Skip to main content

Export Decisions of Services Firms Between Agglomeration Effects and Market-Entry Costs

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
  • 1284 Accesses

Part of the book series: Advances in Spatial Science ((ADVSPATIAL))

Abstract

This chapter tests the role of agglomeration effects on the export decision of services firms. Recent theories on trade with heterogeneous firms predict that export to foreign markets goes along with sunk market-entry costs. Only the more productive firms will be able to absorb such sunk costs, so that ex ante self selection on the basis of productivity may be expected. Recent research by spatial economist suggests however that productivity sorting may also be the result of operating in large-city areas. In this chapter I find strong evidence that the productivity differences between exporting and non-exporting services firms depend on both agglomeration effects and on anticipated market-entry costs in foreign markets. The research is based on a large set of micro-data for Dutch services establishments. Productivity sorting is strongest for markets with heterogeneous services. Productivity self-selection is found to be strongest for services exporters in rural areas and small agglomerations. This is consistent with the finding that urban services firms on average already have a higher productivity.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution.

Buying options

Chapter
USD   29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD   84.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD   109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD   109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Learn about institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    Comprehensive surveys of the results have been provided by Wagner (2007, 2012), Greenaway and Kneller (2007), Mayer and Ottaviano (2007), and ISGEP (2008).

  2. 2.

    Allowing only the most productive ones to survive and thus generating higher average productivity compared to rural areas (like in Melitz & Ottaviano, 2008).

  3. 3.

    Examples of such costs are language barriers, complying with foreign regulations, adapting the product to the foreign market, the fixed costs of reaching foreign customers. Early trade models with sunk costs are Dixit (1989), Baldwin (1988) and Baldwin and Krugman (1989).

  4. 4.

    See Redding (2010) for a review. Prominent theoretical papers are Yeaple (2007), Eaton, Kortum, and Kramarz (2011), Melitz and Ottaviano (2008), and Chaney (2008).

  5. 5.

    Although productivity premiums will be shown as a form of robustness test.

  6. 6.

    Moretti (2004) focuses on the education-level of the employees in the region, whereas Henderson (2003) focuses on the number of other firms in the same industry in the region as a source of spill-over effects.

  7. 7.

    The sampling data are provided in the form of an expansion factor that says for each sampled establishment how much other establishments it represents in its stratum. This expansion factor is used as a weight in regressions.

  8. 8.

    The problem of a long under-represented tail has been reduced by adopting a cut-off size of at least ten employed workers for services establishments. Export participation and association with multinational firm are less important for these small establishments. Data entries holding imputations by Statistics Netherlands were removed from our sample, keeping only questionnaire-based establishment data.

  9. 9.

    The agglomeration density variable measures the average number of addresses per square kilometre within a circle of a 1-km ray, measured at the beginning of each year. The five urbanisation classes are: (1) very strong urbanisation (≥2,500 addresses per km2); (2) strong urbanisation (1,500–2,500 addresses per km2); (3) moderate urbanisation (1,000–1,500 addresses per km2); (4) weak urbanisation (500–1,000 addresses per km2); (5) non-urban area (<500 addresses per km2). In the regressions I have taken the log of the urbanisation-class indicator.

  10. 10.

    The size classes are based on the number of employed persons and cover the following intervals: (1) 10–19 employed persons; (2) 20–39 employed persons; (3) 40–59 employed persons; (4) 60–80 employed persons; (5) 80–124 employed persons; (6) 125–249 employed persons; (7) 250–499 employed persons; (8) 500–999 employed persons; (9) 1,000–1,999 employed persons; (10) >2,000 employed persons. This size class definition is consistently applied in the remainder of the paper.

  11. 11.

    The data do not allow a reliable identification of establishments that are associated with foreign multinational firms.

  12. 12.

    The distinction between rural and non-rural areas is made on the basis of the rural area dummy. The “rural area dummy” has been set to 1 if the number of addresses per postal code amounted to <1,501 per km2, and zero otherwise.

  13. 13.

    Given that for this regression international transaction data were not available, the following assumptions are imposed to test the predictions of the heterogeneous-firms trade model: (a) establishments in each sector (4-digit) have the same information about market size, variable and sunk trade barriers, covering all relevant countries; (b) establishments share a common country set as potential export markets and (giving assumption a) have an identical ranking within their set of preferred export countries; (c) establishments in a (4-digit) sector enter potential export countries according to an identical country sequence based on market size, distance and sunk market-entry costs. In other research (Smeets, Creusen, Lejour, & Kox, 2010) we have estimated the country-specific sunk market entry costs for Dutch manufacturing firms.

  14. 14.

    The threshold value can be set at zero without loss of generality.

  15. 15.

    Usually this means that its variance is fixed at a given value (Verbeek 2004). Since \( \mathrm{ F}(\beta \mathrm{ x}\_ \mathrm{ it}\ ) \) is also bounded between 0 and 1, it is plausible to choose a standard normal distribution \( \varphi (\beta \mathrm{ x}\_ \mathrm{ it}). \) There is no reason to expect that the standard normal distribution does not apply.

  16. 16.

    Impact elasticities instead of marginal effects are presented, because the intuitive interpretation of elasticities is easier. I evaluated point elasticities at the mean and at the median values of ln \( \beta \mathrm{ x}\_ \mathrm{ it} \). Since differences between both were very small, I only report point elasticities at the mean.

  17. 17.

    The size class is measured on a 10-point Likert scale {1, … ,10} that increases in employment size. We took the median size category for the firm over the full observation period. The result is expressed as a natural logarithm.

  18. 18.

    The population size and the agglomeration density scale are expressed in logs.

  19. 19.

    Andersson and Lööf (2009) conclude that firms located in larger regions are more productive, even when controlling for size, human capital, physical capital, ownership structure, import and export, industry classification and time trend. Second, they find that results from dynamic panel estimations suggest a learning effect in that agglomeration enhances firms’ productivity. Third, the role of agglomeration phenomena does not seem to have a clear coupling to firm size.

  20. 20.

    The caveat raised at the end of Sect. 2 about the unreliability of summary statistics for measuring self selection (in the presence of agglomeration factors) remains valid.

  21. 21.

    Cf. Békés and Muraközy (2008) for Hungary. Besedes and Prusa (2006) established for the USA that trade relationships typically start small and that almost half of the “small relationships” end within a year, while larger initial purchases result in longer, stable relationships. From this they advance a matching model of international trade in which uncertainty and the costs of searching reliable trade partners play important roles. The search cost idea can be reconciled with the Melitz model, because search costs are in fact country-specific sunk entry costs. Albornoz, Calvo Pardo, Corcos, and Ornelas (2009) go one step further in evaluating the role of uncertainty and learning. In their view a strategy of sequential exporting to different country markets is a rational firm strategy to discover their own competitive advantage.

  22. 22.

    The mechanism is taken from Jovanovic (1982) and Hopenhayn (1992).

  23. 23.

    Think of taxes that are linked to urban land and property prices, such taxes embody the agglomeration mark-up linked with being in an attractive business and living agglomeration.

References

  • Albornoz, F., Calvo Pardo, H., Corcos, G., & Ornelas, E. (2009, September). Sequential exporting. Paper presented at European Trade Study Group (Rome, 2009), University of Birmingham University of Southampton, NHH Oslo and London School of Economics.

    Google Scholar 

  • Andersson, M., & Lööf, H. (2009). Agglomeration and Productivity- evidence from firm-level data (CESIS Electronic Working Paper Series No. 170). Centre of Excellence for Science and Innovation Studies, Royal Institute of Technology, Stockholm.

    Google Scholar 

  • Baldwin, R., (1988). Hysteresis in import prices: the beachhead effect. American Economic Review, 78(4), 773–785.

    Google Scholar 

  • Baldwin, R., (2005). Heterogeneous firms and trade: Testable and untestable properties of the Melitz model (Working Paper 11471). Cambridge, MA: NBER.

    Google Scholar 

  • Baldwin, R., & Krugman, P. (1989). Persistent trade effects of large exchange rate shocks. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 104, 635–654.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baldwin, R., & Okubo, T. (2006). Heterogeneous firms, agglomeration and economic geography: Spatial selection and sorting. Journal of Economic Geography, 6(3), 323–346.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Balistreri, E., Hillberry, R., &, Rutherford, T. (2008). Structural estimation and solution of international trade models with heterogeneous firms (Research Paper #1056). University Of Melbourne, Department Of Economics, Melbourne.

    Google Scholar 

  • Békés, G., &, Muraközy, B. (2008, May). Permanent and temporary trade. Paper presented at the CAED conference (Budapest, 2008), Hungarian Academy of Sciences, Budapest.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bernard, A., Eaton, J., Jensen, J., & Kortum, S. (2003). Plants and productivity in international trade. American Economic Review, 93, 1268–1290.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bernard, A., & Jensen, J. (1995). Exporters, jobs, and wages in U.S. Manufacturing, 1976–1987. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Microeconomics, Washington, DC.

    Google Scholar 

  • Besedes, T., & Prusa, T. (2006). Ins, outs, and the duration of trade. Canadian Journal of Economics, 39(1), 266–295.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chaney, T. (2008). Distorted gravity: The intensive and extensive margins of international trade. American Economic Review, 98(4), 1707–1721.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ciccone, A. (2002). Agglomeration effects in Europe. European Economic Review, 46, 213–227.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ciccone, A., & Hall, R. (1996). Productivity and the density of economic activity. American Economic Review, 86(1), 54–70.

    Google Scholar 

  • Combes, P., Duranton, G., Gobillon, L., Puga, G., & Roux, S. (2008). The productivity advantages of large markets: Distinguishing agglomeration from firm selection. Mimeo: University of Aix-Marseille.

    Google Scholar 

  • Combes, P., Duranton, G., Gobillon, L., Puga, G., & Roux, S. (2012). The productivity advantages of large markets: Distinguishing agglomeration from firm selection. Econometrica, 80(6), 2543–2594.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dixit, A. (1989). Entry and exit decisions under uncertainty. Journal of Political Economy, 97, 620–638.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Duranton, G., & Puga, D. (2004). Micro-foundations of urban agglomeration economies. In V. Henderson & J. F. Thisse (Eds.), Handbook of regional and urban economics (Vol. 4, pp. 2063–2117). Amsterdam: North-Holland.

    Google Scholar 

  • Eaton, J., Kortum, S., & Kramarz, F. (2011). An anatomy of international trade: Evidence from French firms. Econometrica, 79(5), 1453–1498.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fujita, M., & Thisse, J.-F. (2002). Economics of agglomeration: Cities, industrial location and regional growth. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Greenaway, D., & Kneller, R. (2007). Firm heterogeneity, exporting and foreign direct investment. The Economic Journal, 117, F134–F161.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Helpman, E., Melitz, M., & Yeaple, S. (2004). Export versus FDI with heterogeneous firms. American Economic Review, 94(1), 300–316.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Henderson, V. (2003). Marshall’s scale economies. Journal of Urban Economics, 53, 1–28.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hopenhayn, H. (1992). Entry, exit and firm dynamics in long-run equilibrium. Econometrica, 60, 1127–1150.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • ISGEP. (2008). Understanding cross-country differences in exporter premia: Comparable evidence for 14 countries, International Study Group on Exports and Productivity. Review of World Economics, 144(4), 596–635.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jovanovic, B. (1982). Selection and the evolution of industry. Econometrica, 50, 649–670.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kox, H. (2002). Growth challenges for the Dutch business services industry: International comparison and policy issues (CPB Special Publication #40). CPB/Koninklijke De Swart, The Hague.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kox, H., & Rojas-Romagosa, H. (2010). Exports and productivity selection effects for Dutch firms. De Economist (Springer), 158(3), 295–322.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krugman, P. (1991). Increasing returns and economic geography. Journal of Political Economy, 99(3), 483–499.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krugman, P & Venables, T. (1995). Globalization and the Inequality of Nations. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 110, 857–880.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lawless, M., (2009). Deconstructing gravity: Trade costs and extensive and intensive margins. Paper submitted to EIIE/FREIT, Central Bank and Financial Services Authority of Ireland, Dublin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mayer, T., & Ottaviano, G. (2007). The happy few: The internationalisation of European firms. Bruegel, Brussels: Bruegel Blueprint III.

    Google Scholar 

  • Melitz, M. (2003). The impact of trade on aggregate industry productivity and intra-industry reallocations. Econometrica, 71(6), 1695–1725.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Melitz, M., & Ottaviano, G. (2008). Market size, trade and productivity. Review of Economic Studies, 75(1), 295–316.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Melo, P., Graham, D., & Noland, R. (2009). A meta-analysis of estimates of the urban agglomeration economies. Regional Science and Urban Economics, 39(3), 332–342.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Moretti, E. (2004). Workers’ education spillovers, and productivity: Evidence from plant-level production functions. American Economic Review, 94, 656–690.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ottaviano, G., Tabuchi, T., & Thisse, J.-F. (2002). Agglomeration and trade revisited. International Economic Review, 43(2), 409–435.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Redding, S. (2010). Theories of heterogeneous firms and trade (NBER Working Paper #16562). Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economics Research.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rosenthal, S., & Strange, W. (2004). Evidence on the nature and sources of agglomeration economies. In Handbook of regional and urban economics (Vol. 4, pp. 2119–2171). Amsterdam: North-Holland.

    Google Scholar 

  • Smeets, R., Creusen, H., Lejour, A., & Kox, H. (2010). Export margins and export barriers: Covering market entry costs of exporters in the Netherlands (CPB Document 208). CPB, The Hague.

    Google Scholar 

  • Syverson, C. (2004). Market structure and productivity: A concrete example. Journal of Political Economy, 112(6), 1181–1222.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Verbeek, M., (2004). A guide to modern econometrics, 2nd edition, John Wiley & Sons, Oxford.

    Google Scholar 

  • Vogel, A., & Wagner, J. (2011). Robust estimates of exporter productivity premia in German business services enterprises. Economic and Business Review, 13(1–2), 7–26.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wagner, J. (2007). Exports and productivity: A survey of the evidence from firm level data. The World Economy, 30(10), 60–82.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wagner, J. (2012). International trade and firm performance: A survey of empirical studies since 2006. Review of World Economics, 148, 235–267.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yeaple, S. (2007). A simple model of firm heterogeneity, international trade, and wages. Journal of International Economics, 65, 1–20.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Henk L. M. Kox .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2013 Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Kox, H.L.M. (2013). Export Decisions of Services Firms Between Agglomeration Effects and Market-Entry Costs. In: Cuadrado-Roura, J. (eds) Service Industries and Regions. Advances in Spatial Science. Springer, Berlin, Heidelberg. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-642-35801-2_8

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-642-35801-2_8

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Springer, Berlin, Heidelberg

  • Print ISBN: 978-3-642-35800-5

  • Online ISBN: 978-3-642-35801-2

  • eBook Packages: Business and EconomicsEconomics and Finance (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics