Keywords

These keywords were added by machine and not by the authors. This process is experimental and the keywords may be updated as the learning algorithm improves.

1 Introduction

Economic historians now know that inequality has not been a constant feature of the Latin American landscape since the original colonization by Spain and Portugal. Rather it has fallen and risen several times over the two centuries of independence, and the dawn of the twenty-first century has also brought a welcome slight retreat from extreme inequality.Footnote 1 Why the movements, and why the differences between countries?

Fortunately, the dawn of this century has brought not only a slight reversal of earlier inequality trends in Latin America, but also a blossoming of research on the sources of income inequality in the region today, lead by the World Bank and other international development agencies.Footnote 2 This impressive wave of research has delivered an important part of what was promised by a World Bank call to arms back in the 1970s. Under the Presidency of Robert McNamara, a Bank team co-published the often-cited Redistribution with Growth, outlining how developing countries could produce more and share it more equally, and generating research momentum on these themes. Redistribution told a parable of some wise pro-growth egalitarians (Korea, Sri Lanka, Taiwan), in contrast to four Latin American countries that failed to follow this True Path. Brazil, Mexico, Panama, and Peru were characterized by some of the world’s sharpest inequalities and not particularly strong growth. In later years, ECLAC (1990, 1992) and the World Bank study Inequality in Latin America: Breaking With History? explored the same questions more deeply.Footnote 3

Did government fiscal preferences add to the inequality? That is, what distributional role has been played by movements in government fiscal policy, versus such market forces as changes in technological bias, trade expansion, shifts in labor supply, and shifts in the rate of private accumulation of human capital? For most of the two centuries of post-colonial history, inequality movements must have been caused largely by the ebb and flow of such larger forces outside of government, for the simple reason that government remained so small. Yet government’s share of Latin American economies grew across the twentieth century and into the twenty-first, causing us to wonder how and when the region’s regimes became “progressive” or “regressive” in their fiscal redistribution, breeding equality, or inequality.

The spate of recent studies suggests that countries’ income inequalities in Latin America now differ as much from each other, and from inequalities in OECD countries on other continents, in their fiscal redistribution as in the pre-fisc original incomes they get from market forces. Among data-supplying countries, the Latin American countries stand out as the most unequal countries in terms of people’s final incomes, partly because they have more unequal original incomes and partly because their governments redistribute less.Footnote 4 Why have they had so little progressive redistribution lately, even after the much-heralded retreat from peak inequality? And has the same been true for a century or longer?

This chapter’s strategy exploits the deep analysis of the twenty-first century distributional impact of fiscal policy, and uses it to explore episodes since the nineteenth century to initiate a history of fiscal incidence. We offer these tentative results:

  1. (1)

    Social spending has accelerated in the postwar era: Tax-funded social spending has risen throughout the region since the 1980s.Footnote 5

  2. (2)

    The region invests little in its future today: Latin America redistributes less toward future generations than do other regions. Rather, the region is one of those, like Mediterranean Europe, where redistribution tilts away from investing in future generations and favoring the elderly in privileged formal sectors.

  3. (3)

    It has invested relatively little in infrastructure and education ever since independence: Relative to other regions at comparable income levels, Latin America has invested less in its younger generations since the nineteenth century, and since the middle of the twentieth century it has favored its privileged seniors than other regions have done. Even before the 1990s, when public education was the main form of social spending, less was committed to mass education than in East Asia, East Europe, or the Middle East at similar levels of average income. In what follows we note some important historical exceptions to this rule.

  4. (4)

    Progressivity has been meager. Aside from the Cuban Revolution, governments have redistributed only modestly, preferring a conflicted mix of “redistribution to the rich and the poor.”Footnote 6

  5. (5)

    The rise of non-contributory public pension subsidies to retirees from the formal sectors stands out as a path-dependent legacy that will continue to retard progressivity and public investment. A telltale sign of the strength of this commitment is the design of the pension “reform” in Pinochet’s Chile and the countries that sought to emulate it later.

  6. (6)

    Chile has stood out, as a volatile, and initially regressive, redistributor since 1973. Redistributive policy was visibly regressive in the Pinochet era, both on the expenditure side and with a seemingly regressive tax structure. Yet since 1990 the net impact of its fiscal redistribution was slightly progressive in conventional Gini measures, because it benefited the rich less than their share of pre-fiscal income.

  7. (7)

    Military autocracies differed in their redistributive strategies. Military rule periods did not affect redistribution in the same way in all countries. Unlike Chile (1973–1989), the junta in Uruguay (1973–1985) left the tax and social spending mix alone, at low absolute levels. Argentina’s military rule (1976–1983) consolidated the social security system for most of the period, whereas Peru’s military regime (1968–1980) was quite progressive.

  8. (8)

    Human investments have brought more durable, though delayed, gains relative to transfers, both in the growth of GDP and in holding down inequality. In particular, Costa Rica has gained ground against Uruguay by emphasizing primary and secondary education over pensions.

  9. (9)

    Social spending has been not only volatile but also pro-cyclical. Relative to GDP growth, annual changes in real social spending are at least two times or more variable. Moreover, they tend to follow the swings in economic activity.Footnote 7

2 Strategies for Tracing a History of Fiscal Incidence

Starting from the fiscal mix of this century and the distributional impacts on each household income quintile, we explore the implications of the historical movement in the fiscal mix. Like previous studies of fiscal incidence, ours uses imperfect and incomplete measures to provide insights into differences in progressivity and regressivity. These limitations are so strict that the fiscal incidence calculations are useful only as plausible suggestions about the direction of effect and the general orders of magnitude. As public finance textbooks warn their readers repeatedly, one should never imagine that all the possible effects of a particular set of budgetary flows have been worked out.

To be true to real-world budgetary processes and to pose interesting counterfactuals, one must weigh fiscal incidence on both the revenue side and the expenditure side, using a consistent definition of fiscal neutrality on both sides. Most studies have failed to do so. On the revenue side, studies of the progressivity (or regressivity) of taxation have typically assumed that the revenues are spent in proportion to pre-fisc original income, a rare outcome. On the expenditure side, studies of expenditure progressivity typically assume that the expenditures are financed by taxes that are fixed per person, another rare outcome. Real-world budgetary processes adjust revenues and expenditures together, requiring a two-sided measure of progressivity.

In Latin American history, the expenditure side of the fiscal coin reveals more about differences between countries, and also yields more data. On the revenue side, Kenneth Sokoloff and Eric Zolt have noted a strikingly consistent regional pattern: Latin America, more than any other region, relied on taxing domestic consumption, with little or no direct tax on individual incomes or property. Latin America also tended to concentrate fiscal authority more in the hands of the central government (Sokoloff and Zolt 2006). In what follows, we extract most of the information on differences in progressivity or regressivity from differences in the size and composition of social expenditures, rather than from differences in taxes or non-social expenditures.

To pose sensible counterfactuals about countries’ fiscal incidence, the analysis should also make international comparisons. There should be little interest in comparing the actual fiscal patterns with the zero-government counterfactual, as in the presentation of most estimates. Rather we should compare governments’ fiscal incidence with those of well-documented real-world alternatives, such as Chile or the USA. In our overview of the longer history of redistribution, we will take up the Chilean case first, and compare other countries to Chile.

2.1 Redistribution Through Each Year’s Social Spending and Taxes

Governments channel their tax revenues into three kinds of expenditures: social spending, non-social spending, and debt reduction. The three have very different effects on the distribution of income. Estimating such effects requires figuring out which levels in the income ranks get more or less from each kind of expenditure and the revenues that back it.

The first effect is that of a given social spending budget. That is the traditional focus of much of the fiscal incidence scholarship, and it has been updated skillfully and energetically in the recent literature on Latin America. We shall pursue the same theme at length, taking care to include public spending on health and education as well as social transfers, while also incorporating tax incidence into the calculations of progressivity or regressivity when we can.

To define our measures of impact on the rich, the middle, and the poor, we start with a budget identity for government:

$$ \varSigma {S}_{it}+\varSigma {N}_{jt}-{D}_t=\varSigma {R}_{kt} $$

Here S it = the amount of the ith kind of social spending in time period t. Similarly, N jt is the amount of the jth kind of non-social spending (general administration, police, the military, infrastructure, and so forth), and R kt is the kth kind of government revenue (income tax, tariffs, other taxes, or income from government enterprises and assets). The revenues can cover less than the expenditures to the amount of D t , this time period’s government budget deficit. All magnitudes are in current prices. Later, to add economic meaning, they will be converted into per-household magnitudes and divided by national product or by an income class’s average income.

The budget identity leads to measures of redistribution by following how the direct effects of spending and taxes on household incomes are divided among the five quintile ranks, from the poorest twenty percent of households (q = 1) to the richest (q = 5). Like most of the literature on fiscal incidence, we humbly acknowledge—and then ignore—all the serious reasons why these simple “flypaper” measures of redistribution fail to measure the full range of effects, including general-equilibrium effects through factor markets. To allocate each kind of social spending, and the taxes paying for it, across the income ranks, we define the benefits minus the costs for each quintile, or B net,qit , as

$$ {B}_{net,qit}={S}_{it}\left({b}_{qit}-{c}_{qit}\right), $$

where the five quintiles’ shares of benefits add up to one, as do their shares of the revenue costs \( \left({\displaystyle \sum}_q{b}_{qit}=1={\displaystyle \sum}_q{c}_{qit}\right) \).Footnote 8

To explore “effects” or “impacts,” one must return to the familiar question of counterfactuals: “the effect of the observed budget—relative to what?” As we have already mentioned, the usual analysis unrealistically implies a zero-government alternative, because it tries to assign effects to the entire budget. To pose more realistic counterfactuals, we shrink the scale of the comparisons. We consider the social programs one by one, posing the counterfactual of removing that one real-world social program and the revenues that financed it, while leaving other social programs intact. Imagining a zero option for that one social program is not so unrealistic, since Latin America had done without most of these small social programs until just recently.

The other dimension of our implicit counterfactual about each social program hides within our phrase “and the revenues that pay for it.” Which revenues? There is no point in imagining that all government revenues are at stake, since their amount far exceeds the social expenditures under discussion. Lacking any sound econometric estimates of which revenues increased at the margin when a given social program was introduced and expanded, we make a reasonable simplifying assumption about the revenues that would not have existed in the absence of each social program: For most of our historical measures, we assume that the same mix of revenue types would have held at the social program margin as we observe on the average. Thus if income tax were 16 % of all government revenue, state monopoly proceeds were 6 %, indirect taxes were 70 %, and tariffs were the other 8 %, these same shares would be assume to apply to the scaled-down amount of the social expenditures in question. We do not assume any deficit finance of the social programs, in order to keep the issue of the deficit separate.Footnote 9

To give the measures meaning as commitments to redistribution shares of income, we need to divide the absolute net benefit measures of B net,qit by an income denominator, also expressed in current prices. For convenience and brevity, we divide all quintile groups’ benefit measures from social spending, whether gross or net of taxes, by the same common GDP denominator. We then compare such impacts on rich, middle, and poor income groups.Footnote 10

One other shortcut is dictated by data limitations. The net benefit measures change over time in response to changes in three components of any social program: the program’s existence in a given year; its size as a share of national income; and its target efficiency, namely the extent to which it redistributes in favor of a particular group, usually the poor. We cannot pursue historical changes in the target efficiency of the social spending programs. Their history is just too complex and under-documented. Accordingly, our journey back into the redistributive history of social spending can only follow changes in the existence and size of each category of social spending, with the restrictive assumption that a given program had the same target efficiency in the past that it has today. This retreat is regrettable in large categories of social spending and taxation that kept the same name but shifted their progressivity or regressivity over time. As it happens, the Latin American history of fiscal redistribution limits the historical errors we commit by not following the changes in target efficiency over time. Many of the most progressive social programs did not exist before the 1980s, and have changed only a bit since. Also, the sizes of the individual social programs themselves capture most of the redistribution. We will also limit the loss from not knowing target efficiency by breaking up the historically dominant category of social spending, namely public education, into primary and secondary and tertiary education, which offer very different rewards to the different income ranks.

Fixing the target efficiency of social programs (again, the i’s) at their present-day patterns means that our absolute measures of net fiscal benefits for any income class (q) in years past (the variable t’s) will be

$$ {B}_{net,qit}={S}_{it}\left({b}_{qiT}-{c}_{qiT}\right), $$

where the “T” subscript signals that the redistributive patterns (b’s and c’s) are those from “today,” usually a year at the start of the twenty-first century. In plainer words, our calculations of the fiscal incidence on different income classes will repeatedly ask The Question about any given year in the past:

The Question: How would the amounts of social spending programs, and the extra taxes that paid for them, have affected the incomes of the top, middle, and poorest income classes in that past year, if the benefits of those social programs, and those extra taxes, were distributed between income classes the way they are today?

In what follows we take advantage of the new information on how fiscal impacts are divided among quintiles to look not just at the movements of redistribution between rich and poor, but between rich and middle and poor, to explore the relationship of the “middle-income class” to the observed fiscal redistribution. When did the fiscal climate favor, or disfavor, the middle-income ranks relative to those at the top and bottom of society? To supplement the usual emphasis on overall inequality between rich and poor, we will break it into two parts, looking separately at movements in the fiscal treatment of the rich versus middle-income groups (top quintile vs. middle quintile) and at movements in the fiscal treatment of the middle and poorest groups (middle quintile vs. bottom quintile).

2.2 Non-social Expenditures and the Deficit: Investment and Redistribution Over Time

It would be tempting to explore how the different income ranks are affected by those other two kinds of public uses of funds: the government’s non-social expenditures (Ns in place of Ss), or to the overall budget surplus. Unfortunately, the paucity of data on these incidences prevents our pursuing them in depth, and fixes our focus mainly on social spending and the revenues that pay for it.

Still, there is one major division within the non-social spending that has powerful redistributive meaning and is easy to document. Some kinds of non-social spending are investments that will clearly raise the incomes of future generations. If they are paid for by current taxes, these redistribute from older to younger generations. The most obvious examples are such infrastructure investments as transportation structures, public buildings, science centers, and experiment stations. Other kinds of non-social spending have a more questionable claim to being investments in future generations. Running a budget deficit similarly redistributes from future generations toward the current generation. While such inter-generational redistribution is not at all the usual focus of the now-conventional studies of “fiscal redistribution” within a single year, the inter-generational issue proves to have been a distinctive problem for Latin America, and we must confront it first, before launching a longer exploration of the redistributions that play out completely within 1 year.

3 Today’s Redistributive Patterns in Latin America

The region redistributes income in distinctive ways. Before turning to today’s richly documented patterns in social expenditures, let us first stay with the theme of the inter-generational redistributions implicit in the patterns of recent non-social spending. The simple redistributive pattern in non-social expenditures is one that carries over to the shares of human investments in social spending.

3.1 Low Investment in Future Generations

Perhaps the most pervasive kind of redistribution between parts of society in modern peacetime is the redistribution between present and future generations of adults. Governments, businesses, and households all decide what share of their current incomes should be borrowed from the future or invested in it. Borrowing from the future may or may not raise inequality, now and later, depending on economic growth and how the borrowed funds are spent.

Was Latin American policy worse at investing in the future than policy in other continents? When? What roles were played in investment setbacks like the Latin American debt crisis of 1982? And was the failure to invest especially bad in income-leveling types of human investments, such as public education for the masses?

The investment component of government spending is notoriously difficult to separate out in the data for most countries, blocking our view of how Latin America contrasts with other regions in public non-social investment. Our view is also clouded by the long-standing difficulty in resolving how private investment in the future is affected by taxation and by government capital formation. Our best short route is to look at the official, and imperfect, measures of total private and public formation of non-human capital in the national product accounts. Taking this one step delivers a much clearer view of something distinctive about the region.

The best-known measure of a region’s investing in the future is the share of national product that is channeled into forming non-human capital, both by private parties and by government. Ever since the 1960s we have been able to compare the private investment share for Latin America with the rest of the world’s shares, with the results shown in Fig. 1. Latin America has consistently shown less sacrifice of current consumption for accumulating future assets than the world as a whole, and particularly less than East Asia and the developing countries of the Middle East and North Africa.Footnote 11 Eastern Europe and Central Asia have also invested greater shares than Latin America, even in the austere 1990s, after the collapse of the Soviet Union and central planning. Granted, India had a lower investment share than Latin America from the 1960s to the debt crisis of the 1980s, when Latin America’s investment rate was briefly the lowest among large regions; and granted, Africa South of the Sahara became the lowest-investing region from the late 1980s to the first decade of the twentieth century. Through it all, however, Latin America remained a below-average investor in future structures and equipment.

Fig. 1
figure 1

Capital formation as share of GDP, World Regions, 1960–2012

The region also invests little in human form. A cornerstone of modern growth has always been education in human skills and health. The traditional mechanism used by governments to promote such human development has been tax-based expenditures on formal education. Ever since the dawn of publicly funded mass education in Western Europe and its English-speaking offshoots in the nineteenth century, Latin American countries have lagged behind other regions, even where they had comparable incomes per capita and similar capacity for raising government revenue.Footnote 12 Figure 2 and Table 1 underline this point with a present-day global snapshot. Latin American countries commit less to each child’s public education than other countries, where commitment is reflected in the generosity of funding per school-age child and the ability to pay for it is reflected in GDP per capita.Footnote 13 Some countries are reluctant to support anybody of any age group with taxpayers’ money, as in the Dominican Republic or Guyana. Others support their average elderly person quite generously, yet still commit much less to each child of school age, two global extreme cases being Brazil and Venezuela.Footnote 14 Whether the pension money goes to rich retirees or to poor ones is a question to be taken up shortly. The essential point, though, is that the share of income going into educating children for future earning power is lower in Latin America than elsewhere in the world.

Fig. 2
figure 2

Supporting pensions vs. education: Latin America vs. others, 2010

Table 1 Supporting pensions versus educating the young: Latin America versus other countries, 2010

3.2 New Light on the Social Expenditure Side: Today’s Redistribution to Rich and Poor

What is now becoming clear about social expenditures comes to us mainly from some impressive team research efforts in The World Bank, the Inter-American Development Bank, and now the Commitment to Equity project headed by Nora Lustig.Footnote 15 Taking advantage of the international agencies’ vast accumulation of household surveys since the 1990s, these teams have been able to allocate the annual benefits from social programs among the different parts of the income spectrum, from the richest quintile (top 20 %) down to the poorest.

Table 2 displays what the international research teams have found about the “progressivity” or “regressivity” of distribution through different social expenditures in the decade 2000–2009. Our usual yardsticks for progressivity and regressivity of a public expenditure lie in the range between two popular assumptions about the taxes that pay for them. One assumption is an equal absolute tax, or foregone equal subsidy, on every household. This “poll tax” assumption divides the “clearly progressive” social programs of Table 2, in the left-hand column, from all the rest. Programs listed there on the left would prove to be progressive even if they were paid for by a (famously regressive) poll tax, a fixed amount of tax on each household. A more popular assumption, used by economists to define fiscal neutrality, is a flat percentage tax on all income or expenditure. This assumption divides the “clearly regressive” social programs, on the right-hand side of Table 2, from all the rest. The regressive ones are so tilted toward high-income recipients that they distribute benefits even more unequally than the distribution of pre-fisc original incomes, meaning that the distribution of final post-fisc incomes is even more unequal than the original distribution.

Table 2 Progressive and regressive social spending programs, Latin American countries, 2000–2010

The results have rightly been summarized as “redistribution to the poor and the rich” among Latin America’s social expenditure programs since around the year 2000. Many programs were meant to be progressive, shifting income from rich toward poor; yet some programs may not do so, and a few programs clearly redistribute toward the rich. The most clearly progressive programs are basic family assistance and “conditional cash transfers” (CCTs). The latter involve giving cash to poor parents (usually mothers) conditional on proof that their children were attending school and getting essential health care. The idea of means-tested CCTs was successfully invented and implemented in Brazil (bolsa familia, an extension of the previous bolsa escola) and Mexico (oportunidades, previously progresa). The clearly progressive CCTs have diffused to other countries in Latin America and to other continents.

In the case of public subsidies to education, the progressivity of subsidies depends on the level of education. Having the taxpayers pay for primary education clearly helps out lower-income families in nearly every country studied in the recent literature on redistribution. Yet government subsidies to tertiary education, such as university, are often not progressive. The students getting the subsidies tend to be from better-off families than the average taxpayers, given that most taxes in Latin America are levied on items of mass consumption. Thus the progressivity or regressivity subsidies to tertiary education “depends,” as shown in Table 2, on whether the government paid for the subsidies by levying the same absolute tax on every household or by levying a fixed share of household income.Footnote 16

Consumption subsidies vary widely between clearly progressive and clearly regressive. The result depends on whether the subsidized commodity is a necessity of life or a luxury. Table 2 illustrates this variability by contrasting the means-tested subsidies on essential foods (Costa Rica, Peru, Uruguay) and water (Chile) with the subsidies on airlines and agricultural estates (Argentina).

The impacts of public pension programs vary greatly, as Table 2 illustrates. Some are found to be clearly progressive (e.g., in Costa Rica, and Chile’s PASIS pension benefits), while others are clearly regressive in four countries, and still others are in between.

In reaching these conclusions, the research teams have taken special care to isolate the effects of those pension benefits that are truly redistributed from those that are not. What they have isolated in their recent studies, and what we must isolate as much as possible in the historical data, are the non-contributory parts of the public pension programs, the parts paid for by general taxpayers. We need to avoid counting the pension benefits that are paid for by contributions from the employees themselves and by their employers. These are just part of the labor contract, and not redistributions through the government’s budgets.Footnote 17 The recent wave of research has revealed some very large average shares of pension benefits not paid for by the recipients or their employers. Table 3 illustrates with recent information on pension program deficits as a share of the benefits paid. The researchers’ judgment is that these are true non-contributory (deficit) shares, and not run-downs from past contributions. We return to the issue of pension deficits when exploring the quantitative history of each country’s redistributive social spending.

Table 3 Average net pension subsidies in the early twenty-first century

The same kind of research on redistribution through social programs is extending around the globe. Some more global comparisons restricted to developing countries suggest a split in the Latin American degree of inequality reduction recently achieved by social protection and labor market programs. At the regressive end of the scale, El Salvador, Paraguay, and Peru are among the few data-supplying countries with slightly regressive programs, ones that actually raise the Gini coefficient of inequality above that for original market incomes (along with Ghana, Rwanda, and Cambodia). Toward the more progressive end of the developing-country ranks are the four Southern Cone countries (ABC and Uruguay). Yet even these redistribute less progressively through their social programs than do the countries of the former Soviet zone.

Latin America’s status as an unequal and not-so-progressive region would likely show up in the intergenerational immobility, as distinct from inequality, of its incomes if we had sufficient data comparing income mobility around the world. As a workable proxy for such income mobility, we have a global comparison of intergenerational mobility in years of schooling for the late twentieth century. Of the 42 countries studied, the seven Latin American countries studied had the least educational mobility from parents to children. Clearly, the region has formidable barriers to one’s chances of changing ranks in education, given the position on one’s parents.Footnote 18 These barriers will soon reappear when we look at the restraints on the progressivity of public education finance.

Why is there so little redistribution in Latin America today? The near-null result has not emerged because of lack of scale, at least not for the whole region. In some Southern countries social spending has surpassed 20 % of GDP, a threshold that could define a “welfare state.” Rather, the politically implemented design of social spending and taxes is itself a mix of “redistribution to the rich and the poor,” with inconsistent social targets.

4 How Did This Happen?

4.1 The Evolution of Fiscal Mixes Since the Nineteenth Century

We can easily see the overall net result of fiscal redistribution since Latin American countries gained their independence. Indeed, if we were content to take a single leap back to the historical horizon of 200 years ago, the net result is obvious. Back then there was essentially zero government, as in most countries around 1820. The net changes over 200 years are simply the present-day patterns we have summarized in Table 1 and in Figs. 1, 2, and 3.

Fig. 3
figure 3

Relative social spending benefits and tax burdens for Chile’s top, middle, and bottom income classes, 1965–2013. Sources and notes: see Appendix 1

How did this happen? To know what forces have led to the present redistributions, and their limits, one needs to know the where and when. Narrative histories have painted an historical landscape filled with regime changes and clashes between ethnic groups and special interests. New numbers can frame and support such paintings. We turn to the histories of some data-supplying countries, from which some patterns will emerge.

4.1.1 Chile Since 1842

Chile’s experience with fiscal redistribution is the mostly richly documented, and in recent years the most dramatic and controversial, of all countries in the region, aside from the Cuban Revolution. We shall use the size of Chile’s social budgets as a convenient baseline for commenting on the social spending efforts of each of our other five countries.

The rise of social spending as a share of GDP. Like the rest of the region since the 1960s, the central government of Chile has expanded social spending, a prime vehicle for fiscal redistribution, as shown in Table 4. And like the rest of the region, social spending evolved away from its being tiny and dominated by public education in the nineteenth century to devoting a rising share to transfers, especially pension payments, rather than to human investments like public education and public health. The annual detail behind Table 4, however, shows the instability of Chile’s spending during the military dictatorship of Augusto Pinochet (1973–1989). Education spending gyrated, and pension spending gyrated even more. Let us first describe our resulting estimates of how these gyrations in overall social spending twisted the incomes of the rich, middle, and poorest income groups, before turning to our interpretation of the complex pension reforms that were at the center of the storm.

Table 4 Social spending shares of GDP

The distribution of social spending since 1965. How did social spending affect people in different income ranks? To answer this question requires the procedure we previewed above, in which we apply today’s fiscal incidence of different social expenditures, and the average tax mix that is assumed to pay for them, to each year’s social spending as a share of GDP. Table 5 summarizes the recent unit impacts of each social program or tax on each of the five quintiles of households, in Chile and in three other countries.Footnote 19

Table 5 Fiscal benefits and costs as shares of GDP for benchmark years

Concentrating on Chile’s experience since 1965, Fig. 3 reveals the estimated effects on different ranks by following two kinds of ratios. The ratio of the social payments to households in the top income quintile to those in the middle quintile, or Q5/Q3, represents (one plus) the “upper gap” we introduced earlier, and the ratio of the payments to households in the middle and bottom quintiles (Q3/Q1) represents the “lower gap”. During the military regime, the emphasis in social spending shifted in favor of the top 20 % of the income ranks, and their advantage in such payments has persisted ever since, although it is slowly declining. The bulk of this increase consisted of rising pension benefits favoring higher income households, and the pension movements cry out for explanation.

Untangling the pension reforms of 1979–1981. The pension system set up by Chile’s famous pension reform was, and still is, a huge share of annual GDP. To clear the way for understanding its effects, one should begin by noting that it is not what it is often described to be. It was not a privatization of Social Security, as many have thought. There was no social security system to replace, but only a flawed and incomplete pension system for the privileged occupational groups of the formal sector. The reform also did not exactly privatize or liberalize pensions. It forced individuals to place pension contributions and benefits more firmly in the hands of the state and the private pension managing funds (AFPs) that the state appointed. It also raised the state’s commitments and pension deficits, and these are projected to continue until 2045. Government pension spending, far from phasing out, truly soared.

The 1979–1981 pension reform needs to be understood as a system with these key features:

  1. (1)

    The Pinochet regime inherited a badly broken and underfunded pension system in which formal sector workers were being subsidized. The regime chose to honor their underfunded entitlements by creating new government obligations to be covered by general taxpayers.

  2. (2)

    The reform exempted the military from individualized forced savings or the defined-contribution feature. Military personnel continue to get generous net defined benefits from the taxpayers.

  3. (3)

    To convert from defined benefit pensions to a defined-contribution system for civilians, the regime and its post-1989 successors have had to pay deficits to the transition generation. The deficits continue.

More specifically:

First, as mentioned, the previous system was badly broken, and the rise of unsustainable obligations was hidden from the official data of those pre-reform years. The occupational system for the more established formal-sector occupations, dating back to the 1920s, was increasingly mismanaged after about 1955. What had been a contributory system that should have funded itself slid into deficit, as more and more employees evaded making contributions while keeping their benefit entitlements. Between 1955 and 1979 the ratio of contributors to pensioners fell from 12.2 to 2.5, a result which cannot be explained by demographic trends, but rather resulted from allowing evasion of contributions while delivering generous benefits to those covered (Acuña Rodrigo and Augusto Iglesias 2001, p. 20).

For our accounting framework, this poses a huge problem of fiscal timing. As we had warned earlier, fiscal programs often give tax or benefit accruals in years that can be quite distant from the years of collection or payout. The 1979–1981 Chilean reform is perhaps the region’s largest case of such a discrepancy. The obligations taken on in the 1980s in effect honored formal sector workers’ evasion of pension contributions dating back to the 1950s, with benefits to be paid over subsequent years in ways that our studies have trouble tracking year by year. The military regime found itself inheriting a dilemma, one forcing it to choose between a shocking markdown of all occupational pension benefits and honoring the obligation to cover the full deficit. They chose the latter, with the result that the huge pension expenditures favoring higher-income beneficiaries suddenly show up in our graphs around 1975, even though they had secretly accrued over the previous two decades.

Second, as we have noted, the Pinochet regime did not dare to slash military pensions, nor did it include them in the forced-saving reform, even when holding its firmest grip on power.

Third, like any change in pension regime that tightens up, in pursuit of eliminating deficits, Chile’s new system faced the threat of double-taxing the transitional generation, forcing it to pay for the preceding generation’s retirement while also paying for its own. Like the military exemption, this necessitated deficits lasting for a generation, from 8.4 % of GDP in 1982 to 3.9 % by the close of the century.Footnote 20

At face value, the pension benefits suddenly became huge after the coup, and have stayed that way. In giving this impression Figs. 3 and 4 correctly portray what happened on an “accruals accounting” basis; yet they may mislead by portraying the movements as though the resources were paid out, in the cash accounting sense, at peak years like 1981–1986.

Fig. 4
figure 4

Net benefits minus taxes paid, on social expenditure in Chile, 1965–2013. Sources and notes: see Appendix 1

To portray the level, and the distribution, of pension benefits correctly, we have taken care to use measures of just the redistributive, or non-contributory part of all pension payments. Again, the part covered by current contributions is not redistributive. For 1981 on, we can interpret the Acuña Rodrigo and Augusto Iglesias (2001, Table 5) social security deficit part of pension payments as the redistributive component. It was the “total social security deficit,” most of which was the “transitory social security operational deficit,” with much smaller amounts for Recognition Bonds and for the more permanent welfare and minimum pensions.Footnote 21 The measures for the 1970s and earlier are less straightforward, for want of a clear measure of the pension deficit in those years.Footnote 22

The deficit was huge, taking at least 8.4 % of GDP in 1982, and still over 4 % at the dawn of this century. Clearly, the transition from a broken and underfunded system to a fully funded “defined contributions” system was fiscally costly for Chile, as it has also proved for other countries imitating Chile’s transition. It was also not progressive in Chile’s case, since the beneficiaries of the deficit were, and still tend to be, upper income groups, largely the same formal sector groups that underpaid for their pension entitlements before the reform.Footnote 23

Adding in the tax side. For Chile we have an opportunity to complete our counterfactual on the tax side. That is, there exist studies of how different kinds of taxes are distributed across the income groups “today,” where today is the year 1996, thanks to Engel et al. (1999). Their article on “unpleasant redistributive arithmetic” derived Chile’s distribution of direct taxes versus two kinds of indirect taxes in 1996, and we were able to apply their separate distributions to the shares of direct and indirect taxes back to 1965. This yields the distribution of taxes between high-, middle-, and low-income groups shown already in Fig. 3, and now in Fig. 4. Both portrayals show that the years of military rule were remarkably favorable to top income groups and unfavorable to the bottom, relative to the earlier and later regimes of democratically elected governments. Adding taxes into the picture shows an additional reason why: the top 20 % got a relative tax break, one that was largely reversed by the concertación government starting in 1991, as is also clear in Figs. 3 and 4.

Chile’s shift toward more progressive redistribution, and lower post-fisc inequality, since 2000 has been widely noted.Footnote 24 Our Figs. 3 and 4 confirm the rise in redistributive progressivity. The middle income groups regained a net positive fiscal effect across the 1990s, and the poorest quintile gained positive redistribution from 2005 on. The underlying mechanism, while not entirely clear, seems to have worked mainly on the tax side. Direct tax collections rose considerably as a share of government revenue, while the value added tax dropped. Given that the former fall mainly on the top quintile and the latter are neutral or slightly regressive, the revenue shift should have been progressive, as our figures imply.

4.1.2 Argentina Since World War II

Argentina’s commitment to social spending gained steam during Perón’s administration with expansion of education and social security; however, these policies were consolidated in later decades, as social spending became a larger share of the budget. This evolution was far from steady, as the Argentine economy failed to achieve stable economic growth. The social welfare state suffered a setback in the late 1970s with a sharp impact on the social security and labor market programs paired with a more regressive taxation system. Employer contributions were seen as detrimental to the private sector’s competitiveness, resulting into their subsequent abolition. With lower direct tax collection and increasing inflation tax, the net benefits of the bottom quintile stagnated at best. From the 1980s onwards, while social spending increased in terms of GDP, this rise was far from stable. Social spending has been more volatile than GDP growth and has run pro-cyclically. This combination has eroded its effectiveness as progress in education and health requires sustainable social spending. That said, the sheer magnitude of Argentina’s tax effort on behalf of social spending, as a share of GDP, jumped far ahead of Chile’s in the 1990s, under Menem. Argentina’s greater social spending share has not fallen back in the twenty-first century, despite the depth of the 2001 crash and the steepness of the subsequent recovery.

State-induced redistribution. With the advent of populism in Argentina, income redistribution towards the popular class became a priority for the new government. Under Perón’s initial presidencies (1946–1955), the public sector quickly expanded with the proliferation of ministries and the takeover of public utilities.Footnote 25 Social spending followed the trend, with education rising from 6 % of the budget to nearly 15 % by the end of the term. This commitment to education translated into a rise in enrollment reaching 50 % of the children in schooling age, a net 12-percentage-point increase from 1945 (Véganzonès and Winograd 1997). While education was an important component of social spending before 1970, the expansion of the pension system’s coverage turned into an important source of benefits, mostly to the urban population.Footnote 26 The redistributive efforts worked, as wage earners’ GDP share climbed ten percentage points by 1954 to reach over 48 % of GDP by 1954.Footnote 27 This impressive gain, however, was mostly due to public credit policies increasing monetary wages, including a very popular innovation of the compulsory Christmas bonus (the “Aguinaldo”).Footnote 28 Taking advantage of the taxation infrastructure established in the 1930s, the government expanded taxation by increasing rates . Faced with insufficient revenue, sales taxes rose from 1.25 to 8 % while profit and export taxes were also targets (Blanco 1956; Gerchunoff 1989). Later, the government attempted to ameliorate the regressive character of the tax system by decreasing taxes of basic necessities (Banco Central 1955).

More significant was the progressive role of the income tax (see Fig. 5). The top rates were increased from 7 to 22 % in 1942 to be revised again a decade later (Alvaredo 2007). Income tax collection grew accordingly reaching 2.7 % of GDP during the Peronato compared to 0.7 % during the previous decade.

Fig. 5
figure 5

Benefits of social spending, rich vs. middle vs. poor, Urban Argentina, 1870–2009. Sources and notes: see Appendix 1

The revenue-enhancing reforms failed to cover the growing public expenditure, and the government resorted to tapping social security funds. The growing imbalance of the fiscal accounts translated into inflation, reaching nearly 10 % of GDP in 1949. Though it decreased subsequently, the inflation tax was to remain a feature in the fiscal and daily lives of Argentina.

Consolidation and retreat of social spending with less progressive taxation, 1955–1989. Life after Perón was plagued with sudden changes in economic policy. The intermittent and interrupted long-term and stabilization programs hampered economic growth. In terms of social spending, the central government devoted considerable resources in the 1960s and 1970s to reach around 10 % of GDP, and over 25 % for all levels of government combined. Social assistance transfers (pensions and “other”) represented nearly 40 % of all social spending by the central government. Progressive taxation remained in place for another decade post Perón but it had unraveled by mid-1970s with a substantial decrease in direct taxes as a source of revenue.Footnote 29

Curiously the military governments did not eradicate the welfare state introduced by Perón, but consolidated it with an array of inefficient policies within the framework of a state-oriented economy.Footnote 30 Dubbed as paternalistic and rooted in Catholic views of a more unified society, the state expanded social security to include a new national housing system (FONAVI) funded by employers’ tax contributions. However, this expansion was short-lived. In 1979 the employers’ contributions are abolished, defunding the pension system and the public housing program. This sharp turn in social policy reduced the relative benefits of the top and middle quintiles as shown in Fig. 5. This slash of the benefits was outweighed by the government’s rising use of the sales tax to recoup revenue (Marshall 1988). With inflation graduating from moderate to high (and even reaching hyperinflation in 1989 and 1990), the taxation system turned much more regressive.Footnote 31 For the 1980s, the inflation tax incidence on wage earners hovered around 2.2 to nearly 6 % of GDP per year. However, the impact was 3:1 when comparing the first to the fifth quintile, making the tax incidence more regressive due to the increasing monetization of the fiscal deficit (Ahumada et al. 1993). Figure 6 shows the regressive net effect of this combination in the 1980s.

Fig. 6
figure 6

Net Benefits minus taxes paid, on social spending by consolidated government, Argentina 1970–2009. Sources and notes: see Appendix 1

The rise of social spending along with changes in taxation, 1990–2013. Since 1992 Argentina’s social spending has been more volatile, pro-cyclical—and more progressive, as shown in Figs. 5 and 6. Spending on social security has expanded, and the pension system alone reached almost 74 % of total spending in 2013. This time, however, the rise in pensions was progressive. The extension of coverage and the rise in social security paychecks explains most of this increase. Consistent with the retreat of post-fisc inequality observed in the 2000s, the net fiscal benefits for the bottom quintile increased substantially to nearly reach 5 % of GDP.Footnote 32 On the taxation side, the Menem government introduced a two-sided change. On the regressive side, it relied more on the value-added tax with rates climbing to 21 % while the income tax rate for the top bracket was reduced to 33 % in 1997 (to be increased 2 percentage points 3 years later). Yet at the same time, it improved tax collection by reducing evasion. This latter, progressive, side of the coin takes on a strong form in our Figs. 5 and 6, which show a trend toward progressivity shared by the otherwise very different presidencies from Menem to the Kirschners.

The impact of this mix actually worsened inequality in the late 1990s, according to CEPAL estimates.Footnote 33 Still, the expansion of social spending with an increase of overall tax collection gave rise to a more progressive fiscal redistribution since 1992.

4.1.3 Uruguay, the Social Spending Leader Over the Last 100 Years

Though the region has lagged in public education spending ever since Independence, Uruguay was an early leader in education levels, helped by its initially high income (Lindert 2010; Rodriguez Weber and Thorp 2013). Its commitment to primary and secondary education did not flag, although Chile and Argentina caught up by the 1930s.

In terms of social assistance, the 1930s saw a jump, due to enlarging the social security system, and to expanding the pension system to cover workers in the formal industry and commerce sectors.

What shows up even more clearly in the history of social spending is a consistent Uruguayan tendency toward equalizing incomes. As shown in Fig. 7, Uruguay’s social spending has been highly progressive throughout the last 100 years. The long rise of the redistribution in terms of GDP, so conspicuous in Fig. 7, is due mainly to the expansion in the size of social budgets, rather than to any shift toward greater unit progressivity of social programs. For at least a 100 years Uruguay has had a more progressive mix of social programs than in Chile.Footnote 34 Certainly the mix is more progressive today, as Table 5 testifies.

Fig. 7
figure 7

Benefits of social spending benefits minus taxes for them, rich vs. middle vs. poor, Uruguay 1910–2008. Sources and notes: see Appendix 1

One potential interruption to the upward march of social spending came with military rule in 1973–1985. In this respect Uruguay’s time path could have resembled that of Chile and Argentina. Yet in Uruguay the military rule did not reverse either the expansionary trend or the progressivity of social programs, as evident in Fig. 7. Thus Uruguay stands out as the region with the longest-standing trend toward progressive redistribution.

4.1.4 Colombia—Half Progressive, Half Regressive

Colombia’s patterns of fiscal incidence are decidedly mixed, according to two studies of social spending and taxes in the 1960s and 1970s. On the one hand, public primary education and all rural public services have been progressive, even in the “clearly progressive” sense delineated in Table 3 above. Subsidies to university education were highly regressive, in Colombia as elsewhere, although the magnitude of university subsidies was small in relation to the amounts given out in the other programs. Also regressive were urban public services. On balance, the entire fiscal system seems to have redistributed only a small share of national income, perhaps 1.4 %, from the top quintile the other 80 % of the population as of 1966.Footnote 35

On the pension front, once public pensions were started in 1967, Colombia has followed in Chile’s footsteps, both in the under-contribution problem inherited by reformers in 1993 and in the regressive deficits that the reforms brought to light. Again, as in Chile, repairing and removing the handover from the previous defined benefit system have proven difficult ever since the reforms were launched, in this case by Law 100 in 1993. Though the reform tried to set up a pension reserve, it was exhausted as early as 2004. Since the pension system covers only 25–27 % of the labor market, under a dual private-public regressive scheme, the central government has been forced to cover pension deficits out of about a third of its total tax revenues, or nearly 5 % of GDP. As shown in Table 4, Colombia fits the regional pattern of veering toward dominance of non-contributory pensions in its social programs, despite attempts to curb this tendency.Footnote 36

4.1.5 Costa Rica Since the 1940s

As the available numbers in Table 4 suggest, Costa Rica has had a steadier growth of social spending than some of the other countries.

As compared with Uruguay, Costa Rica redistributes less progressively each year, in the sense of reducing the Gini coefficient of inequality. Yet as of 2003, it has achieved greater equality of final income, and also greater equality of original (market, or pre-fisc) income. How? The contrast can have many explanations, including the countries’ fortunes in international trade. One element of social policy seems to have contributed. Since at least 1900, Costa Rica has poured a greater share of national product into public primary and secondary education than has Uruguay, and the difference persists in this century. Its broader skill base has produced more equality in the long run by equalizing basic earning power, thereby achieving a greater reduction in inequality than Uruguay’s more ambitious pensions and other transfer payments, even though both have existed since the dawn of the twentieth century. Here again, we must remember that each year’s egalitarian investments have a longer lasting, though delayed, effect on equality than that year’s expenditures can show.

On the public pension front, Costa Rica started developing its system early. Its pre-1948 institutional innovations became a permanent feature of Costa Rica’s equity oriented policy framework, despite the defeat of the system’s original designers during the civil war in 1949–1950. Costa Rica has more recently had the same problems of incomplete pension coverage and underfunding as in other countries, but these never became as serious as in Chile or Brazil or Colombia. The guidelines of social policy, like the larger issues of governance, were effectively resolved in the middle of the twentieth century, with a combination of political cooperation, foresight, and a lucky boom in coffee exports.Footnote 37

4.1.6 Peru Since the 1940s

Peru has always spent a lower share of GDP on social programs than even Chile, as Table 4 has shown. And on balance, its fiscal redistributions have not yielded any net progressivity. The social policies since the 1940s in Peru have derived from the role that the state played in the economy, swaying from interventionism to (neo)liberalism. The steady growth of social spending since the 1940s was abruptly interrupted with the crisis of the late 1980s, and then resumed in the following decades.

Modest progress under an interventionist state. From 1945 to 1948, the government adopted a pro-distribution stance through income policies (such as price freezes and wage increases) and extension of social policies (including free and universal secondary education and the Sunday wage). The state was seen as a means of economic development and social integration and social spending increased accordingly. With a change to a more liberal regime the government implemented a more pragmatic social policy with selected programs in education and health. From a macroeconomic point of view, none of these initiatives amounted to more than 2 % of GDP. The government intervention to foster social progress had limited impact by the early 1960s. While the net benefits were progressive, they did little to overcome the initial market-based inequalities, especially for the rural traditional sector. Confronted with this reality the military government headed by President Velasco (1968–1973) initiated an ambitious plan to redistribute income and wealth. This conscious commitment to redistribution translated into a significant increase in social spending.Footnote 38

Crisis and reform. The 1980s meant a continuous struggle to achieve macroeconomic stabilization resulting in a decrease of social and total public spending culminating in hyperinflationary episodes in 1987–1990. In the following decade the reorganization of the public sector included an expansion of social spending, especially in education and health. That expansion notwithstanding, Peru’s fiscal redistribution failed to be progressive overall, as shown by the studies that have led to Table 2.

5 Summary: What the Emerging Historical Patterns Suggest

Most countries’ social expenditure programs end up redistributing to an intermediate degree—that is, in the intermediate range shown in Table 2. They deliver a greater absolute value of benefits to higher income groups, relative to a flat per capita “poll subsidy.” That looks regressive. On the other hand, they deliver rewards that are less unequal than the distribution of original incomes. That means that their expenditure pattern dampens the serious inequalities of original income. This slightly progressive tendency is reinforced by the modest progressivity in tax rates as a share of original market income.

Of the six countries covered here, the two most progressive have been Uruguay and Argentina, which have historically met the standard of absolute progressivity for a few decades. To judge from the region-wide situation at the start of the twenty-first century, those two countries may have been the only absolutely progressive countries in all of Latin America, aside from Cuba.

To this pattern of only middling progressivity in social programs and taxes, we have added the easily documented tendency of Latin America to redistribute toward the current senior generation by investing little in the younger generations. Over recent decades the countries in the region have increasingly squandered lost economic capital and growth by spending their political capital on subsidizing the older generations with non-contributory public pensions. Of the countries studied here, the Southern Cone has redistributed away from future generations the most, and Costa Rica has done so the least. While Peru and Colombia have also tended to tilt toward pensions, they have done so with smaller overall budgets in relation to GDP, and their regressive side has manifested itself in more conventional ways.

This low-investment tendency has featured a hundred-year history of lower investment in primary and secondary education. The implied prescription is to seize the opportunity, at last, of achieving both more equality and faster growth with broader investments in human skills. In this prescription our study seems to be in accord with the present-day prescription of Augusto de la Torre and co-authors:

“[E]fforts to equalize opportunities for human capital formation, particularly by broadening the access to high quality education regardless of socio-economic background, must be at the core of the search for shared prosperity in [Latin America and the Caribbean].”Footnote 39

The region as a whole still has time to reduce the pension deficits that even Chile’s reform have not yet tamed. The opportunity is there because the region’s populations are still younger than those of the core OECD countries or Eastern Europe. Yet the political will may not be there, in view of how readily the appetite for non-contributory public pensions has grown since the 1960s, and how half-hearted the commitment to public education remains.