Skip to main content

US and EU Agricultural Policy: Divergence or Convergence?

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Book cover The Economic Impact of Public Support to Agriculture

Part of the book series: Studies in Productivity and Efficiency ((SIPE,volume 7))

Abstract

The 2008 US Farm Bill has many similar features to the 2002 US Farm Bill where key provisions such as the target price and loan rate remain. On the other hand, the European Union is following a path of more decoupled payments, especially given the reforms in 2003 and afterward. However, many of the elements of either farm program may no longer be of significance if high commodity prices remain, many of which are above US target prices. High prices have caused many countries to lower tariff and nontariff barriers. In the context of high prices, the welfare costs of both the US and EU policies have been greatly reduced. However, especially for the European Union, there remains a large income transfer from the treasury to farmers since, under decoupling, farmers are given annual payments at least through 2013. Given the single farm payment scheme of the European Union, farmers are allowed to respond to high prices and, in addition, collect a subsidy from the treasury under the rubric of decoupling. Producers have collected double rents: from the market and the government.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 129.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 169.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 169.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

References

  • Ackrill, R., Kay, A., Morgan, W. (2008), The CAP and the GATT/WTO: A story of mutual influence and antipathy, Canadian Journal of Agricultural Economics 56(4): 393–412.

    Google Scholar 

  • Anderson, D.P., Outlaw, J.L., Bryand, H.L., Richardson, J.W., Ernstes, D.P., Raulson, J.M., Welch, J.M., Knapek, G.M., Herbst, B.K., Allison, M.S. (2008), The Effects of Ethanol on Texas Food and Feed, Agricultural and Food Policy Center, Texas A&M University, College Station, Texas (April).

    Google Scholar 

  • Arfini, F., Kleinhanss, W., Kuepker, B., Jayet, P. (2007), Insights from GENEDEC, DG AGRI Dissemination Meeting, http://www.grignon.inra.fr/economie-publique/genedec/publi/insights.pdf. Accessed on June 2007.

  • Benjamin, M., Drajem, M. (2008), Global import barriers fall as food prices trump Doha (Update), Bloomberg.com (April 15), http://www.bloomberg.com/apps/news?pid=newsarchive&sid=admKeNIaN5pw.

  • Binfield, J., Donnellan, T., Hanranhan, K., Hart, C., Westhoff, P. (2004), CAP reform and the WTO: Potential impacts on EU agriculture, Proceedings of the AAEA Conference, Denver, CO, http://www.fapri.missouri.edu/outreach/publications/2004/FAPRI_UMC_Report_08_04.pdf. Accessed on June 2007.

  • Carter, C.A., Schmitz, A. (1979), Import tariffs and price formation in the world wheat market, American Journal of Agricultural Economics 61(3): 517–552.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De Gorter, H., Cranfield, J. (2005), The Impacts of U.S. Crop Subsidies on Livestock Production, Department of Applied Economics and Management, Cornell University, Ithaca, New York, NY.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dillen, K., Demont, M., Tollens, E. (2007), European sugar policy reform and agricultural innovation, Canadian Journal of Agricultural Economics 56(4): 533–544.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dohlman, E., Livezey, J. (2005), Peanut Backgrounder, Outlook Report OCS-05i-01, Economic Research Service, United States Department of Agriculture, Washington, DC (October).

    Google Scholar 

  • Elam, T. (2008), Biofuel Support Policy Costs to the U.S. Economy, Report for the Coalition for Balanced Food and Fuel Policy, FarmEcon LLC, Carmel, IN (March).

    Google Scholar 

  • European Commission. (2003), Reform of the Common Agricultural Policy: A Long-Term Perspective for Sustainability Agriculture, Report of Directorate-General for Agriculture, European Commission, Brussels, Belgium.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gardner, B. (2000), Pre- and Post-FAIR Act Comparisons, Paper Presented at the Conference in Honor of Luther Tweeten, Ohio State University, Columbus, OH.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gardner, B. (2002a), North American Agricultural Policies and Effects on Western Hemisphere Markets Since 1995, with a Focus on Grains and Oilseeds, Working Paper WP-02–12, Department of Agricultural and Resource Economics, University of Maryland, College Park, Maryland.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gardner, B. (2002b), U.S. Agricultural Policies Since 1995, with a Focus on Market Effects in Grains and Oilseeds, Working Paper 02-17, Department of Agricultural and Resource Economics, University of Maryland, College Park, Maryland (December).

    Google Scholar 

  • Gardner, B. (2007), Fuel ethanol subsidies and farm price supports, Journal of Agricultural and Food Industrial Organization 5(2): 1–22.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gohin, A., Latuffe, L. (2006), The Luxembourg common agricultural policy and the European food industries: What’s at stake?, Canadian Journal of Agricultural Economics 24(1): 175–194.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Just, R., Calvin, L., Quiggin, J. (1999), Adverse selection in crop insurance, American Journal of Agricultural Economics 81(4): 834–849.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • OECD. (2004), Analysis of the 2003 CAP Reform, Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD), Paris, France.

    Google Scholar 

  • Orden, D. (2002), Alternative sugar policies for the United States, In A. Schmitz, T.H. Spreen, W.A. Messina, C.B. Moss (eds.), Sugar and Related Sweetener Markets International Perspectives, CABI Publishing, New York, NY, 315–328.

    Google Scholar 

  • Powell, S., Schmitz, A. (2005), The cotton and sugar subsidies decisions: WTO’s dispute settlement system rebalances the agreement on agriculture, Drake Journal of Agricultural Law 10(2): 287–330.

    Google Scholar 

  • Price, J.M. (2004), Effects of U.S. Dairy Policies on Markets for Milk and Dairy Products, USDA-ERS Technical Bulletin No. 1910, United States Department of Agriculture, Economic Research Service, Washington, DC (March).

    Google Scholar 

  • Rausser, G. (1982), Political economic markets: PERTs and PESTs in food and agriculture, American Journal of Agricultural Economics 64(5): 821–833.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rossi, F., Schmitz, A., Schmitz, T.G. (2005), The multiplicative effect of water subsidies and price support payments: The case of U.S. cotton, Journal of International Agricultural Trade Development 1(1): 55–70.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rude, J. (2008), Production effects of the European Union’s single farm payment, Canadian Journal of Agricultural Economics 56(4): 457–472.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schmitz, A. (2002), The European Union’s high-priced sugar-support regime, Chapter 15, In A. Schmitz, T.H. Spreen, W.A. Messina, C.B. Moss (eds.), Sugar and Related Sweetener Markets: International Perspectives, CABPI Publishing, Wallingford, UK, pp. 193–213.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schmitz, A., Furtan, H. (2000), The Canadian Wheat Board: Marketing in the New Millennium, Canadian Plains Research Center, Regina, Saskatchewan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schmitz, A., Gray, R. (2001), The divergence in Canada-U.S. grain and oilseed policies, Canadian Journal of Agricultural Economics 49: 459–478.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schmitz, A., Furtan, H., Baylis, K., eds. (2002), Agricultural Policy, Agribusiness, and Rent-Seeking Behaviour, University of Toronto Press, Toronto, ON.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schmitz, T.G., Giese, C.R., Shultz, II, C.J. (2008), Welfare implications of EU enlargement under the CAP, Canadian Journal of Agricultural Economics 56(4): 555–562.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schmitz, A., Moss, C.B., Schmitz, T.G. (2007), Ethanol: No free lunch, Journal of Agricultural and Food Industrial Organization 5(2): Article 3, http://www.bepress.com/jafio/vol5/iss2/art3. Accessed on July 2007.

  • Schmitz, A., Rossi, F., Schmitz, T.G. (2007a), Agricultural subsidies under decoupling, Research in Law and Economics: A Journal of Policy 23: 131–148.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schmitz, A., Rossi, F., Schmitz, T.G. (2007b), U.S. cotton subsidies: Drawing a fine line on the degree of decoupling, Journal of Agricultural and Applied Economics 39(1): 135–149.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schmitz, T., Schmitz, A., Dumas, C. (1997), Gains from trade, inefficiency of government programs and the net economic effects of trading, Journal of Political Economy 105(3): 637–647.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schmitz, A., Schmitz, T.G., Rossi, F. (2006), Agricultural subsidies in developed countries: Impact on global welfare, Review of Agricultural Economics 28(3): 416–425.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schmitz, T.G., Giese, C.R., Shultz, II, C.J. (2008), Welfare implications of EU enlargement under the CAP, Canadian Journal of Agricultural Economics 56(4): 555–562.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schmitz, A., Schmitz, T.G., Schure P. (2008), High Commodity Prices and the EU’s Single Payment Scheme: Some Consequences of Double Dipping, Candian Journal of Agricultural Economiec 56(4): 523–532.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sullivan, P., Hellerstein, D., Hansen, L., Johansson, R., Koenig, S., Lubowsky, R., Mcbride, W., Mcgranahan, D., Roberts, M., Vogel, S., Bucholtz, S. (2004), The Conservation Reserve Program: Economic Implications for Rural America, Agricultural Economic Report No. AER834, United States Department of Agriculture, Washington, DC.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sumner, D.A. (2007), U.S. Farm Policy and the White Commodities: Cotton, Rice, Sugar and Milk, IPC Policy Focus (Farm Bill Series No. 5, June), http://www.agritrade.org/Publications/PolicyFocus/Farm_Bill_5_white_commodities.pdf.

  • Sumner, D.A., Wolf, C.A. (1996), Quotas without supply control: Effects of dairy quota policy in California, American Journal of Agricultural Economics 78: 354–366.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Swinbank, A. (2008), Potential WTO challenges to the reformed CAP, Canadian Journal of Agricultural Economics 56(4): 445–456.

    Google Scholar 

  • Swinbank, A., Daugbjerg, C. (2006), The 2003 CAP reform: Accommodating WTO pressures, Comparative European Politics 4(1): 47–64.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Swinbank, A., Tanner, C. (1996), Farm Policy and Trade Conflict: The Uruguay Round and CAP Reform, The University of Michigan Press, Ann Arbor, MI.

    Google Scholar 

  • USDA. (2004), Economic Effects of U.S. Dairy Policy and Alternative Approaches to Milk Pricing, Report to Congress, United States Department of Agriculture, Washington, DC (July).

    Google Scholar 

  • Westcott, P.C., Price, J.M. (2001), Analysis of the U.S. Commodity Loan Program with Marketing Loan Provisions, AER 801, United States Department of Agriculture, Washington, DC.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Andrew Schmitz .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Appendices

Appendix 1: Ethanol and Market Distortions

Appendix 1, Fig. 3.10 depicts the US corn market where S is the supply schedule and D T is total demand. Given the loan rate under the 2002 Farm Security and Rural Investment (FSRI) Act of 2002, farmers receive a price of p LR for each bushel of corn produced, yielding a total production of q s bushels. Given a domestic demand curve D d and an export demand curve of D e, the total demand curve is D T. These demand curves result in a market clearing price of p 0. With this market clearing price, q d is consumed domestically and q e is exported. At this equilibrium, the loan deficiency payments paid to farmers based on the level of production is represented by the area p LR abp 0. In addition, farmers receive a countercyclical payment based on their historical level of production (q k, typically 85% of historical yields) and the target price (p TP). Graphically, this payment is depicted by the area p TP cdp LR. The net cost of the subsidy program from the US perspective is aefgb, of which efgb is a gain to importers (the “slippage” effect).

Fig. 3.10
figure 10

Ethanol effects: direct and indirect subsidies

In this original equilibrium, we assume that the market clearing price (p 0) is less than the choke price for the derived demand curve for corn used to produce ethanol (D ET). Thus, given the total demand curve of D T + D ET, no ethanol is produced. Next, we assume that increases in the price of gasoline shift the derived demand for corn used to produce ethanol outward to D ETʹ. This changes the shape of the total demand curve to D T + D ETʹ. This rightward shift in the derived demand for corn from ethanol producers is sufficient to raise the equilibrium price of corn to the loan rate, eliminating the loan deficiency payments to farmers. Thus, there are no direct subsidies based on production, but there are indirect subsidies to corn producers via ethanol tax credits.

Consider further the demand for corn derived from ethanol production. Starting from D ETʹ (which assumes a fixed oil price), a sufficiently large increase in corn prices (above p 2) chokes off the demand for corn to produce ethanol. This point represents the corner solution in Appendix 1, Fig. 3.10. However, if one assumes an increase in oil prices for a given price of corn, the derived demand curve for corn shifts to the right. It is important to note that from a theoretical perspective, the demand for corn for ethanol production could be positive without a tax credit, which is discussed later. At least two factors affect ethanol production, namely, the favorable oil to corn price ratio and a tax credit for ethanol production.

In the first case, we assume that producers are not impacted by ethanol demand even though corn prices rise. This is because the loan deficiency payments no longer exist (and the countercyclical payments remain unchanged). Also, an important result is derived from the observation that market clearing prices rise from p 0 to p LR, causing both domestic and export demand to fall for those components making up demand D T. (The demand for corn for ethanol is q sq sʹ.) Domestic consumers now pay a higher price for corn and related products, given demand D d. Likewise, foreign importers pay a higher price for the corn they import.

The market for corn-given demand D T + D ETʹ might look like a “free market” except for the subsidies provided to the ethanol sector. From a distributional standpoint, (1) producers are unaffected from ethanol demand, (2) domestic consumers lose p LR hgp 0, (3) foreign importers lose hibg, (4) the government saves loan deficiency payments p TP cdp LR, (5) the consumers of ethanol gain jia, and (6) there are government cuts from the indirect subsidy on ethanol production.

To calculate the “net effect” of ethanol, one needs to consider (1) the net welfare gain of aefgb, (2) the consumer gain from the introduction of ethanol of jia, and (3) the cost of the indirect ethanol subsidy. The first two components are positive, while the last one is negative. Ethanol subsidies replace direct subsidies. The price impact due to ethanol affects consumers. The direct effect from ethanol is a rise in the price of corn. Production costs are now covered so direct subsidies are no longer binding.

To further show the interrelationship between ethanol production and government payments to corn farmers, we assume that the derived demand for corn used to produce ethanol shifts farther outward to D T it. This increased derived demand causes the total demand for corn to shift outward to D T + D ET it, increasing the market equilibrium price to p 1 and the equilibrium quantity to q t. Comparing this equilibrium with the equilibrium at the loan rate, producers gain p 1 lap LR. However, part of this gain (p 1 kdp LR) is offset by reductions in the countercyclical payments to farmers. Thus, the net producer gain is kdal. This shift results in an economic loss to domestic consumers of p 1 mhp LR and a loss to foreign consumers of mndh. Completing the model, the economic gain for ethanol producers is the area onl.

If the demand for ethanol shifts even farther to the right than D ET it, all government payments (including countercyclical payments) are eliminated. Thus, there a direct linkage between tax credit to ethanol and farm program payments.

Appendix 2: Coupled Versus Decoupled Subsidies: The Case of Cotton

In the following theoretical discussion, we emphasize that the price impact of US cotton policy critically depends on the choice of which cotton price to use in the analysis, since the positioning of the supply and demand structure is dependent on the particular price. In Appendix 2, Fig. 3.11, S is the US supply curve under a coupled framework, while S' is the US supply curve under a coupled framework that includes water subsidies. Likewise, S 0 is the supply curve under decoupling and S'0 is the supply curve under decoupling that includes water subsidies. Domestic demand is D d, and total demand is D D. Given a specific domestic supply–price elasticity and production point q*, one can either use the target price P s to derive the intercept and slope of the subsidized supply curve (that leads to the coupled subsidized supply curve S') or the loan rate P l to derive the decoupled supply curve S 0 (and the decoupled subsidized supply curve S'0). Under the decoupled model, the subsidized supply curve changes from S' to S'0 by shifting downward and rotating clockwise. Essentially, the initial free-trade equilibrium price P f, derived from the intersection of the coupled unsubsidized supply curve S and the total demand curve T D, moves downward along the total demand curve to establish a smaller decoupled free-trade price P f' and free-trade quantity q. Schmitz et al. (2006) perform sensitivity analyses for the coupled model by rotating the coupled subsidized supply curve S 0 around point o in Appendix 2, Fig. 3.11, using different elasticities. They also perform sensitivity analyses for the decoupled model by rotating the decoupled subsidized supply curve S'0 around point z using different elasticities.

Fig. 3.11
figure 11

A decoupled policy

Appendix 3: US and EU Producer Supports

Fig. 3.12
figure 12

US producer supports: 1990–2004 (US$ millions). Source: OECD (2005)

Fig. 3.13
figure 13

EU producer supports: 1990–2004 (ECU million). Source: OECD (2005)

Appendix 4: National Ceilings

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2010 Springer Science+Business Media, LLC

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Schmitz, A., Schmitz, T.G. (2010). US and EU Agricultural Policy: Divergence or Convergence?. In: Ball, V., Fanfani, R., Gutierrez, L. (eds) The Economic Impact of Public Support to Agriculture. Studies in Productivity and Efficiency, vol 7. Springer, New York, NY. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-1-4419-6385-7_3

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics