Skip to main content

Household Time Use, Inequality and Taxation

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Household Economic Behaviors

Part of the book series: International Series on Consumer Science ((ISCS))

Abstract

A basic dilemma underlying the vast literature on the measurement of inequality is that, conceptually, we are concerned about inequality among individuals but empirically, we measure the inequality of the distribution of household income and consumption.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 84.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    Throughout this chapter, whenever we refer to the word “household”, we mean it in this sense; otherwise, we qualify it with “single-person”.

  2. 2.

    See in particular Haddad and Kanbur (1990), who provide a thorough analysis of the statistical aspects of this issue.

  3. 3.

    This is a function, analogous to a social welfare function, which represents the household’s preferences over utility profiles of its members. Its use goes back to a proposal by Samuelson (1956). For further discussion, see Apps and Rees (2009).

  4. 4.

    See for example Gronau and Hammermesh (2006).

  5. 5.

    For earlier formal models, see Apps (1981) and Apps and Rees (1988).

  6. 6.

    This suggests giving the label “mercantilist” to the traditional approach to inequality measurement, which, however, is unlikely to be very much appreciated.

  7. 7.

    The sum of the values of the products of market wage rates and total time endowments.

  8. 8.

    In a model without household production, the idea that households may face different prices for the composite consumption commodity can be handled simply by defining their real wage rates as the ratio of the nominal wage rate to the consumption good price they face. In empirical studies it is usually, unrealistically, assumed that consumers always face the same market prices. In the present context, however, non-parental child care is a good example of a good whose cost varies, ranging from the opportunity cost of a grandmother’s time, through the fees for a pre-school playgroup or creche, to the wage of a highly trained nanny. These differences may not reflect simply differences in quality, but rather random differences in availability.

  9. 9.

    We assume that all of the child’s time is spent as leisure. This utility function could be that imputed to the child by its parents.

  10. 10.

    This, rather than the individual utility functions defined only on own consumptions, expresses the love, care and concern that household members may have for each other.

  11. 11.

    For further discussion of this function see Apps and Rees (2009), Chap. 3. We could also include additional exogenous variables, or “exogenous environmental parameter” in the terminology of McElroy (1990).

  12. 12.

    To see this, give 1 and 2 the same utility values in each household, and note that u k can be higher in h =1 if and only if \( {V^1} > {V^2}. \)

  13. 13.

    See Apps and Rees (2009), Chap. 3 for an explicit analysis of the effects of productivity variations across households.

  14. 14.

    Note also that we assume for simplicity that q h has no distributional effects within the household.

  15. 15.

    In the light of the analysis in the next subsection, it is clear that here we have assumed that the distributional term \( {{{{{{(\partial {l_{ih}}}} \left/ {\partial } \right.}{s_{ih}})}} \left/ {{{{{\partial {s_{ih}}}} \left/ {{\partial {q_h}}} \right.}}} \right.}) \) is small enough to be ignored. Note that the derivatives \( {{{\partial {s_{ih}}}} \left/ {{\partial {q_h}}} \right.} \), i = 1, 2, k must sum to 0, since full income is unaffected by a change in q h .

  16. 16.

    We can, in the usual way, use a Slutsky equation to decompose this into income and substitution effects.

  17. 17.

    Just as an oil exporting country gains from a higher price of oil even though it may be a major oil consumer also.

  18. 18.

    Since we are concerned with a single household, we drop the subscript h.

  19. 19.

    These explain the point made in footnote () above.

  20. 20.

    In a more comprehensive and realistic model, in which there would also be domestically produced consumption goods, the values of individual shares in these would also be part of the sharing rule. See Apps and Rees (2001).

  21. 21.

    See Apps and Rees (2001) for an approach to this. Note that the functional form of the sharing rule is implied by the forms assumed for the HWF and the individual indirect utility functions.

  22. 22.

    For a comprehensive discussion of how this model relates to the existing life cycle literature see Chap. 5 of Apps and Rees (2009).

  23. 23.

    This is supported by panel data studies. See, for example, Shaw (1994).

  24. 24.

    For each activity episode, information is recorded for a “primary” and, if relevant, a “secondary” activity. Where primary and secondary activities are reported, the weighting used is 0.6:0.4.

  25. 25.

    This gives samples containing 2,085 records from the TUS and 4,064 records from the HES. Less than 4% of records report negative incomes in the HES sample.

  26. 26.

    Private income is defined by the ABS as all income from wages, investments, etc. Government benefits are not included.

  27. 27.

    Of course, still more extreme would be that transfers are made from the lower to the higher income partner, or that the higher income partner transfers so much that the lower income partner ends up with higher income/consumption. We do not pursue these possibilities here, however.

  28. 28.

    In Apps and Rees (1996) we refre to this model as the “transfer model” to distinguish from our more plausible “exchange model”.

  29. 29.

    Gross wage rates are computed from hours and earnings data, and the predicted values are based on regression models estimated on data for workers, with the Heckman correction for selectivity applied in the estimation of the female wage equation.

  30. 30.

    The same argument can be applied to the market income of the female partner (as second earner) in phase 2 because much of her net income will be spent on buying in child care.

  31. 31.

    Apps and Rees (2001) show that when parental time cost of child care is included in the analysis of intrahousehold shares, the “cost” of a child is close to that of an adult.

  32. 32.

    Note that adding the opportunity cost of leisure to net income and the cost of home production gives full income. In Apps and Rees (2009, Chap. 5), we obtain a U-shaped profile of full income. We attribute this to an imperfect capital market in which the borrowing rate is above the lending rate.

  33. 33.

    In some countries, e.g. the USA, it is argued that this could be unconstitutional.

  34. 34.

    Equal to the sum of consumptions of market goods, household goods and leisures.

References

  • Apps, P. F. (1981), A Theory of Inequality and Taxation. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Apps, P.F., and R. Rees, (1988), “Taxation and the household”, Journal of Public Economics, 35, 355–369.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Apps, P.F. and R. Rees, (1996) “Labour supply, household production and intra-family welfare disitribution”. Journal of Public Economics 60, 199–219.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Apps, P.F., and R. Rees, (2001), Household production, full consumption and the costs of children, Labour Economics, 8, 621–648.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Apps, P.F., and R. Rees, (2009), Public Economics and the Household, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Australian Bureau of Statistics (2001), Government Benefits, Taxes and Household Income, Cat No 6537.0, ABS, Canberra.

    Google Scholar 

  • Browning, M. and J. Bonke, (2009a), “The distribution of financial well-being and income within the household”, 621–648.Review of Economics of the Household, 7, 31–42.

    Google Scholar 

  • Browning, M. and J. Bonke, (2009b), “The allocation of expenditure within the household: A new survey”, Fiscal Studies, 30, 461–481.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Browning, M. and M.Gortz, (2006), “Spending time and money within the household”, Oxford Economic Papers

    Google Scholar 

  • Gronau, R. and D. Hammermesh, (2006), “Time vs goods: The value of measuring household production technologies”, Review of Income and Wealth, 52, 1, 1–16.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Haddad, L. and R.Kanbur, (1990), “How serious is the neglect of intra-household inequality”, The Economic Journal, 100, 866–88.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lise, J. and S.Seitz, (2010), “Consumption inequality and intra-househhold allocations”, Review of Economic Studies, forthcoming.

    Google Scholar 

  • McElroy, M. B. (1990). “The empirical content of Nash bargained household behaviour”. Journal of Human Resources, (25)4, 559–583.

    Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson, P. A. (1956). “Social indifference curves”. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 70, 1–22.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shaw, K., (1994), “The persistence of female labor supply: empirical evidence and implications”, Journal of Human Resources, 29, 348–378.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Patricia Apps .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2011 Springer Science+Business Media, LLC

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Apps, P., Rees, R. (2011). Household Time Use, Inequality and Taxation. In: Molina, J. (eds) Household Economic Behaviors. International Series on Consumer Science. Springer, New York, NY. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-1-4419-9431-8_3

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics