Skip to main content

The Great Depression, the Global Financial Crisis and Old Versus New Keynesian Thinking: What Have We Learned and What Remains To Be Learned?

  • Chapter
  • First Online:

Abstract

Following a brief overview of major developments in macroeconomic thought since the Keynesian revolution in the introduction the paper features three main sections plus a conclusion. The first section presents a detailed comparison of background institutions, policy responses and economic performance during the great depression (GD) and the Global Financial Crisis (GFC). The second section discusses the role of lessons from the GD in shaping fiscal and monetary policy responses to the GFC as well as newer problems that emerged during the second crisis. Among the newer issues are runs between financial institutions, the role of financial derivatives, the opaqueness of securitization, the too big to fail problem, the incompleteness of micro-based risk assessments by financial institutions and a modern reinterpretation of the liquidity trap. The next section contains a systematic comparison of the methodological similarities and differences between old Keynesian economics and its recent New Keynesian Economics reincarnation. The concluding section points out missing elements in both old and new Keynesian methodologies and speculates about the likely path of future macroeconomic research in the aftermath of the GFC.

Presented at the symposium on “Perspectives on Keynesian Economics”, Ben Gurion University, 14–15 July 2009.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution.

Buying options

Chapter
USD   29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD   84.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD   109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD   109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Learn about institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    Interestingly, the view that the long run Phillips curve is vertical and that money is neutral in the long run took hold in spite of the fact that econometric studies of the time indicated that, although worse than in the short run, the tradeoff between inflation and unemployment does not totally disappear in the long run (Solow 1969; Cukierman 1974).

  2. 2.

    In a classic article Diamond and Dybvig (1983) show that deposit insurance neutralizes the incentive of depositors to run on banks.

  3. 3.

    An isolated exception was the case of Northern Rock in the UK. Following the broadening of deposit insurance by UK authorities, this run too was quickly quelled.

  4. 4.

    An additional reason for this large figure is the decrease in tax collections due to the recession. Fiscal year 2009 started on October 1, 2008 and will end on September 30, 2009.

  5. 5.

    Since the price level went down the real decrease was lower. Romer (2009) puts it at over 25%.

  6. 6.

    Interestingly, the flight to safety at the end of 2008 and the beginning of 2009 enabled the Treasury to borrow funds needed to finance the recapitalization of banks and other activities at low interest rates.

  7. 7.

    This subsection introduces some of the most salient new issues raised by the GFC but does not discuss possible solutions. Those are discussed in greater detail in Cukierman (Forthcoming).

  8. 8.

    There was some attempt to recapitalize banks during the GD under Roosevelt. However its size was modest in comparison to the bailout effort, to date, during the GFC.

  9. 9.

    During 2008 Bear-Stern, AIG, Citibank, Merrill-Lynch, Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac were bailed out in various ways. Although Lehman Brothers was not rescued it is clear that the financial shock waves created by its downfall raised the likelihood that systemically important institutions will, most likely, be bailed out in the future.

  10. 10.

    This section draws on section 2 of Cukierman (2005).

  11. 11.

    This statement is also true for open economy versions of New Keynesian frameworks like Obstfeld and Rogoff (1995).

  12. 12.

    In the old models there is no explicit mention of the length of time over which prices are sticky.

  13. 13.

    Recent evidence for the US supports the view that nominal wages are particularly sticky downward (Bewley 1999).

  14. 14.

    Explicit modeling of the consequences of costs of price adjustments for endogenous price setting decisions have been extensively studied during the eighties at the micro level. A collection of relevant articles appears in Sheshinski and Weiss (1993). Another device occasionally used to model costs of price adjustments in New Keynesian models are quadratic costs of price adjustments (Rotemberg and Woodford 1997). Although convenient analytically, this device is less attractive than its Calvo counterpart for two reasons: First, it does not generate nominal staggering. Second, its implicit assumption – that the costs of price adjustments increase at an increasing rate with the size of the adjustment – appears rather unrealistic.

  15. 15.

    Interestingly, the monetary policy procedures of the ECB and of the Bundesbank before it are based on this view.

  16. 16.

    Chapter 7 in Cukierman (1992) shows that there is a tradeoff between price stability and financial stability, and discusses determinants of this tradeoff.

  17. 17.

    See: Goldin–Bordo–White (1998) for a very good summary of the changes due to GD.

  18. 18.

    See Figures 1 and 2 from: Spivak-Sussman (2009).

  19. 19.

    See: Golden Fetters by Eichengreen (1996).

  20. 20.

    Greenspan admitted in a famous Congressional hearing that there was a flaw in his theory. Interestingly, Greenspan recounts in his biography the influence of Ayn Rand, the epitome of libertarianism, on the development of his thinking.

  21. 21.

    Krugman (2009), p. 4.

  22. 22.

    For the effect of GD on institutions see: Goldin-Bordo-White (1998).

References

  • Ando, A., & Modigliani, F. (1969). Econometric evaluation of stabilization policies. American Economic Review, 59, 296–314.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bernanke, B. (1983a). Irreversibility, uncertainty, and cyclical investment. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 98(1), 85–106.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bernanke, B. (1983b). Non-monetary effects of the financial crises in the propagation of the great depression. American Economic Review, 73, 257–276.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bewley, T. (1999). Why Wages Don’t Fall During a Recession. Cambridge, MA, USA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Blanchard, O., & Kiyotaki, N. (1987). Monopolistic competition and the effects of aggregate demand. American Economic Review, 77, 647–666.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brunnermeier, M., Crockett, A., Goodhart, C., Persaud, A., & Shin, H. (2009). The Fundamental Principles of Financial Regulation, Geneva Reports on the World Economy 11. London: ICBM and CEPR, Preliminary.

    Google Scholar 

  • Calvo, G. (1983). Staggered price setting in a utility-maximizing framework. Journal of Monetary Economics, 12, 383–398.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cukierman, A. (1974). A test of the ‘no trade-off in the long run’ hypothesis. Econometrica, 42(6), 1069–1080.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cukierman, A. (1980). The effects of uncertainty on investment under risk neutrality with endogenous information. Journal of Political Economy, 88, 462–475.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cukierman, A. (1992). Central Bank Strategy, Credibility and Independence: Theory and Evidence. Cambridge, MA, USA: The MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cukierman, A. (2005). Keynesian economics, monetary policy and the business cycle – new and old. CESifo Economic Studies, 51(4), 697–728. Available at: http://www.tau.ac.il/~alexcuk/pdf/CES-ifo-ES-12-05.pdf.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cukierman, A. (Forthcoming). Reflections on the crisis and on its lessons for regulatory reform and for Central Bank Policies. Journal of Financial Stability. Available on the web at http://www.tau.ac.il/~alexcuk/pdf/Bocconi-Revised%20&%20Expanded-12-09.pdf.

  • Diamond, D., & Dybvig, P. (1983). Bank runs, deposit insurance, and liquidity. Journal of Political Economy, 91(3), 401–419.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dixit, A., & Stiglitz, J. (1977). Monopolistic competition and optimal product diversity. American Economic Review, 67, 297–308.

    Google Scholar 

  • Duffie, D., & Zhu, H. (2009). Does a Central Clearing Counterparty Reduce Counterparty Risk? Stanford: Stanford University.

    Google Scholar 

  • Friedman, M. (1968). The role of monetary policy. American Economic Review, 58, 1–17.

    Google Scholar 

  • Friedman, M., & Schwartz, A. (1963). A Monetary History of the US, 1867–1960. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • G20 Official Communique. (2009). Global Plan for Recovery and Reform, 2 April 2009.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gali, J. (2008). Monetary Policy, Inflation and the Business Cycle: An Introduction to the New Keynesian Framework. Princeton and Oxford: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Goodfriend, M., & King, R. (1997). The New Neoclassical Synthesis and the Role of Monetary Policy. In NBER Macroeconomic Annual (pp. 231–282). Cambridge, MA: MIT.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hart, O., & Zingales, L. (2009). A New Capital Regulation for Large Financial Institutions, CEPR DP # 7298, June.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hicks, J. (1937). Mr. Keynes and the ‘classics’: A suggested interpretation. Econometrica, 5(2), 147–159.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kydland, F. E., & Prescott, E. C. (1982). Time to build and aggregate fluctuations. Econometrica, 50(6), 1345–1370.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lucas, R. E., Jr. (1972). Expectations and the neutrality of money. Journal of Economic Theory, 4, 103–124.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lucas, R. E., Jr. (1973). Some international evidence on output-inflation tradeoffs. American Economic Review, 63, 326–335.

    Google Scholar 

  • Obstfeld, M., & Rogoff, K. (1995). Foundations of international macroeconomics. Cambridge, MA, USA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Patinkin, D. (1965). Money, Interest and Prices: An Integration of Monetary and Value Theory (2nd ed.). New York, NY, USA: Harper and Row.

    Google Scholar 

  • Phillips, A. W. (1958). The relation between unemployment and the rate of change of money wage rates in the UK, 1861–1957. Economica, 25, 283–299.

    Google Scholar 

  • Romer, C. (2009). Lessons from the New Deal. Testimony Before the Economic Policy Subcommittee. Washington DC: Senate Committee on Banking, Housing and Urban Affairs.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rotemberg, J., & Woodford, M. (1997). An Optimization Based Econometric Framework for the Evaluation of Monetary Policy. In B. Bernanke & J. Rotemberg (Eds.), NBER Macroeconomic Annual (pp. 297–346). Cambridge, MA, USA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson, P. A., & Solow, R. M. (1960). Analytical aspects of anti-inflation policy. Papers and Proceedings of the American Economic Association, 50, 177–194.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sheshinski, E., & Weiss, Y. (Eds.) (1993). Optimal Pricing, Inflation and Cost of Price Adjustment. Cambridge, MA, USA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Solow, R. (1969). Price Expectations and the Behavior of the Price Level. Manchester, UK: Manchester University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sundaresan, S. (2009). Fixed Income Markets and their Derivatives (Advanced Finance Series). Amsterdam: Academic Press, Elsevier.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tobin, J. (1969). A general equilibrium approach to monetary theory. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 1, 15–29.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Woodford, M. (2003). Interest and Prices: Foundations of a Theory of Monetary Policy. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

References

  • Eichengreen, B. (1996). Golden Fetters. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Krugman, P. (2009). How Did Economists Get It So Wrong? New York Times Magazine, September 2.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mankiw, G. (2006). The macroeconomist as scientist and engineer. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 20(4), 29–46.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goldin, C., Bordo, M., & White, E. (Eds.) (1998). The Defining Moment: The Great Depression and the American History. Chicago and London: The University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cogan, J., Tobias, C., John B. T., & Volker, W. (2009). New Keynesian versus Old Keynesian Government Spending Multipliers. CEPR Discussion Paper 7236, March 2009.

    Google Scholar 

  • Romer, C., & Jared, B. (2009). The Job Impact of the American Recovery and Reinvestment Plan. January 8, 2009.

    Google Scholar 

  • Smets, F., & Raf, W. (2007). Shocks and frictions in US business cycles: A Bayesian DSGE approach. American Economic Review, 97(3), 506–606.

    Google Scholar 

  • Spivak, A., & Nathan, S. (2009). Inflation Targeting as the New Golden Standard. unpublished

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Alex Cukierman .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Appendices

The Great Depression, the Current Crisis and Old Versus New Keynesian Thinking. What Have We Learned and What Remains To Be Learned?: Discussion

Avia Spivak, Ben-Gurion Universeity and the Van Leer Institute

Where I Agree with the Paper

Cukierman correctly characterizes the current crisis (GFC) as less severe than the former crisis (GD). He lists a few reasons behind that phenomenon.

  1. (a)

    The greatly increased role of the government in the economy. The GFC institutional landscape included features that automatically stabilized the economy, such as the financial safety net to depositors. (Cukierman overlooks the contribution of the social safety net to the unemployed, poor, old and sick in limiting the severity of the crisis.) The increased power of central banks and treasuries in the economy allowed them to react swiftly to the crisis.Footnote 15

  2. (b)

    Under GFC there was a much better international system as compared with GD.

  3. (c)

    On the nominal side, the inflation targeting together with flexible exchange rates were successful in keeping international capital markets functioning while allowing substantial exchange rate flexibility.Footnote 16 On the real side, countries came to mutual agreement to avoid trade wars and managed to keep the international flow of goods and services unhindered.Footnote 17

  4. (d)

    Lessons that were learned in GD were applied in GFC, especially the need for active role of the central bank. Luckily, the Fed’s chair, Bernanke had studied the failures and mistakes of the Fed in GD, and thus was ready to prevent repetitions of the same mistakes in the GFC.

An important insight of the paper is that FDIC insurance solves run on banks by depositors, but not by banks on other banks or financial institutions. Run on banks by other banks can also have systemic repercussions, as the fall of Lehman Brothers on September 15, 2008 – that sent shock waves through the entire global system – showed. Thus, the theory that big financial institutions are too big to fail was proved and immediately applied to the rescue of AIG. The theory that non-banks financial institution – “shadow banking” need not be regulated because the market will regulate them proved to be false.

Where I Disagree with the Paper

  1. (a)

    The paper is silent on the political and intellectual background that allowed the phenomenal growth of the shadow banking. Both were united in the person of the then legendary Chairman of the Federal Reserve, Alan Greenspan. In his autobiography (2007) he writes:

The resulting advance of global financial markets has markedly improved the efficiency with which the world’s savings are invested… As I saw it, from 1995 forward, the largely unregulated global markets, with some notable exceptions, appeared to be moving smoothly from one state of equilibrium to another. Adam Smith’s invisible hand was at work on a global scale. But what does that invisible hand do? … Given the trillions of dollars of daily cross-border transactions, few of which are publicly recorded, indeed how can anybody be sure that an unregulated global system will work? Yet it does, day in and day out. Systemic breakdown occur, of course, but they are surprisingly rare. Confidence that the global economy works the way it is supposed to work requires insight into the role of balancing forces. (Those forces regrettably seem more evident to economists than to the lawyers and politicians who do the regulating.)…

The inevitable mistakes and euphorias of participants in the global marketplace and the inefficiencies spawned by those missteps produce economic imbalances, large and small. Yet even in crisis, economies seem inevitably to right themselves….[crisis] creates opportunities to reap abnormally high profits in the buying or selling of some goods, services and assets. The scramble by market participants to seize those opportunities … eliminate both the abnormal profit margins and the inefficiencies that create them. (Greenspan 2007, pp. 367–368).

It is this world view that was behind the abolition of the Banking Act of 1933 (The Glass–Steagal Act) in 1999 which was a signal for the relaxation of regulation of the financial system.Footnote 18

  1. (b)

    In the same vein, and not less important is the presentation of macro-economics as going through a process of seemingly harmonic evolution, centered around the NKM – New Keynesian Models school, These NKMs represent, according to the view presented – the best of the two worlds: Keynesian models that manage to be based on sound microeconomic foundations. Most economists, however, acknowledge the rift between the Chicago–Minnesota RBC school and the MIT–Harvard–Berkley school, nicknamed by freshwater economics vs. saltwater economics. This is how Nobel laureate Paul Krugman describes the RBC theory:

By the 1980s, however, even this severely limited acceptance of the idea that recessions are bad things had been rejected by many freshwater economists. Instead, the new leaders of the movement, especially Edward Prescott, who was then at the University of Minnesota (you can see where the freshwater moniker comes from), argued that price fluctuations and changes in demand actually had nothing to do with the business cycle. Rather, the business cycle reflects fluctuations in the rate of technological progress, which are amplified by the rational response of workers, who voluntarily work more when the environment is favorable and less when it’s unfavorable. Unemployment is a deliberate decision by workers to take time off.

Put baldly like that, this theory sounds foolish – was the Great Depression really the Great Vacation? And to be honest, I think it really is silly. But the basic premise of Prescott’s “real business cycle” theory was embedded in ingeniously constructed mathematical models, which were mapped onto real data using sophisticated statistical techniques, and the theory came to dominate the teaching of macroeconomics in many university departments. In 2004, reflecting the theory’s influence, Prescott shared a Nobel with Finn Kydland of Carnegie Mellon University.

Krugman goes on to criticize the NKM:

But the self-described New Keynesian economists weren’t immune to the charms of rational individuals and perfect markets. They tried to keep their deviations from neoclassical orthodoxy as limited as possible. This meant that there was no room in the prevailing models for such things as bubbles and banking-system collapse. The fact that such things continued to happen in the real world – there was a terrible financial and macroeconomic crisis in much of Asia in 1997–1998 and a depression-level slump in Argentina in 2002 – wasn’t reflected in the mainstream of New Keynesian thinking.Footnote 19

The lack of explicit financial system in the NKM due to the rationality of its agents and the smooth functioning of most markets that hence can go wrong is at odds with the original Keynes approach who put much stress on the mal-functioning of the stock market (the famous beauty contest paradigm). Indeed, Cukierman concedes that this part is still missing in the NKM: “The GFC makes the development of such analysis essential” (p. 28).

  1. (c)

    The rift in academic macroeconomics has implications for policy making in the GFC, and not on a small issue, but on the effect of fiscal policy on economic activity. More technically, by how much will a one percent increase in government expenditures increase the GDP. This magnitude is known as the Keynesian multiplier and the two schools arrive at very different numbers because they use different methodology. Table 2 shows the results:

    Table 2 Impact of a permanent increase in government spending by 1% of GDP (federal funds rate set to zero throughout 2009 and 2010)

Romer and Bernstein (2009) use old Keynsian models: “we use multipliers that we feel represent a consensus of a broad range of economists and professional forecasters… They are broadly similar to those implied by the Federal Reserve’s FRB/US model and the models of leading private forecasters, such as Macroeconomic Advisers”. Smets and Wouters use a NKM model.

The striking difference between the results say it all: the NKM results show only a transitory effect on the output, declining to less than six-tenths after 2 years. If physists and engineers had such disagreement on such basic calculations they could never have landed a man on the moon. (Macroeconomics today looks more like the failed project of landing a probe on Mars, where some teams used the metric system and the other the Anglo-Saxon system of inches and pounds; Mankiw (2006) separates between the role of the Macroeconomist as a scientist that uses very strict methodology with his role as engineer, who can use his intuition and broad knoweldge of the data and the economy to suggest useful analysis of the economy).

Conclusion

Cukierman correctly attributes the success of preventing the GFC from becoming another GD to the practical lessons learned from the GD and the resulting change in the institutional framework.Footnote 20

The influence of the academic development in the macro area is less clear. The Keynesian Revolution was succeeded by a monetarist counter-revolution led at first by Milton Friedman and them by Robert Lucas. According to Lucas and his school, there is very little that the government can do to change the course of the economy, even in times of crisis. It is fortunate that the decision makers were more practical.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2011 Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Cukierman, A. (2011). The Great Depression, the Global Financial Crisis and Old Versus New Keynesian Thinking: What Have We Learned and What Remains To Be Learned?. In: Arnon, A., Weinblatt, J., Young, W. (eds) Perspectives on Keynesian Economics. Springer, Berlin, Heidelberg. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-642-14409-7_12

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-642-14409-7_12

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Springer, Berlin, Heidelberg

  • Print ISBN: 978-3-642-14408-0

  • Online ISBN: 978-3-642-14409-7

  • eBook Packages: Business and EconomicsEconomics and Finance (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics