Skip to main content

The Structure of Classical Theory

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Competing Schools of Economic Thought
  • 1962 Accesses

Abstract

Classical economics is a term invented by Marx to characterise all economists beginning with William Petty (1623–1687) in England and Pierre Le Pesant de Boisguilbert (1646–1714) in France, and ending with Ricardo in England and Simonde de Sismondi (1773–1842) in France. According to Marx, the focus of classical economists was the determination of the surplus (value), defined as the difference between the value of total output produced and the value of (labour and non-labour) inputs used in production. The evaluation of inputs and outputs is in terms of prices, determined mainly by labour times. Furthermore, classical economists share the view that labour employed in production (in general) is responsible for the creation of surplus. Hence, some caution should be applied because Marx excluded, from his characterisation of classical economics, major economists such as Thomas Malthus (1706–1834) and John Stuart Mill (1806–1873), who not only questioned the validity of the labour theory of (exchange) value but also were eager to replace it with the ephemeral forces of supply and demand. Marx has also used the term ‘vulgar economists’ to refer to those whose analysis was based on the surface phenomena of supply and demand.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 109.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 139.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 139.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    In fact, Marx uses the term “classical political economy” (see Marx 1859, p. 52 and 1865, pp. 174–175).

  2. 2.

    The same economists today are called neoclassical economists.

  3. 3.

    This adjustment mechanism, where prices react on outputs and outputs react on prices is called cross dual and its details have been discussed in Chap. 2, while its formal presentation can be found in Flaschel and Semmler (1989).

  4. 4.

    Eatwell (1977) argued that in the determination of the rate of profit and the equilibrium of relative prices there is no need to assume any specific type of returns to production. That is to say, there is no need to assume that returns to production are constant in order to determine the rate of profit. The idea is that there is no interrelation between outputs and prices or between outputs and inputs, since output is taken as an independent variable.

  5. 5.

    We would say that relative prices and the rate of profit are inelastic to the changes in the input–output or labour-input coefficients.

  6. 6.

    The new Keynesian literature provides much more theoretical justification and empirical evidence in favour of the rigidity of real wages and also money wages. A rigidity which classical economists would not at all attribute to market imperfections.

  7. 7.

    As we will see it is doubtful whether there is an equilibrium rate of interest in the sense of natural rate of interest. We know that Marx definitely ruled out such a case, whereas Keynes’s position is ambivalent. It is important to note that this is still a hotly debated issue in macroeconomic analysis.

  8. 8.

    For the sake of simplicity we assume a circulating capital model with wages paid in advance. Of course, a more complicated model could be used and the interested reader can consult the relevant literature.

  9. 9.

    Rent is price determined rather than the other way around.

  10. 10.

    The idea is that as more people become owners of land overall demand for consumer goods is expected to increase.

  11. 11.

    This conclusion is in stark contrast with the presentation that is usually found in macroeconomic textbooks, where it is claimed that classical economists assumed full employment of labour!

  12. 12.

    The treatment of imports is a complicated matter and the interested reader should consult the more specialised literature.

  13. 13.

    For the definitions see footnote 37 in Chap. 5.

References

  • Blaug, M. (1999). Misunderstanding classical economics: the Sraffian interpretation of the surplus approach. History of Political Economy, 31, 213–236.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bleaney, M. (1976). Underconsumption theories: a history and critical analysis. New York: International.

    Google Scholar 

  • Carter, A. (1981). Structural change in the American economy. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Corry, B. (1959). Malthus and Keynes – a reconsideration. Economic Journal, 69, 717–724.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dome, T. (1994). History of economic theory: a critical introduction. Aldershot: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Eatwell, J. (1977). The irrelevance of returns to scale in Sraffa's analysis. Journal of Economic Literature, 15, 61–68.

    Google Scholar 

  • Eatwell, J. (1983b). Analytical foundations of monetarism. In J. Eatwell & M. Milgate (Eds.), Keynes’s economics and the theory of value and distribution. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Flaschel, P., & Semmler, W. (1990). On composite classical and Keynesian microdynamic adjustment processes. In N. Christodoulakis (Ed.), Dynamic modelling and control of national economies. Oxford: Pergamon.

    Google Scholar 

  • Garegnani, P. (1978–1979). Notes on consumption, investment and effective demand, I & II. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 2, 335–353; 3, 63–82. Reprinted in Eatwell, & Milgate (Eds.) (1983).

    Google Scholar 

  • Garegnani, P. (1983). The classical theory of wages and the role of demand schedules in the determination of relative prices. American Economic Review, 73, 309–313.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gehrke, C., & Kurz, H. (2006). Sraffa on von Bortkiewicz: reconstructing the classical theory of value and distribution. History of Political Economy, 38(1), 91–149.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Keynes, J. (1936). The general theory of employment, interest, and money. New York: Harcourt, Brace and Jovanovich.

    Google Scholar 

  • Keynes, J. (1937a). The general theory of employment. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 51, 209–223.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kurz, H., & Salvadori, N. (1995). Theory of production. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Leontief, W. (1986). Input–output economics. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Malthus, T. (1827). Definitions in political economy, London. Reprinted in E. Wrigley, & D. Souden (Eds.) (1986) The works of Thomas Robert Malthus (Vol. VIII). London: Pickering & Chatto.

    Google Scholar 

  • Marx, K. (1859). A contribution to the critique of political economy. New York: International, 1981.

    Google Scholar 

  • Marx, K. (1969). Theories of surplus value, parts I, II and III. Moscow: Progress.

    Google Scholar 

  • Paglin, M. (1973). Malthus and Lauderdale: the anti-Ricardian tradition. New Jersey: A.M. Kelley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pasinetti, L. (1977). Lectures on the theory of production. New York: Columbia University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Semmler, W. (1984). Competition monopoly and differential profit rates: on the relevance of the classical and Marxian theories of production prices for modern industrial and corporate pricing. New York: Columbia University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sraffa, P. (1960). Production of commodities by means of commodities: a prelude to economic theory. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Steedman, I. (1977). Marx after Sraffa. London: New Left.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tsoulfidis, L. (2007). Classical economists and public debt. International Review of Economics, 54, 1–12.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tsoulfidis, L. (2008a). Price–value deviations: further evidence from input–output data of Japan. International Review of Applied Economics, 22, 707–724.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tsoulfidis, L. (2008b). Capacity output. In International encyclopaedia of social sciences (2nd ed.). London: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Von Neumann, J. (1945). A model of general economic equilibrium. Review of Economic Studies, 13, 1–9.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Lefteris Tsoulfidis .

Appendices

Appendix A

A1. The Input–Output Analysis

The input–output analysis is a technique, which is used in the study of relations between industries. The major characteristic of input–output tables is that the total input of each industry must be equal to its total output. Quesnay’s Tableau Economique and also Marx’s schemes of reproduction form the basis of modern input–output tables.

The columns of an input–output table describe the inputs of each industry to itself and to the others. The column sum of an input–output table gives the total cost of production. Costs include the rewards of primary inputs also; that is, wages, profits, depreciation, taxes, etc., in short, the value added. The rows of an input–output table refer to the sales of an industry to itself and to the other industries (see also Chap. 1). A portion of the total output produced is absorbed by the final demand; that is, consumption, investment, government expenditures, and exports.Footnote 12

Table A1 Input–outputs

The classical assumption of a given technology implies that if for some reason the output of industry j increases, x j , it follows that the inputs x ij of the industry j must increase proportionally. The technological coefficients are determined by the following relationship a ij =x ij /x j , where a ij s are the technical coefficient or input–output coefficient. Once computed, input–output coefficients are treated as constant (fixed). Moreover, the column sum of technological coefficients for a viable economy must less than one, which is equivalent to saying that the value of output produced must not exceed the value of inputs that were used in its production.

The input–output coefficients can be converted from a descriptive invention to a useful analytical tool with the aid of linear algebra. In the interest of brevity we restrict the analysis to two industries. Thus we have:

$$ {{x_1} = {a_{11}}{x_1} + {a_{12}}{x_2} + {y_1}} $$
$$ {{x_2} = {a_{21}}{x_1} + {a_{22}}{x_2} + {y_2}} $$

where y 1 and y 2 are the final demands (consumption, investment, (net) exports, and government expenditures) of industries 1 and 2, respectively. Hence, we have a system of equations which can be written in terms of matrices as follows:

$$ {\left[ {\begin{array}{*{20}{c}} {{x_1}} \hfill \\ {{x_2}} \hfill \\ \end{array} } \right] = \left[ {\begin{array}{*{20}{c}} {{a_{11}}} \hfill & {{a_{12}}} \hfill \\ {{a_{21}}} \hfill & {{a_{22}}} \hfill \\ \end{array} } \right]\left[ {\begin{array}{*{20}{c}} {{x_1}} \hfill \\ {{x_2}} \hfill \\ \end{array} } \right] + \left[ {\begin{array}{*{20}{c}} {{y_1}} \hfill \\ {{y_2}} \hfill \\ \end{array} } \right]} $$

and in compact form x=Ax+y which solves for the output vector

$$ x = {({\rm I}--{\rm A})^{--1}}y $$

the matrix (ΙΑ)–1 is known as the Leontief inverse whose columns show the input requirements, both direct, and indirect, on all other producers, generated by one unit of output.

A.1.1 Price Determination

In what follows we introduce prices p 1 and p 2 which correspond to the outputs of industries 1 and 2, respectively. The total revenues from the sales of each sector will be:

Revenues of industry 1: p 1 x 1

Revenues of industry 2: p 2 x 2

Τhe total cost of each industry is:

Cost of industry 1: (p 1 a 11+p 2 a 21)x 1

Cost of industry 2: (p 1 a 12+p 2 a 22)x 2

We further assume a uniform profit rate r and we get: \( {p_1} = {p_1}{a_{11}} + {p_2}{a_{21}} + r({p_1}{a_{11}} + {p_2}{a_{21}}) = (1 + r)({p_1}{a_{11}} + {p_2}{a_{21}}) \)

$$ {p_2} = {p_1}{a_{12}} + {p_2}{a_{22}} + r({p_1}{a_{12}} + {p_2}{a_{22}}) = (1 + r)({p_1}{a_{12}} + {p_2}{a_{22}}) $$

or in matrix form:

$$ {\left[ {\begin{array}{*{20}{c}} {{p_1}} \hfill \\ {{p_2}} \hfill \\ \end{array} } \right] = (1 + r)\left[ {\begin{array}{*{20}{c}} {{a_{11}}} \hfill & {{a_{21}}} \hfill \\ {{a_{12}}} \hfill & {{a_{22}}} \hfill \\ \end{array} } \right]\left[ {\begin{array}{*{20}{c}} {{p_1}} \hfill \\ {{p_2}} \hfill \\ \end{array} } \right]} $$

The problem now is to find the rate of profit and prices which are consistent with the givens of this economy. Clearly, the profit rate will correspond to the maximum eigen value of our hypothetical economy while equilibrium prices will correspond to the associated eigenvector. If we therefore write the above system in compact form, we will have:

$$ p\prime (1/1 + r) = A\prime p\prime \,or\,p\gamma = p{\rm A}, $$

where the eigenvalue 1/1+r and where the eigenvector p corresponds to the vector of positive relative prices.

A.1.2 A Numerical Example

For the better understanding of the preceding analysis let us take a realistic input–output table in order to present a series of questions that we referred to above. The data are presented below:

Table A.2 Aggregated input–output table

The input–output coefficients of the above input–output table are estimated if we divide each of the inputs of each sector by the total output produced. Thus we have:

$$ A = \left[ {\begin{array}{*{20}{c}} {8969/71189} & {32919/244519} & {489/114875} \\ {8180/71189} & {84296/244519} & {16661/114875} \\ {3034/71189} & {18286/244519} & {9350/114875} \\ \end{array} } \right] = \left[ {\begin{array}{*{20}{c}} {0.125} & {0.134} & {0.004} \\ {0.114} & {0.344} & {0.145} \\ {0.042} & {0.074} & {0.081} \\ \end{array} } \right] $$

We observe that the sum of no column or row of matrix Α exceeds one and as a result the economy produces surplus and thus it is capable of reproduction (for details see Passineti 1977).

A.1.3 The Marxian Theory of Value and Direct Prices

If we symbolise the row vector of values of produced commodities by λ, the row vector of direct labour coefficients by a ο the indirect labour, that is, the labour contained in the inputs which are used in the current production of commodity j by λ j a ij and the value of depreciation, that is the wear and tear of the fixed capital invested in every production period, by λ j d ij , then we will have:

$$ {[{\lambda_1},{\lambda_2},...,{\lambda_n}] = [{a_{o1}},{a_{o2}},...,{a_{on}}] + [{\lambda_1},{\lambda_2},...,{\lambda_n}]\left[ {\begin{array}{*{20}{c}} {{a_{11}} + {d_{11}}} \hfill & {{a_{12}} + {d_{12}}} \hfill & {...} \hfill & {{a_{1n}} + {d_{1n}}} \hfill \\ {{a_{21}} + {d_{21}}} \hfill & {{a_{22}} + {d_{22}}} \hfill & {...} \hfill & {{a_{2n}} + {d_{2n}}} \hfill \\ \cdots \hfill & \cdots \hfill & \cdots \hfill & \cdots \hfill \\ {{a_{n1}} + {d_{n1}}} \hfill & {{a_{n2}} + {d_{n2}}} \hfill & \cdots \hfill & {{a_{nn}} + {d_{nn}}} \hfill \\ \end{array} } \right]} $$

or in compact form

$$ \lambda = {\alpha_o} + \lambda ({\rm A} + D) $$

where D is the matrix of depreciation coefficients. The above equation solves for:

$$ \lambda = {a_o}{[{\rm I}--({\rm A} + D)]^{ - 1}} $$

Using the above input–output numerical example together with the corresponding matrix of depreciation coefficients and the vector of the labour input coefficients, that is,

$$ D = \left[ {\begin{array}{*{20}{c}} 0 & 0 & 0 \\ {0.012} & {0.019} & {0.029} \\ {0.006} & {0.004} & {0.002} \\ \end{array} } \right]\,and{ }{a_o} = \left[ {\begin{array}{*{20}{c}} {0.592} & {0.198} & {0.422} \\ \end{array} } \right] $$

and after the appropriate substitutions we get:

$$ \lambda = \left[ {0.784 0.547 0.567} \right] $$

The row vector λ gives the quantity of homogenised labour contained (directly and indirectly) in the output of each sector. The notion of value in Marx is, as we know, monetary. Thus we have to transform the above quantities of direct and indirect labour time to direct prices, which we symbolise by d j . For the estimation as well as for the comparison of direct prices with the market prices, we consider that the market price of each unit of output of a sector is equal to 1 monetary unit. We stipulate the following normalisation condition dλx=λex and so the vector of labour values is transformed to direct prices as follows:

$$ d = \lambda \frac{{e \cdot x}}{{\lambda \cdot x}} = [0.784{ }0.547{ }0.567] \cdot 1.68 $$

so we get:

$$ d = \left[ {0.846 1.025 1.064} \right] $$

We observe that the vector of direct prices is extremely close to the vector of market prices, which we symbolise by e and which is the row unit vector. This can be identified by using one of the usual measures of deviationsFootnote 13:

  • The mean absolute deviation is 0.147 or 14.7%.

  • The mean absolute weighted by the output deviation is 0.098 or 9.8%.

A.1.4 Prices of Production

In Marxian analysis prices of production are defined as the prices that incorporate the economy’s general profit rate. For their estimation, we need the real wage of the workers, that is, the basket of goods that the workers spend their wage money on, i.e.,

$$ w = pb $$

where w is the wage money and b is the (nx1) vector of real wage goods. In addition, we take into account the following matrices that correspond to the above numerical example:

$$ < t > = \left[ {\begin{array}{*{20}{c}} {0.0019} & 0 & 0 \\ 0 & {0.1291} & 0 \\ 0 & 0 & {0.0771} \\ \end{array} } \right],\,K = \left[ {\begin{array}{*{20}{c}} 0 & 0 & 0 \\ {1.136} & {0.480} & {1.8918} \\ {0.0272} & {0.0410} & {0.08083} \\ \end{array} } \right]\,and\,b = \left[ {\begin{array}{*{20}{c}} {0.0046} \\ {0.0124} \\ {0.0118} \\ \end{array} } \right] $$

where <t> is the diagonal matrix of indirect tax coefficients, K is the matrix of fixed capital stock coefficients and b is the vector of wage goods. Thus prices of production are defined as

$$ {p = pb{a_o} + pA + pD + p < t > + rpK} $$

where ba o is a new matrix that represents the quantity of commodity i which is required for the consumption of workers in order to produce commodity j. The above relation after some manipulation gives the following eigenequation:

$$ {p(1/r) = pK{{[I - (ba + A + D + < t > )]}^{ - 1}}} $$

According to Perron–Frobenious theorem only the maximal eigenvalue is associated with a unique positive left-hand side eigenvector which gives the vector of relative prices. In terms of our numerical example we get the rate of profit r= 0.136 and the normalised vector of prices of production which will be:

$$ p = \left[ {1.054 0.971 1.027} \right] $$

Once again we invoke the statistics of deviation:

  • The mean absolute deviation is 0.036 or 3.6%.

  • The mean absolute weighted deviation is 0.032 or 3.2%.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2009 Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Tsoulfidis, L. (2009). The Structure of Classical Theory. In: Competing Schools of Economic Thought. Springer, Berlin, Heidelberg. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-540-92693-1_6

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-540-92693-1_6

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Springer, Berlin, Heidelberg

  • Print ISBN: 978-3-540-92692-4

  • Online ISBN: 978-3-540-92693-1

  • eBook Packages: Business and EconomicsEconomics and Finance (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics