Skip to main content

The State Intervention and the Public Organization of Tourism

  • Chapter
  • First Online:

Part of the book series: Springer Texts in Business and Economics ((STBE))

Abstract

When speaking of tourism, there exist positive and normative motivations (see Sect. 2.7) for analyzing those institutions that govern and organize the economic relationships between tourism operators in the market. An institution can be defined as any organization accepted by the members of the society and with the power of regulating the behavior of individuals and to make decisions which consequences fall on the entire community. In fact, as a general rule of the economy, and this is particularly true for the tourism sector, many economic problems can be mainly settled through the intervention of an external authority, either being a voluntary organization (such an association of firms) or a public institution (such a public body), which sets the rules and enables to make them obligatory.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution.

Buying options

Chapter
USD   29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD   89.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD   119.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD   109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Learn about institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    If the game is repeated with an infinite horizon, the Folk Theorem states that the cooperative solution may be obtained without public intervention, only through individual strategies.

  2. 2.

    Pareto optimality, also called Pareto efficiency, is a situation in which it is not possible to increase the well-being of an individual without decreasing the well-being of someone else.

  3. 3.

    Since the manufacturing sector produces income and employment, the socially optimal solution would not be the one in which industrial production is set to zero, as Fig. 15.1 clearly shows.

  4. 4.

    The socioeconomic impact of tourism and the factors affecting residents’ attitude towards tourism have received some attention in recent years (Akis et al. 1996; Alberini et al. 2005; Crotts and Holland 1993; Faulkner and Tideswell 1997; Figini et al. 2009; Haralambopoulos and Pizam 1996; Lindberg and Johnson 1997a, b; Lindberg et al. 1999; Concu and Atzeni 2012). In particular, the impact of tourism is often disaggregated into three categories: economic, sociocultural, and environmental effects (Ryan 1991; Williams 1979). Since tourism generally disrupts social, cultural, and environmental local systems, the non-economic impact often tends to be negative as a whole (Liu et al. 1987), while economic effects are perceived as positive.

  5. 5.

    Also public bads have an optimal size, which is generally different from zero: think that the absence of pollution, for example, is absence of life.

  6. 6.

    In the most general case, it is possible to demonstrate that the distribution of the tax between the tourists and the firms depends on the elasticity of demand and the elasticity of supply of the tourism service (Mak and Nishimura 1979).

  7. 7.

    Symmetrically, most of these arguments can be used to justify the use of subsidies to promote arrivals at the destination (see the important example of Ryanair, Papatheodorou and Lei 2006) or to contrast crisis management (Faulkner 2001; Blake and Sinclair 2003, for the 9/11 terrorist attack; Pambudi et al. 2009, for the Bali bombings).

  8. 8.

    National organizations, with ad hoc advertising campaigns targeted to selected markets, are able to promote incoming tourism (with the positive macroeconomic effects spreading on the entire economy, Chap. 13) and, indirectly, tourism in the individual destinations.

References

  • Akis, S., Peristianis, N., & Warner, J. (1996). Residents’ attitudes to tourism development: the case of Cyprus. Tourism Management, 17, 481–494.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alberini, A., Rosato, P., & Zanatta, V. (2005). Combining actual and contingent behaviour to estimate the value of sport fishing in the lagoon of Venice. Ecological Economics, 61, 530–541.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Archer, B. H. (1977). Tourism in the Bahamas and Bermuda: two case studies. Occasional Papers in Economics. UK: University of Wales.

    Google Scholar 

  • Blake, A. T., & Sinclair, M. T. (2003). Tourism crisis management: US response to September 11. Annals of Tourism Research, 30, 813–832.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brau, R., Scorcu, A. E., & Vici, L. (2009). Assessing visitor satisfaction with tourism rejuvenation policies: the case of Rimini, Italy. Journal of Environmental Planning and Management, 52, 25–42.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Candela, G., Castellani, M., & Dieci, R. (2008a). Economics of externalities and public policy. International Review of Economics, 55, 285–311.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Candela, G., Figini, P., & Scorcu, A. E. (2008b). The economics of local tourist systems. In R. Brau, A. Lanza, & S. Usai (Eds.), Tourism and sustainable economic development: macroeconomic models and empirical methods. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Coase, R. (1960). The problem of social cost. Journal of Law and Economics, 3, 1–44.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Concu, N., & Atzeni, G. (2012). Conflicting preferences among tourists and residents. Tourism Management. doi:10.1016/j.tourman.2011.12.009.

  • Crotts, J. C., & Holland, S. M. (1993). Objective indicators of the impact of rural tourism development in the state of Florida. Journal of Sustainable Tourism, 1, 112–120.

    Google Scholar 

  • Faulkner, B. (2001). Towards a framework for tourism disaster management. Tourism Management, 22, 135–147.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Faulkner, H. W., & Tideswell, C. (1997). A framework for monitoring community impacts of tourism. Journal of Sustainable Tourism, 5, 3–28.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Feldman, A. M., & Serrano, R. (2006). Welfare economics and social choice theory (2nd ed.). New York: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Figini, P., Castellani, M., & Vici, L. (2009). Estimating tourist externalities on residents: a choice modelling approach to the case of Rimini. In A. Matias, P. Nijkamp, & M. Sarmento (Eds.), Advances in tourism economics new developments. Berlin: Springer-Verlag.

    Google Scholar 

  • Figini, P., & Vici, L. (2012a). Off-season tourists and the cultural offer of a mass tourism destination: the case of Rimini. Tourism Management, 33, 825–839.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fisch, M. (1982). Taxing international tourism in West Africa. Annals of Tourism Research, 9, 91–103.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fuji, E., Khaled, M., & Mak, J. (1985). The exportability of hotel occupancy and other tourist taxes. National Tax Journal, 38, 169–177.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gago, A., Labandeira, X., Picos, F., & Rodriguez, M. (2009). Specific and general taxation of tourism activities: evidence from Spain. Tourism Management, 30, 381–392.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Haralambopoulos, N., & Pizam, A. (1996). Perceived impacts of tourism: the case of Samoas. Annals of Tourism Research, 23, 503–526.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hughes, H. L. (1981). A tourism tax The case for and against. International Journal of Tourism Management, 2, 196–206.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jensen, C. M., & Wanhill, S. (2002). Tourism’s taxing times: value added tax in Europe and Denmark. Tourism Management, 23, 67–79.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lindberg, K., Dellaert, B. G. C., & Rassing, C. R. (1999). Resident trade-offs. A choice modelling approach. Annals of Tourism Research, 26, 554–569.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lindberg, K., & Johnson, R. L. (1997a). The economic values of tourism’s social impacts. Annals of Tourism Research, 24, 90–116.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lindberg, K., & Johnson, R. L. (1997b). Modelling resident attitudes toward tourism. Annals of Tourism Research, 24, 402–424.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Liu, J., Sheldon, P., & Var, T. (1987). A cross-national approach to determining resident perceptions of the impact of tourism on the environment. Annals of Tourism Research, 14, 17–37.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mak, J., & Nishimura, E. (1979). The economics of a hotel room tax. Journal of Travel Research, 17, 2–6.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Oi, W. (1971). A disneyland dilemma: two-part tariffs for a Mickey Mouse monopoly. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 85, 77–96.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pambudi, D., McCaughey, N., & Smith, R. (2009). Computable general equilibrium estimates of the impact of the Bali bombing on the Indonesian economy. Tourism Management, 30, 232–239.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Papatheodorou, A., & Lei, Z. (2006). Leisure travel in Europe and airline business models: a study of regional airports in Great Britain. Journal of Air Transport Management, 12, 47–52.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pearce, D. W., & Turner, R. H. (1990). Economics of natural resources and the environment. New York: Harverster Wheatsheaf.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rigall-I-Torrent, R., & Fluvià, M. (2007). Public goods in tourism municipalities: formal analysis, empirical evidence and implications for sustainable development. Tourism Economics, 13, 361–378.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ryan, C. (1991). Recreational tourism: a social science perspective. London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Satuiendrakumar, R., & Tisdell, C. (1989). Tourism and the economic development of the Maldives. Annals of Tourism Research, 16, 254–269.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schubert, S. (2010). Coping with externalities in tourism: a dynamic optimal taxation approach. Tourism Economics, 16, 321–343.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vaccaro, G. (2007). Pro e contro un’imposizione fiscale sui turisti. Studi e Note di Economia, 11, 257–282.

    Google Scholar 

  • Weston, R. (1986). The ubiquity of room taxes. Tourism Management, 4, 194–198.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Williams, T. A. (1979). Impact of domestic tourism in host population: the evolution of a model. Tourist Recreation Research, 4, 15–21.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2012 Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Candela, G., Figini, P. (2012). The State Intervention and the Public Organization of Tourism. In: The Economics of Tourism Destinations. Springer Texts in Business and Economics. Springer, Berlin, Heidelberg. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-642-20874-4_15

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-642-20874-4_15

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Springer, Berlin, Heidelberg

  • Print ISBN: 978-3-642-20873-7

  • Online ISBN: 978-3-642-20874-4

  • eBook Packages: Business and EconomicsEconomics and Finance (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics