Skip to main content

Intercultural Economic Influences

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
  • 479 Accesses

Abstract

Given the markedly differing attitudes as well as cultural values between different cultural groups of people, the adoption of a common standard is unlikely to prove effective. However “cultural dissimilarity” may also generate “economic complementarities” that will in turn exert positive influences on foreign trade. As a result the final output of the cultural influences should be nonlinear, subjected to various conditions concerned. In this chapter, cultural influences on international trade are found to be more significant for the post-Cold War era than in the Cold War era. Our empirical results also provide evidence supporting the presumption that high-income trade partners will be less sensitive to the measures of cultural dissimilarity than low-income trade partners between which cultural dissimilarity leads to barriers to international trade. The treatment of linguistic and religious factors as continuous variables in this chapter has improved past studies in which “language” was treated as one or more dummy variables and “religion” was ignored.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution.

Buying options

Chapter
USD   29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD   84.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD   109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD   109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Learn about institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    Linnemann (1966) and Frankel et al. (1997a) have estimated the effects of both GDP and GNP on trade, but no significant difference is found.

  2. 2.

    For example, Linnemann (1966) puts the estimated coefficient as −0.77, Brada and Mendez (1983) and Oguledo and MacPhee (1994) as 0.76, Bikker (1987) as −0.90 to −1.1, Mansfield and Bronson (1997) as −0.51 to −0.69 (for 1950–90), and Rauch (1999) as −0.62 to −0.70 (1970–90).

  3. 3.

    See, for example, Leontief (1956), Kravis (1956a, 1956b) Keesing (1966), Kenen (1965), Baldwin (1971), Branson and Monoyios (1977), Leamer (1980, 1984, 1993), Stern and Maskus (1981), Bowen, Leamer and Sveikauskas (1987), and Salvatore and Barazesh (1990).

  4. 4.

    Frankel et al. (1997a, p. 58). Of the many relevant works, some of the more important are Grossman and Helpman (1989, 1991), Rivera-Batiz and Romer (1991) and, for further references on the connections between trade and growth, Frankel et al. (1995).

  5. 5.

    Selected literature on the intraindustry trade can be found in Grubel and Lloyd (1975), Krugman (1980), Lancaster (1980), Greenaway and Milner (1986), Vona (1990), and Leamer (1993).

  6. 6.

    We define “intercultural trade” as “trade between countries or regions differing in one or more cultural elements.” However, since no countries have exactly same cultural elements, “intercultural trade” and “international trade” are not different from each other.

  7. 7.

    Data source: IMF (various issues).

  8. 8.

    As a matter of fact, a negative coefficient on per capita GDP sometimes may be found in gravity model on trade for homogeneous products if they are more agricultural and rich countries tend to have managed trade in agricultural products.

  9. 9.

    The application of the gravity model in regional science and economic geography can be traced back to as far as the 1940s (see, for example, Zipf 1946; Stewart 1948; Isard 1949).

  10. 10.

    Note that if there are a significant number of zero values in the pair-wise trade, then Tobit regressions techniques should be used. However, in this research, the number of country-pairs identified by “TRADE = 0” (that is, there is no trade for a country pair) is quite small.

  11. 11.

    In fact, there still exist some amount of “illegal” (or unofficial) trade for those economies that are officially reporting no bilateral trade flows.

  12. 12.

    For example, Frankel et al. (1997a, p. 56) use Chicago for the major city of the United States rather than Washington, DC, and Shanghai for the major city of China rather than Beijing.

  13. 13.

    Technically, the data of more years should be considered to represent each period. But this would increase the difficulties in the collection and calculation of cultural data.

  14. 14.

    Of course, one can also include more countries. But this would increase the work of data processing significantly.

  15. 15.

    In the Britannica Book (1996), atheism and nonreligion were each treated as a “religious affiliation” in USA and China, but in other countries such as Austria, Czech Republic, North Korea, etc., they were grouped as a single religious group.

  16. 16.

    Among the past literature (see, for example, Linnemann 1966; Brada and Mendez 1983; Oguledo and MacPhee 1994; Bikker 1987; and Mansfield and Bronson 1995) relating to the determinants of international trade (in logarithmic form), the statistically significant coefficients on the log of distance have ranged between −0.51 and −1.50, which demonstrate the decreases (in percentage) in international trade as a result of a 1.0% increase in distance. Specifically, Linnemann (1966) estimates the coefficient as −0.77, Brada and Mendez (1983) and Oguledo and MacPhee (1994) as −0.76, Bikker (1987) as −0.90 to −1.1, and Mansfield and Bronson (1997) as −0.51 to −0.69 (for 1950–1990).

  17. 17.

    Such as the mountains of Altai with Russia and Mongolia, Tian-Shan with Kazakhstan and Kyrgyzstan, and Himalayas with Bhutan, India, and Nepal, and so on.

  18. 18.

    The three breakpoint values are obtained by letting the first-order differentials of the dependent variables (ln(TRADE ij + 1), ln(EXPORT ij + 1) and ln(IMPORT ij + 1)) with respect to RELIGION be zero, respectively.

  19. 19.

    For example, Linder (1961) predicts that countries with similar levels of per capita income will tend to have similar preferences with somewhat differentiated marketable goods and thus will trade more with each other.

  20. 20.

    Before deriving its first-order partial differential with respective to ln(GNPPC j ), the variable ln(GNP i GNP j ) can be decomposed into ln(POP i POP j ) + ln(GNPPC i ) + ln(GNPPC j ), where POP i and POP j are the sizes of population of the ith and jth countries, respectively.

References

  • Baldwin RE (1971) Determinants of the commodity structure of US trade. Am Econ Rev 61:126–146

    Google Scholar 

  • Bikker J (1987) An international trade flow model with substitution: an extension of the gravity model. Kyklos 40:315–337

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boisso D, Ferrantino M (1997) Economic distance, cultural distance and openness in international trade: empirical puzzles. J Econ Intgr 12:456–484

    Google Scholar 

  • Brada J, Mendez J (1983) Regional economic integration and the volume of intra-regional trade: a comparison of developed and developing country experience. Kyklos 36:589–603

    Google Scholar 

  • Branson WH, Monoyios N (1977) Factor inputs in US trade. J Int Econ 20:111–131

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Deardorff A (1998) Determinants of bilateral trade: does gravity work in a classical world? In: Frankel JA (ed) The regionalization of the world economy. University of Chicago Press, Chicago, pp 213–243

    Google Scholar 

  • Eichengreen B, Irwin D (1995) Trade blocs, currency blocs and the reorientation of trade in the 1930s. J Int Econ 38(2):89–106

    Google Scholar 

  • Foroutan F, Pritchett L (1993) Intra-Sub-Saharan African trade: is it too little? J Afr Econ 2:74–105

    Google Scholar 

  • Frankel JA, Romer D (1996) Trade and growth. NBER Working Paper No. 5476. National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA

    Google Scholar 

  • Frankel JA, Wei S-J (1995) European integration and the regionalization of world trade and currencies: the economics and the politics. In: Eichengreen B, Frieden F, von Hagen J (eds) Monetary and fiscal policy in an integrated Europe. Springer, New York, pp 89–123

    Google Scholar 

  • Frankel JA, Romer D, Cyrus T (1995) Trade and growth in East Asian countries: Cause and effect? Pacific Basin Working Paper Series No. 95-03, Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco, San Francisco

    Google Scholar 

  • Frankel JA, Stein E, Wei S-J (1997a) Regional trading blocs in the world economic system. Institute for International Economics, Washington, DC

    Google Scholar 

  • Frankel JA, Stein E, Wei S-J (1997b) Trading blocs and the americas: the natural, the unnatural, and the super-natural. J Dev Econ 47(1):61–95

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Greenaway D, Milner CR (1986) The economics of intra-industry trade. Basil Blackwell, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Greenstein M, Feinman TM (2000) Electronic commerce: security, risk management. McGraw-Hill/China Machine Press, Beijing

    Google Scholar 

  • Grossman G, Helpman E (1989) Product development and international trade. J Polit Econ 97:1261–1283

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grossman G, Helpman E (1991) Innovation and growth in the world economy. The MIT Press, Cambridge, MA

    Google Scholar 

  • Grubel HG, Lloyd PJ (1975) Intra-industry trade: the theory and measurement of international trade in differentiated products. Macmillan Press, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Guo R (2004) How culture influences foreign trade–evidence from the US and China. J Socio-Econ 33(6):785–812

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Guo R (2006) Cultural influences on economic analysis—theory and empirical evidence. Palgrave-Macmillan, New York

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Havrylyshyn O, Pritchett L (1991) European trade patterns after the transition. Policy, Research and External Affairs Working Paper Series No. 74, World Bank, Washington, DC

    Google Scholar 

  • Heckscher EF (1919) The effect of foreign trade on the distribution of income. Ekonomisk Tidskirift, 497–512. Reprinted in Ellis HS, Metzler LM (eds) Readings in the theory of international trade. Irwin, Homewood, IL, pp 272–300

    Google Scholar 

  • Helpman E (1987) Imperfect competition and international trade: evidence from fourteen industrial countries. J Jpn Int Econ 1:62–81

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Huntington SP (1996) The clash of civilization and the remaking of world order. Simon & Schuster, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Isard W (1949) Gravity, potential, and spatial interaction models. Reprinted in Smith C (ed) (1990) Practical methods of regional science and empirical applications: selected papers of Walter Isard, vol 2. New York University Press, New Work, pp 1–23

    Google Scholar 

  • Keesing DB (1966) Labor skills and comparative advantage. Am Econ Rev 56:249–258

    Google Scholar 

  • Kenen P (1965) Nature, capital and trade. J Polit Econ 73:437–460

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kravis IB (1956a) Wages and foreign trade. Rev Econ Stat 38:14–30

