Genome’ of NEG models with vertical linkages: A positive and normative synthesis.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ottaviano, G. I. P., Tabuchi, T., & Thisse, J.-F. (2002). Agglomeration and trade revisited.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ottaviano, G. I. P., & van Ypersele, T. (2005) Market size and tax competition.

    Google Scholar 

  • Puga, D. (1999). The rise and fall of regional inequalities.

    Google Scholar 

  • Redding, S. J. (2010). The empirics of new economic geography.

    Google Scholar 

  • Redding, S. J., & Sturm, D. (2008). The costs of remoteness: Evidence from German division and reunification.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ricci, L. A. (1999). Economic geography and comparative advantage: Agglomeration versus specialization.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stern, R. M. (2009). Globalization and international trade policies, (chap. 2, sect. II).

    Google Scholar 

  • Trionfetti, F. (2001). Public procurement, economic integration, and income inequality.

    Google Scholar 

  • Trionfetti, F. (2012). Public debt and economic geography.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2014 Springer-Verlag Berlin · Heidelberg

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Gandolfo, G. (2014). Globalization and Economic Geography. In: International Trade Theory and Policy. Springer Texts in Business and Economics. Springer, Berlin, Heidelberg. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-642-37314-5_16

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-642-37314-5_16

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Springer, Berlin, Heidelberg

  • Print ISBN: 978-3-642-37313-8

  • Online ISBN: 978-3-642-37314-5

  • eBook Packages: Business and EconomicsEconomics and Finance (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics