Skip to main content

Interest Group Behavior and Influence

  • Chapter
The Encyclopedia of Public Choice

Abstract

During the last two decades economics has witnessed a remarkable upsurge in theoretical as well as empirical studies of the behavior and political influence of interest groups. Recent books by Sloof (1998), Drazen (2000), Persson and Tabellini (2000), and Grossman and Helpman (2001) refer to a wealth of evidence of the significance of organized interests in the political arena, besides presenting surveys of theoretical studies. Political economics definitively seems to move away from the common assumption of atomistic demand in ‘political markets’ (the median voter model) towards a more realistic framework. In a sense it is picking up and deepening some older strands of literature inspired by classical writers on political economy (like Marx and Pareto), the so-called pluralists in political science (like Bentley and Truman), and others, who were concerned with the political impact of particular social groups under the label of ‘factions’, ‘classes’, or ‘elites’ (see e.g., Bottomore, 1970; Moe 1980). The modern political economic literature to be surveyed in this paper, however, is characterized by much greater rigor, through the use mathematical modeling, and keener attention for individual incentives.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 429.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 549.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 549.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

References

  • Abelson, R.P., Kinder, D.R., Peters, M.D., and Fiske, S.T. (1982). “Affective and semantic components in political person perception.” Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 42: 619–630.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aidt, T. (1998). “Political internalization of economic externalities and environmental policy.” Journal of Public Economics, 69: 1–16.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ainsworth, S. (1993). “Regulating lobbyists and interest group influence.” The Journal of Politics, 55: 41–56.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ainsworth, S. and Sened, I. (1993). “The role of lobbyists: entrepreneurs with two audiences.” American Journal of Political Science, 37: 834–866.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aumann, R. and Kurz, M. (1977). “Power and taxes.” Econometrica, 45: 1137–1161.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aumann, R. and Kurz, M., and Neyman, A. (1983). “Voting for public goods.” Review of Economic Studies, 50: 677–693.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Austen-Smith, D. (1987). “Interest groups, campaign contributions, and probabilistic voting.” Public Choice, 54: 123–139.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Austen-Smith, D. (1993). “Information and influence: lobbying for agendas and votes.” American Journal of Political Science, 37: 799–833.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Austen-Smith, D. (1994). “Strategic transmission of costly information.” Econometrica, 62: 955–963.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Austen-Smith, D. (1995). “Campaign contributions and access.” American Political Science Review, 89: 566–581.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Austen-Smith, D. (1997). “Interest groups: money, information and influence,” in D.C. Mueller (ed.) Perspectives on Public Choice. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Austen-Smith, D. and Banks, J.S. (2002). “Costly signaling and cheap talk in models of political influence.” European Journal of Political Economy, 18: 263–280.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Austen-Smith, D. and Wright, J.R. (1992). “Competitive lobbying for a legislator’s vote.” Social Choice and Welfare, 9: 229–257.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Banks, J.S. and Weingast, B.R. (1992). “The political control of bureaucracies under asymmetric information.” American Journal of Political Science, 36: 509–524.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baron, D. (1989). “Service-induced campaign contributions and the electoral equilibrium.” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 104: 45–72.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Battaglini, M. (2002). “Multiple referrals and multidimensional cheap talk.” Econometrica, 70: 1379–1401.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker, G. (1983). “A theory of competition among pressure groups for political influence.” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 98: 371–400.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bennedsen, M. and Feldmann, S.E. (2000). “Lobbying legislatures,” mimeo.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bennedsen, M. and Feldmann, S.E. (2001). “Informational lobbying and political contributions,” mimeo.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bennedsen, M. and Feldmann, S.E. (2002). “Lobbying and legislative organization, the effect of the vote of confidence procedure,” mimeo.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bergemann, D. and Välimäki, J. (1998). “Dynamic common agency.” Cowles Foundation Working Paper, Yale University.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bernheim, B.D. and Whinston, M.D. (1986). “Menu auctions, resource allocation, and economic influence.” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 101: 1–31.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Besley, T. and Coate, S. (1997). “An economic model of representative democracy.” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 112: 85–114.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Besley, T. and Coate, S. (2001). “Lobbying and welfare in a representative democracy.” Review of Economic Studies, 68: 67–82.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Borooah, V. and van der Ploeg, F. (1983). Political Aspects of the Economy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bosman, R. and van Winden, F. (2002). “Emotional hazard in a power-to-take experiment.” The Economic Journal, 112: 147–169.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bottomore, T.B. (1970). Elites and Society. Harmondsworth: Penguin Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brock, W. and Magee, S. (1980). “Tariff formation in a democracy.” in J. Black and B. Hindley (eds.) Current Issues in Commercial Policy and Diplomacy. London: MacMillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cairns, R. (1989). “Dynamic rent-seeking.” Journal of Public Economics, 39: 315–334.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cameron, C.M. and Jung, J.P. (1992). “Strategic endorsements,” mimeo, New York: Columbia University.

    Google Scholar 

  • Coate, S. (2001). “Political competition with campaign contributions and informative advertising.” Working Paper 8693, NBER, Cambridge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Coggins, J., Graham-Tomasi, T., and Roe, T. (1991). “Existence of equilibrium in a lobbying economy.” International Economic Review, 32: 533–550.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coughlin, P. (1992). Probabilistic Voting Theory. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Coughlin, P., and Mueller, D., and Murrell, P. (1990). “Electoral politics, interest groups, and the size of government.” Economic Inquiry, 29: 682–705.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Crawford, V. and Sobel, J. (1982). “Strategic information transmission.” Econometrica, 50: 1431–1451.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Denzau, A. and Munger, M. (1986). “Legislators and interest groups: how unorganized interests get represented.” American Political Science Review, 80: 89–106.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dharmapala, D. (1999a). “Comparing tax expenditures and direct subsidies: the role of legislative committee structure.” Journal of Public Economics, 72: 421–454.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dharmapala, D. (1999b). Legislative bargaining and vote buying under the influence of lobbying, mimeo, Cambridge: Harvard University.

    Google Scholar 

  • van Dijk, F. and van Winden, F. (1997). “Dynamics of social ties and public good provision.” Journal of Public Economics, 323–341.

    Google Scholar 

  • van Dijk, F., and Sonnemans, J., and van Winden, F. (2002). “Social ties in a public good experiment.” Journal of Public Economics, 85: 275–299.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dixit, A., Grossman, G.M., and Helpman, E. (1997). “Common agency and coordination: General theory and application to government policy making.” Journal of Political Economy, 105: 752–769.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dougan, W.R. and Snyder, J.M. Jr. (1996). “Interest-group politics under majority rule.” Journal of Public Economics, 61: 49–71.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Drazen, A. (2000). Political Economy in Macroeconomics. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Drissen, E. (1999). Government Decisions on Income Redistribution and Public Production. Amsterdam: Thela Thesis.

    Google Scholar 

  • Edelman, S. (1992). “Two politicians, a PAC, and how they interact: two extensive form games.” Economics and Politics, 4: 289–305.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Epstein, D. and O’Halloran, S. (1995). “A theory of strategic oversight: congress, lobbyists, and the bureaucracy.” Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 11: 227–255.

    Google Scholar 

  • Esteban, J. and Ray, D. (2000). “Wealth constraints, lobbying and the efficiency of public allocation.” European Economic Review. 44: 694–705.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fafchamps, M., De Janvry, A., and Sadoulet, E. (1999). “Social heterogeneity and wasteful lobbying.” Public Choice, 98: 5–27.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ferejohn, J.A. and Fiorina, M.P. (1974). “The paradox of not voting: a decision theoretic analysis.” American Political Science Review, 68: 525–536.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Findlay, R. and Wellisz, S. (1983). “Some aspects of the political economy of trade restrictions.” Kyklos. 36: 469–481.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gardner, R. (1981). “Wealth and power in a collegial polity.” Journal of Economic Theory, 25: 353–366.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grossman, G.M. and Helpman, E. (1994). “Protection for sale.” American Economic Review, 84: 833–850.

    Google Scholar 

  • Grossman, G.M. and Helpman, E. (1995). “Trade wars and trade talks.” Journal of Political Economy, 103: 675–708.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grossman, G.M. and Helpman, E. (1996). “Electoral competition and special interest politics.” Review of Economic Studies, 63: 265–286.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grossman, G.M. and Helpman, E. (1998). “Intergenerational redistribution with short-lived governments.” The Economic Journal, 108: 1299–1329.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grossman, G.M. and Helpman, E. (1999). “Competing for endorsements.” American Economic Review, 89: 501–524.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grossman, G.M. and Helpman, E. (2001). Special Interest Politics. Cambridge: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Harrington, J.E. (1993). “The impact of reelection pressures on the fulfilment of campaign promises.” Games and Economic Behavior, 5: 71–97.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Harsanyi, J. (1962). “Measurement of social power, opportunity costs, and the theory of two-person bargaining games.” Behavioral Science, 7: 67–80.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hettich, W. and Winer, S.L. (1999). Democratic Choice and Taxation. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hillman, A. (1989). The Political Economy of Protection. Chur: Harwood.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hillman, A. and Ursprung, H. (1988). “Domestic politics, foreign interests, and international trade policy.” American Economic Review, 78: 729–745.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hirshleifer, J. (1976). “Comment (on: Peltzman 1976).” Journal of Law and Economics, 19: 240–244.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hojnacki, M. and Kimball, D.C. (1998). “Organized interests and the decision of whom to lobby in Congress.” American Political Science Review, 92: 775–790.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hoyt, W.H. and Toma, E.F. (1989). “State mandates and interest group lobbying.” Journal of Public Economics, 38: 199–213.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Johnson, P.E. (1996). “Corporate political offices in a rent-seeking society.” Public Choice, 88: 309–331.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kagel, J.H. and Roth, A.E. (eds.) (1995). The Handbook of Experimental Economics. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kirchsteiger, G. and Prat, A. (2001). “Inefficient equilibria in lobbying.” Journal of Public Economics, 82: 349–375.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kollman, K. (1997). “Inviting friends to lobby: interest groups, ideological bias, and congressional committees.” American Journal of Political Science, 41: 519–544.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Laffont, J. and Tirole, J. (1991). “The politics of government decisionmaking: a theory of regulatory capture.” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 106: 1089–1127.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lagerlöf, J. (1997). “Lobbying, information, and private and social welfare.” European Journal of Political Economy, 13: 615–637.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lohmann, S. (1995). “Information, access, and contributions: a signaling model of lobbying.” Public Choice, 85: 267–284.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lohmann, S. (1998). “An informational rationale for the power of special interests.” American Political Science Review, 92: 809–827.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Marceau, N. and Smart, M. (2002). “Corporate lobbying and commitment failure in capital taxation.” CESifo Working Paper No. 676.

    Google Scholar 

  • Marcus, G.E. and Mackuen, M.B. (1993). “Anxiety, enthusiasm, and the vote: the emotional underpinnings of learning and involvement during presidential campaigns.” American Political Science Review, 87: 672–685.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mazza, I. and van Winden, F. (1996). “A political economic analysis of labor migration and income redistribution.” Public Choice, 88: 333–363.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mazza, I. and van Winden, F. (2000). “An endogenous policy model of hierarchical government.” CREED Working Paper, University of Amsterdam.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mazza, I. and van Winden, F. (2002a). “Does centralization increase the size of government? The effects of separation of powers and lobbying.” International Tax and Public Finance, 9: 379–389.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mazza, I. and van Winden, F. (2002b). “Delegation of lobbying to a policymaker.” CREED Working Paper (in preparation), University of Amsterdam.

    Google Scholar 

  • Milner, H.V. and Rosendorff, B.P. (1996). “Trade negotiations, information, and domestic politics: the role of domestic groups.” Economics and Politics, 8: 145–189.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mitchell, W.C. and Munger, M.C. (1991). “Economic models of interest groups: an introductory survey.” American Journal of Political Science, 35: 512–546.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Moe, T.M. (1980). The Organization of Interests. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Moore, M.O. and Suranovic, S.M. (1992). “Lobbying vs. administered protection.” Journal of International Economics, 32: 289–303.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Morton, R. and Cameron, C. (1992). “Elections and the theory of campaign contributions: a survey and critical analysis.” Economics and Politics, 4: 79–108.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Neary, H.M. (1997). “A comparison of rent-seeking models and economic models of conflict.” Public Choice, 93: 373–388.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nitzan, S. (1994). “Modelling rent-seeking contests.” European Journal of Political Economy, 10: 41–60.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Olson, M. (1965). The Logic of Collective Action. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ortoni, A., Clore, G.L., and Collins, A. (1988). The Cognitive Structure of Emotions. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Osborne, M.J. (1984). “Why do some goods bear higher taxes than others?” Journal of Economic Theory, 32: 111–127.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Osborne, M.J. and Slivinski, A. (1996). “A model of political competition with citizen candidates.” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 111: 65–96.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Peck, R. (1986). “Power and linear income taxes: an example.” Econometrica, 54: 87–94.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pedersen, K.R. (1995). “Rent-seeking, political influence and inequality: a simple analytical example.” Public Choice, 82: 281–305.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pelzman, S. (1976). “Toward a more general theory of regulation.” Journal of Law and Economics, 19: 211–240.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Persson, T. (1998). “Economic policy and special interest policy.” The Economic Journal, 108: 310–327.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Persson, T. and Tabellini, G. (1994). “Does centralization increase the size of government?” European Economic Review, 38: 765–773.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Persson, T. and Tabellini, G. (2000). Political Economics. Cambridge: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Potters, J. (1992). “Lobbying and pressure.” Tinbergen Institute Research Series No. 36, Amsterdam.

    Google Scholar 

  • Potters, J. and Sloof, R. (1996). “Interest groups. A survey of empirical models that try to assess their influence.” European Journal of Political Economy, 12: 403–442.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Potters, J., and Sloof, R., and van Winden, F. (1997). “Campaign expenditures, contributions and direct endorsements: the strategic use of information and money to influence voter behavior.” European Journal of Political Economy, 13: 1–31.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Potters, J., and van Winden, F. (1990). “Modelling political pressure as transmission of information.” European Journal of Political Economy, 6: 61–88.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Potters, J. and van Winden, F. (1992). “Lobbying and asymmetric information.” Public Choice, 74: 269–292.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Potters, J. and van Winden, F. (1996). “Models of interest groups: four different approaches,” in N. Schofield (ed.) Collective Decision-Making, Social Choice and Political Economy. Boston: Kluwer, pp. 337–362.

    Google Scholar 

  • Prat, A. (2000a). “Campaign spending with office-seeking politicians, rational voters, and multiple lobbies.” Journal of Economic Theory.

    Google Scholar 

  • Prat, A. (2000b). “An economic analysis of campaign finance.” World Economics, 1: 13–28.

    Google Scholar 

  • Prat, A. (2001). “Campaign advertising and voter welfare.” Review of Economic Studies.

    Google Scholar 

  • Prat, A., and Rustichini, A. (1998). “Sequential common agency.” Discussion Paper No. (9895). CentER, Tilburg University.

    Google Scholar 

  • Prat, A. and Rustichini, A. (1999). “Games played through agents.” Discussion Paper No. (9968). CentER, Tilburg University.

    Google Scholar 

  • Przeworski, A. and Wallerstein, M. (1988). “Structural dependence of the state on capital.” American Political Science Review, 82: 1–29.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rama, M. and Tabellini, G. (1998). “Lobbying by capital and labor over trade and labor market policies.” European Economic Review, 42: 1295–1316.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rasmusen, E. (1993). “Lobbying when the decisionmaker can acquire independent information.” Public Choice, 77: 899–913.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Renaud, P.S.A. (1989). Applied Political Economic Modelling. Heidelberg: Springer Verlag.

    Google Scholar 

  • Renaud, P. and van Winden, F. (1988). “Fiscal behaviour and the growth of government in the Netherlands,” in J. Lybeck and M. Henrekson (eds.) Explaining the Growth of Government. Amsterdam: North Holland, pp. 133–156.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rothenberg, L.S. (1988). “Organizational maintenance and the retention decision in groups.” American Political Science Review, 82: 1129–1152.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sadiraj, V., Tuinstra, J., and van Winden, F. (2001). “A dynamic model of endogenous interest group sizes and policymaking.” CREED/CENDEF Working Paper, University of Amsterdam.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sadiraj, V., Tuinstra, J., and van Winden, F. (2002). “Interest groups and social dynamics in a model of spatial competition.” CREED/CENDEF Working Paper, University of Amsterdam.

    Google Scholar 

  • Saint-Paul, G. (2000). “The new political economy: recent books by Allan Drazen and Torsten Persson and Guido Tabellini.” Journal of Economic Literature, 38: 915–925.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sloof, R. (1998). Game-Theoretic Models of the Political Influence of Interest Groups. Boston: Kluwer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sloof, R. (1999). “Campaign contributions and the desirability of full disclosure laws.” Economics and Politics, 11: 83–107.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sloof, R. (2000). “Interest group lobbying and the delegation of policy authority.” Economics and Politics, 12: 247–274.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sloof, R., and van Winden, F. (2000). “Show them your teeth first!” Public Choice, 104: 81–120.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Spiller, P.T. (1990). “Politicians, interest groups, and regulators: a multi-principals agency theory of regulation, or ‘let them be bribed’.” Journal of Law and Economics, 33: 65–101.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stigler, G. (1971). “The theory of economic regulation.” Bell Journal of Economics and Management, 2: 3–21.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sutter, D. (2002). “Constitutional prohibitions in a rent seeking model.” Public Choice, 111: 105–125.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tollison, R.D. (1997). “Rent seeking,” in D.C. Mueller (ed.) Perspectives on Public Choice. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 506–525.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (1967). “The welfare costs of tariffs, monopolies, and theft.” Western Economic Journal, 5: 224–232.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (1980). “Efficient rent-seeking,” in J.M. Buchanan, R.D. Tollison, and G. Tullock (eds.) Toward a Theory of the Rent-Seeking Society. College Station: Texas A&M University Press, pp. 97–112.

    Google Scholar 

  • van Velthoven, B. (1989). The Endogenization of Government Behaviour in Macroeconomic Models. Berlin: Springer Verlag.

    Google Scholar 

  • van Velthoven, B. and van Winden, F. (1985). “Towards a politico-economic theory of social security.” European Economic Review, 27: 263–289.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Verbon, H. (1989). The Evolution of Public Pension Schemes. Berlin: Springer Verlag.

    Google Scholar 

  • Welch, W. (1980). “The allocation of political monies: economic interest groups.” Public Choice, 35: 97–120.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • van Winden, F. (1983). On the Interaction between State and Private Sector. Amsterdam: North Holland.

    Google Scholar 

  • van Winden, F. (1999). “On the economic theory of interest groups: towards a group frame of reference.” Public Choice, 100: 1–29.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • van Winden, F. (2002). “Experimental investigation of collective action,” in S.L. Winer and H. Shibata (eds.) Political Economy and Public Finance. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • van Winden, F., Schram, A., and Groot, F. (1987). “The interaction between economics and politics: modelling cycles.” European Journal of Political Research, 15: 185–202.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wright, J.R. (1990). “Contributions, lobbying, and committee voting in the U.S. House of Representatives.” American Political Science Review, 84: 417–438.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zusman, P. (1976). “The incorporation and measurement of social power in economic models.” International Economic Review, 17: 447–462.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Authors

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2004 Kluwer Academic Publishers

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

van Winden, F. (2004). Interest Group Behavior and Influence. In: Rowley, C.K., Schneider, F. (eds) The Encyclopedia of Public Choice. Springer, Boston, MA. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-0-306-47828-4_10

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-0-306-47828-4_10

  • Publisher Name: Springer, Boston, MA

  • Print ISBN: 978-0-7923-8607-0

  • Online ISBN: 978-0-306-47828-4

  • eBook Packages: Springer Book Archive

Publish with us

Policies and ethics