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kravis IB (1956b) Availability and other influences on the commodity composition of trade. J Polit Econ 73:143–155

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krugman PR (1980) Scale economies, product differentiation, and the pattern of trade. Am Econ Rev 70:950–959

    Google Scholar 

  • Krugman PR (1995) Growing world trade: causes and consequences. Brookings Pap Econ Act 1:327–362

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lancaster K (1980) Intra-industry trade under perfect monopolistic competition. J Int Econ 23:151–175

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leamer EE (1980) The Leontef paradox reconsidered. J Polit Econ 88:495–503

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leamer EE (1984) Sources for international comparative advantage. The MIT Press, Cambridge, MA

    Google Scholar 

  • Leamer EE (1993) Factor–supply differences as a source of comparative advantage. Am Econ Rev 83:436–444

    Google Scholar 

  • Leontief W (1954) Domestic production and foreign trade: the American capital position re-examined. Economia Internationale, Feb., 2–32. Reprinted in Bhagwati JH (ed) (1969) International trade: selected readings. Baltimore: Penguin, pp 3–16.

    Google Scholar 

  • Leontief W (1956) Factor proportions and the structure of American trade; Further theoretical and empirical analysis. Rev Econ Stat 38:386–407

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Linder SB (1961) An essay on trade and transformation. John Wiley and sons, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Linnemann H (1966) An econometric study of international trade theory. North-Holland, Amsterdam

    Google Scholar 

  • Mansfield E, Bronson R (1997) The political economy of major-power trade flows. In: Mansfield E, Milner H (eds) The political economy of regionalism. Columbia University Press, New York, pp 213–256

    Google Scholar 

  • Markusen J (1986) Explaining the volume of trade: an eclectic approach. Am Econ Rev 76:1002–1011

    Google Scholar 

  • Noland M (2005) Affinity and international trade. Working Paper Series No. WP 05-3, June, Institute for International Economics, Washington DC

    Google Scholar 

  • Oguledo V, MacPhee C (1994) Gravity models: a reformulation and an application to discriminatory trade arrangement. Appl Econ 26:107–120

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ohlin B (1933) Interregional and international trade. Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MA

    Google Scholar 

  • Pöyhönen P (1963) A tentative model for the volume of trade between countries. Weltwirtsch Arch 90(1):93–99

    Google Scholar 

  • Rauch JE (1999) Networks versus markets in international trade. J Int Econ 48:7–35

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rauch JE, Trindade V (2002) Ethnic Chinese networks in international trade. Rev Econ Stat 84(1):116–130

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rivera-Batiz L, Romer P (1991) International trade and endogenous growth. Q J Econ 106:531–555

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rose A (2004) Do we really know that the WTO increases trade? Am Econ Rev 94:98–114

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Salvatore D (1995) International economics, 5th edn. Prentice Hall, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Salvatore D, Barazesh R (1990) The factor content of US foreign trade and the Heckscher-Ohlin theory. Int Trade J 16:149–181

    Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson PA (1948) International trade and the equalization of factor prices. Econ J 58:165–184

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson PA (1949) International factor-price equalization once again. The Economic Journal, vol 59, 181–197. Reprinted in Bhagwati JN (ed) (1981) International trade: selected readings. The MIT Press, Cambridge, MA, pp 93–139

    Google Scholar 

  • Shanker R (1996) Culture and development. Development Express, no. 8, International Development Information Center, Hull, Québec

    Google Scholar 

  • Stern RM, Maskus KE (1981) Determinants of the structure of US foreign trade. J Int Econ 24:207–224

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stewart JQ (1948) Demographic gravitation: evidence and applications. Sociometry 2:31–58

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tinbergen J (1962) An analysis of world trade flows, the Linder hypothesis, and exchange risk. In: Tinbergen J (ed) Shaping the world economy. The Twentieth Century Fund, New York, pp 20–42

    Google Scholar 

  • United Nations (1986) Annual statistical yearbook. UN, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Vona S (1990) Intra-industry trade: a statistical prefect or a real phenomenon? Banca Naz. Lavoro Quarterly Review, 487–497

    Google Scholar 

  • Wilson EA (1980) Sociobiology. Belknap, Cambridge, MA

    Google Scholar 

  • World Atlas. (1994) Rand McNally & Company, USA

    Google Scholar 

  • World Bank (1991) World bank atlas. The World Bank, Washington DC

    Google Scholar 

  • World Bank (2001) World development indicators. The World Bank, Washington DC

    Google Scholar 

  • World Commission on Culture and Development (WCCD) (1995) Our creative diversity. United Nations’s Science, Education and Culture Organization (UNSECO), Paris

    Google Scholar 

  • Zipf GK (1946) The P1P2/D hypothesis: on the intercity movement of persons. Am Sociol Rev 11(6):677–686

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Rongxing Guo .

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2009 Springer Science+Business Media, LLC

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Guo, R. (2009). Intercultural Economic Influences. In: Intercultural Economic Analysis. Springer, New York, NY. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-1-4419-0849-0_4

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics