Skip to main content

Evolution of Consistent Conjectures in Semi-aggregative Representation of Games, with Applications to Public Good Games and Contests

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Book cover The Theory of Externalities and Public Goods
  • 1073 Accesses

Abstract

In a semi-aggregative representation of a game, the payoff of a player depends on a player’s own strategy and on a personalized aggregate of all players’ strategies. Suppose that each player has a conjecture about the reaction of the personalized aggregate to a change in the player’s own strategy. The players play an equilibrium given their conjectures, and evolution selects conjectures that lead to a higher payoff in such an equilibrium. Considering one player role, I show that for any conjectures of the other players, only conjectures that are consistent can be evolutionarily stable, where consistency means that the conjecture is, to a first approximation, correct at equilibrium. I illustrate this result in public good games and contests.

Paper prepared for a volume honoring the memory of Richard Cornes. In his time at the University of Nottingham, Richard was a helpful colleague, ready to give advice in his usual witty and entertaining manner.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 149.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 199.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 199.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    Further examples of aggregative games are listed in Cornes and Hartley (2011) and Cornes (2016) discusses the applications of aggregative games in the analysis of environmental problems.

  2. 2.

    Another interpretation is that players first choose conjectures and then play the game. The search is then for an equilibrium in the game of choosing conjectures. I nevertheless prefer the evolutionary interpretation, which makes it clearer that the process of forming beliefs and choosing strategies occur at different times. This evolutionary interpretation is an example of the “indirect evolution approach” (Güth and Yaari 1992).

  3. 3.

    For example, consider the identity u i (x 1, , x n ) = x i + u i (x 1, , x n ) − x i . Let A i  = f i (x 1, , x n ) = u i (x 1, , x n ) − x i and write u i (x i , A i ) = x i + A i .

  4. 4.

    In a homogeneous good market with one price, the aggregate (the price) is the same for all firms, and the game is properly aggregative.

  5. 5.

    In a duopoly context, Dockner (1992) and Cabral (1995) show that a dynamic model indeed can lead to the same outcomes as certain CVEs, and Itaya and Dasgupta (1995) and Itaya and Okamura (2003) do so for a public good game.

  6. 6.

    This consistency requirement was introduced by Bresnahan (1981) for a duopoly, and also used e.g. in Perry (1982) in an oligopoly and Cornes and Sandler (1984a) in a public good game context.

  7. 7.

    Note that the definition focuses on player i treating the other players conjectures as fixed; Selten (1980) showed that such an approach is appropriate in asymmetric games.

  8. 8.

    To save space, arguments of derivatives are omitted. It is understood that they are evaluated at r = (r i ES, r i ) and CVE (x (r), A (r)).

  9. 9.

    The relationship between consistent conjectures and the conjectures that maximize the indirect payoff function u i (x i (r i , r j ), A i (r i , r j )) was noted by Itaya and Dasgupta (1995) for a two-player public good game.

  10. 10.

    See e.g. Makowski (1987) and Cornes and Sandler (1996, p. 32) say that they do not attach any particular importance to consistent conjectures.

  11. 11.

    The observation that the consistent conjecture is the best response conjecture of one player to any given conjecture of the other player was made in Dixon and Somma (2003) for a linear-quadratic Cournot duopoly game.

  12. 12.

    Note that if b i  = 1 for all i, then the public good becomes a pure public good and the same aggregate G =  i = 1 n x i can be used for all players.

  13. 13.

    The second-order condition \(\alpha _{i}(1 -\alpha _{i})(m_{i} - x_{i})^{\alpha _{i}-2}G_{i}^{-\alpha _{i}-1}(-G_{i}^{2} - 2(m_{i} - x_{i})G_{i}r_{i} - (m_{i} - x_{i})^{2}r_{i}^{2}) < 0\) is satisfied for r i  ≥ 0 and all interior x i , G i .

  14. 14.

    Note that if b = 1, then r = 0 is the solution of the consistency condition (Sugden 1985). However, for r = 0 the solution of the players’ maximization problem is not interior and the first-order conditions do not characterize it. The propositions do not apply in this case.

  15. 15.

    To avoid indeterminacies, let \(u_{i} = \frac{1} {n}\) if A = 0.

  16. 16.

    For n = 2, there are non-zero symmetric conjectures that are consistent and evolutionarily stable. The consistency condition for n = 2 is \(r_{i} = \frac{c_{i}} {c_{j}}r_{j}\). If c i  = c j , then any r is consistent. It is shown in Possajennikov (2009) that any 0 < r < 2 is evolutionarily stable then.

References

  • Bresnahan, T. F. (1981). Duopoly models with consistent conjectures. American Economic Review, 71, 934–945.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cabral, L. M. B. (1995). Conjectural variations as a reduced form. Economics Letters, 49, 397–402.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Corchón, L. C. (1994). Comparative statics for aggregative games. The strong concavity case. Mathematical Social Sciences, 28, 151–165.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cornes, R. (2016). Aggregative environmental games. Environmental and Resource Economics, 63, 339–365.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cornes, R., & Hartley, R. (2003). Risk aversion, heterogeneity and contests. Public Choice, 117, 1–25.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cornes, R., & Hartley, R. (2005). Asymmetric contests with general technologies. Economic Theory, 26, 923–946.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cornes, R., & Hartley, R. (2007). Aggregative public good games. Journal of Public Economic Theory, 9, 201–219.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cornes, R., & Hartley, R. (2011). Well-behaved aggregative games. Presented at the 2011 Workshop on Aggregative Games at Strathclyde University, Glasgow.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cornes, R., & Hartley, R. (2012). Fully aggregative games. Economics Letters, 116, 631–633.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cornes, R., & Sandler, T. (1983). On commons and tragedies. American Economic Review, 73, 787–792.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cornes, R., & Sandler, T. (1984a). The theory of public goods: Non-nash behavior. Journal of Public Economics, 23, 367–379.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cornes, R., & Sandler, T. (1984b). Easy riders, joint production and public goods. Economic Journal, 94, 580–598.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cornes, R., & Sandler, T. (1996) The theory of externalities, public goods and club goods (2nd ed.). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Costrell, R. M. (1991). Immiserizing growth with semi-public goods under consistent conjectures. Journal of Public Economics, 45, 383–389.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dixon, H. D., & Somma, E. (2003). The evolution of consistent conjectures. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 51, 523–536.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dockner, E. J. (1992). Dynamic theory of conjectural variations. Journal of Industrial Economics, 40, 377–395.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Güth, W., & Yaari, M. (1992). An evolutionary approach to explain reciprocal behavior in a simple strategic game. In U. Witt (Ed.), Explaining process and change – Approaches to evolutionary economics (pp. 23–34). Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Itaya, J.-I., & Dasgupta, D. (1995). Dynamics, consistent conjectures, and heterogeneous agents in the private provision of public goods. Public Finance/Finances Publiques, 50, 371–389.

    Google Scholar 

  • Itaya, J.-I., & Okamura, M. (2003). Conjectural variations and voluntary public good provision in a repeated game setting. Journal of Public Economic Theory, 5, 51–66.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Laitner, J. (1980). Rational duopoly equilibria. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 95, 641–662.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Makowski, L. (1987). Are ‘rational conjectures’ rational? Journal of Industrial Economics, 36, 35–47.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Maynard Smith, J., & Price, G. R. (1973). The logic of animal conflict. Nature, 246(Nov 2), 15–18.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Müller, W., & Normann, H.-T. (2005). Conjectural variations and evolutionary stability: A rationale for consistency. Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 161, 491–502.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Perry, M. K. (1982). Oligopoly and consistent conjectural variations. Bell Journal of Economics, 13, 197–205.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Possajennikov, A. (2009). The evolutionary stability of constant consistent conjectures. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 72, 21–29.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Possajennikov, A. (2015). Conjectural variations in aggregative games: An evolutionary perspective. Mathematical Social Sciences, 77, 55–61.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Selten, R. (1980). A note on evolutionarily stable strategies in asymmetric animal conflicts. Journal of Theoretical Biology, 84, 93–101.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sugden, R. (1985). Consistent conjectures and voluntary contributions to public goods: Why the conventional theory does not work. Journal of Public Economics, 27, 117–124.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (1980). Efficient rent-seeking. In J. M. Buchanan, R. D. Tollison, & G. Tullock (Eds.), Toward a theory of the rent-seeking society (pp. 131–146). College Station: Texas A&M University Press.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

I would like to thank Dirk Rübbelke and Wolfgang Buchholz for this opportunity. I would also like to thank Alex Dickson for inviting me to participate in April 2011 in a workshop on aggregative games, which incited me to think about conjectures and aggregative games, and develop the ideas leading to this paper. I also thank Maria Montero for improving the exposition in the paper.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Alex Possajennikov .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2017 Springer International Publishing AG

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Possajennikov, A. (2017). Evolution of Consistent Conjectures in Semi-aggregative Representation of Games, with Applications to Public Good Games and Contests. In: Buchholz, W., Rübbelke, D. (eds) The Theory of Externalities and Public Goods. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-49442-5_5

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics