Introduction

The bio-waste valorization is becoming an increasingly urgent priority for governments and environmental and social organizations (Morone et al. 2015). In this respect, the attention is mainly focused on the organic fraction of municipal and agricultural waste that can be used as raw material for biodegradable products (e.g., detergents, fuels, textile auxiliaries, plastic, fertilizers) (Motoneri et al. 2014, Scaringelli et al. 2016). Among these, a promising sustainable innovation is represented by biodegradable mulching films derived from soluble bio-based substances (SBOs) (Motoneri et al. 2014). This technology is at a development stage (TRLFootnote 1 4/5), and its future adoption by farmers can improve both the sustainability of agricultural practices and the waste management process. This introduces the issue of innovation diffusion, proven that the achievement of the abovementioned benefits strictly depends on the spread of the novelty among a critical mass of users.

Here, we stress that, at the core of the diffusion process, there are operation and functioning of the social networks (i.e., the set and pattern of support, friendship, and communication relations) connecting people (Valente 1995). In fact, in its straightforward definition, the diffusion of innovation can be intended as “a special type of communication, in that the messages are concerned with new ideas” (Rogers 2003: 5). Communication implies the mobilization of social ties among people to create and share information and reach a reciprocal understanding (Rogers 2003). This process is fundamental in overcoming the innovation resistance that is the agents’ normal response against uncertainty and the costly readjustment activity imposed by the innovation (Ram 1987). To put differently, the learning-from-others mechanism is likely to enhance the diffusion of innovation: this is true not only for innovations but also for farming strategies (Santeramo 2018).

More in-depth, social networks can influence diffusion providing (1) the medium for the circulation of information that is crucial to make the agents aware about the novelty and its real costs and benefits; (2) a certain level of redundancy of the information, deriving from social reinforcement, that is useful in overcoming uncertainty; (3) a certain level of homophily among actors (defined as the overlap degree of some agents attributes, such as education, socioeconomic status, and preferences) that favors common meanings, beliefs sharing, and mutual understandings (Rogers 2003).

As a consequence, the ability of the agents to affect their neighbors’ (i.e., the others with whom they are connected) adoption decision is closely related to their role and location in the network. The social network analysis (SNA) has developed various centrality measures to capture network characteristics of the agents. These centrality measures can be considered by market operators and policymakers as a key driver to build effective promotional strategies. With this regard, the literature demonstrates that diffusion rates can vary greatly depending on the injection points (IPs) (i.e., the agents where the innovation is first injected, which are “early adopters”) used, according to their network centrality (Banerjee et al. 2013). This is particularly true in the case of diffusion of new sustainable practices in agriculture (Tey and Brindal 2012).

In this perspective, this work represents a preliminary analysis of the network features which best predict effective IPs (i.e., those able to reach the highest adoption rates) in the case of a specific sustainable novelty, the SBO mulching films, in a rural context. The aim is to find those individual centrality measures that can be used as a rational criterion to select the best spreaders. The focus is on a community of farmers located in the north of Apulia (Italy) specialized in the production of vegetables. By means of an agent-based model (ABM), we simulated the effects of different IPs on the diffusion rates into an artificial community representing the one studied. In order to evaluate the robustness of our findings, we conduct a sensitivity analysis accounting for the possibility that the novelty disappoints a fraction of consumers. Moreover, we applied the SNA to obtain measures of IPs’ network characteristics. Finally, we adopted a multiple linear regression model to estimate the effect of the various centrality measures of the IPs on the final adoption rates.

The use of social network potentialities to design successful diffusion campaigns is a topic largely investigated by the literature on ABMs of innovation diffusion (Goldenberg et al. 2001, Moldovan and Goldenberg 2004, Alkemade and Castaldi 2005, Goldenberg et al. 2007, Delre et al. 2007a). In this kind of approach, different from another kind of models such as linear programming, dynamic models, differential equation, the most elementary unit of modelization is represented by the single agent rather than the social system as a whole. This allows researchers to explicitly model the agents’ heterogeneity, their social interactions, and their decision-making processes. In fact, the distinguishing feature of the ABM is that it represents the macro-level dynamics that take place in a social system as the result of the behavior of every single agent belonging to the social system and the interactions with its neighbors. For these reasons, ABM results are particularly suitable in showing the different performances of diffusion strategies based on the choice of the best connected actors (Valente and Davis 1999, Delre et al. 2007a, Goldenberg et al. 2009, Delre et al. 2010, Bohlmann et al. 2010, van Eck et al. 2011). Some of these models (Alkemande and Castaldi 2005, Goldenberg et al. 2000, Delre et al. 2007b; Bohlmann et al. 2010) explicitly include an adoption threshold to represent the different propensity of potential consumers of a new product to adopt (Kiesling 2012). Another type of models is devoted to simulating informational cascade (Banerjee 1992, Watts 2002). These models depict the graduation of the diffusion dynamic where different classes of consumer gradually adopt the novelty according to a progressive fashion distinguishing early adopters, followers, and laggards. When the novelty spreads in the largest part of the network, it occurs as a cascade.

The paper is structured as follows: the “The diffusion model” section describes the model employed, its basic assumption, its construction, and internal dynamics; the “Simulation and results” section reports the main results; and the “Concluding remarks” section concludes with some discussion and policy implications, including also suggestion for further research and some concluding remarks.

The diffusion model

For the sake of clarity, in what follows, we shall describe the model according to the “guidelines for model development” outlined in Rand and Rust (2011) aimed at setting a rigorous procedure for AB modeling. The logical basis of the model is provided by the following assumptions that cover all the relevant elements of the model inferences; moreover, the references after each statement provide the empirical basis for the assumptions (East et al. 2016): (A1) Each agent has a specific innovation resistance, represented by an individual adoption threshold (Nisbet and Collins 1978). (A2) For the adoption to occur, the agent’s preference toward the innovation must overcome its innovation threshold. (A3) To form a preference, the agent must be aware of the innovation existence and its advantages (Chen 1996; Daberkow and McBride 2003). (A4) The agent grasps relevant information to become aware of the preferences of his neighbors (agents connected with it) (Molina-Morales and Martinez-Fernandez 2010; Narayan and Pritchett 1999; Van Rijn et al. 2012). (A5) The more homophilous the neighbor is, the more pieces of information the agent will grasp from it (Centola 2010, 2011). (A6) The higher the agent’s education, the higher its capacity to grasp information from its neighborhood as a whole (Gellynck et al. 2014; Tepic et al. 2012).

Model design

The scope of the model is to reproduce the passing information dynamics and the adoption decision process among a population of farmers. In its most straightforward outline, the model depicts a network of agents connected by bidirectional links. As a consequence, the environment of each agent is represented by its neighbors that are the agents with whom it is connected via in/out-links through which it receives/sends information and influence. As highlighted by East et al. (2016), a common shortcoming in network diffusion models derives from the use of theoretical network structure (e.g., random networks, regular lattice) typically exhibiting the same centrality for all the actors. To overcome this limitation and to reach a better representation of relational complexity, the network in this case is modeled on the basis of a real-world network as explained below. The agents are divided into two classes, ordinaries and IPs; in each model run, we have one IP, being the rest of the agent ordinaries. They are characterized by different behaviors: The ordinaries represent farmers that have to decide whether to adopt or not. The IP represents a farmer which has already adopted the novelty and uses it over all the model time span since the initialization phase. Concerning the set of properties of the model’s elements, each link has a property representing the level of homophily between the agents connected [h], and each agent has a preference toward the new technology [p], an adoption threshold [θ], a level of education [e], and the innovation status [novelty?]. These properties represent also the basic inputs of the model, while the model fundamental output is the number of ordinaries that have adopted at each time step.

Model construction

The model is structured into two phases: the initialization and the iteration. At the initialization step, n agents and m links are created. At this phase, p is set at 0 for ordinaries and 1 for IPs and θ and e are set at specific values (see below). The innovation status is set false for ordinaries and true for the IP. At each iteration time step, each ordinary (1) reconsiders its preference after having received information from its neighbors,Footnote 2 (2) pass information to neighbors,Footnote 3 and (3) decides to adopt (i.e., novelty? is set true) if p ≥ θ. This sequence is repeated until the model time span reaches the value t.

Concerning step 1, it is worth noting that the sole factor influencing the preference of an ordinary agent is the preferences of its neighbors. Specifically, at each time t, each ordinary i calculates its preference pit as the sum of its preference in the previous period pit − 1 and the average of the preferences of its j neighbors pjt weighted with the homophily degree with its neighbors hji. This sum is then corrected multiplying it by the level of education of i ei. Formally, the calculation of pit is:

$$ {p}_{it}={p}_{it-1}+\left(\sum \frac{p_{jt-1}{h}_{ji}}{n}\right)C\ \mathrm{with}\ C=\frac{e_i}{\max_e}. $$
(1)

It is worth noting that the time dimension in this process acts as an accumulator of the preference level allowing to unravel the interaction between network features and preference formation.

To augment the model reality, we developed also a disappointment extension, which introduces a common issue in the innovation adoption process, that is the probability that the novelty disappoints a fraction of users. To simulate this behavior, the disappoint version includes the possibility that the innovation disappoints the adopter. When this case occurs, the model provides a possible third action for the ordinary agent, to reduce its preference of a variable % (between 25 and 75%) toward the novelty. In this version of the model, the disappointment is modeled as a random event which affects a variable fraction of the population (between 0 and 25%).

Model verification

Our model was implemented and run using the NetLogo 5.2 platform (Wilensky 1999). To import the network under investigation, we included in the model a routine adapted by the “Network Import Example” authored by Uri Wilensky and available at the modeling commons platform.Footnote 4 The sequence of model execution is outlined in Fig. 1. It plots the chart flow of the model dynamics that is the internal agent’s decision logic. The code flow was analyzed, and each piece of the code was tested to verify its correct functioning. In this phase, we also employed corner cases (extreme values of the inputs) to verify that the implemented model does not show aberrant behaviors (e.g., no adoption is realized without any IP).

Fig. 1
figure 1

The model flow chart adopted to generate the data in our simulation

Model calibration

The identification of model parameters was based on a case from South Italy, located in the Province of Foggia. It relates to a group of specialized vegetable farmers (N = 80) which already use conventional or biodegradable mulching technique and are therefore potentially interested in the innovative use of SBO-derived films (Scaringelli et al. 2016). Sample size covers 2% of the population. This is a reasonable sample extension to obtain enough real-world data for the calibration of the model parameters. This case study is suitable to this end, prove that it offers a cross-section of the social and professional interactions of vegetable crop farmers in this territory. Being the technology under investigation still at a development stage, no real adoption rate already exists. This is exactly what the ABM model addresses: to simulate the effect of various IPs on the final adoption rate. Thus, we used the case study with the sole purpose to calibrate the following model parameters: (i) the network structure, which is defined by the number of agents, the number of links connecting the agents, and the links distribution among agents; (ii) the agent parameters e and θ; and (iii) the link parameter h. We obtained the information on the network structure by means of deep face-to-face interviews with two experts which live and work within the context of the case study and can be considered direct observers. These interviews were directed at recognizing the social and professional relations connecting the web by means of a participatory social network observation.Footnote 5 To this end, the experts were asked to trace the who-knows-who relations and to identify the affiliations to local cooperatives. To obtain the other information needed to calibrate the reminder of model parameters, we performed a questionnaire survey on the actors forming the network asking for age, years of education, cropping patterns, willingness to adopt SBO mulching films, farm size, and number of employees. We also calculated the distance between the farmers based on their location. Some descriptive statistics are reported in Table 1.

Table 1 The descriptive statics of observations of our case study

The relational data were used to build the network of firms that form the interaction arrangement of the agents. This network is formed of a single component, not fragmented, with a medium level of density (21%). Within this network, two randomly chosen nodes have an average distance of 2.42, and the maximum distance observed is 6. On the whole, the network results are very clustered (clustering coefficient 0.78). The demographic data were employed in the validation of agents’ properties. Specifically, we used the following parameters: n = 80, as the number of respondent farmers. In each simulation, we split this number in 79 ordinaries and 1 IP; m = 1296 that is the number of links observed in the real farmers’ network. Moreover, in the construction of the simulated network, the links have not been evenly distributed among the agents. Instead, the agents in the model reproduce exactly the relational profile of each farmer interviewed, with the same number of relations with the same neighbors; h varies in the range [0.1]. Rather than using a single dimension, we set this property on the base of four socioeconomic attributes (farm size, number of employees, age, and distances between farmers), as in Blau et al. 1984, Mc Pherson et al. 2001; Centola et al. 2007; p is 0 for ordinaries and 1 for IPs; novelty? is false for ordinaries and true for IPs; θ reflects the willingness to adopt SBO mulching films declared by respondents and is set on a six-degree scale ranging between − 1 (completely adverse to adoption) and 1 (completely favorable to adoption); e is various and reflects the year of education of each farmer. For the estimation of t (i.e., the model time span), we matched a 5-year time horizon (representing a rational span to allow the innovation to became mature) with 45 model periods, that is the time needed by the most part of the IPs to reach a stable adoption rate. As a consequence, in our model, a time step is equal to 40 days.

Simulation and results

The procedure adopted to find those centrality measures that can be used as rational criterion to select effective IPs can be broken down in three main phases: (1) calculation of the centrality measures for each agent in the network, (2) simulation of the IP’s effect in terms of final adoption rate using the ABM model, and (3) estimation of the effect of centrality measures on the simulated adoption rates employing the multiple linear regression.

Phase 1

By means of the SNA, we calculated six network measures for each agent (Table 2).

Table 2 The network measures employed to characterize the IPs

Table 3 contains the descriptive analysis of the abovementioned network measures. All the measures used were standardized over a range of 0.1 to facilitate the interpretation of the results. The table shows that each node (1) is connected to 21% of the rest of the network in mean, (2) intercepts 2% of the shortest path length among others, (3) is rather close to others, (4) has a medium level of ARD, (5) is characterized by a high local clustering coefficient, (6) and has a relatively low eigenvector.

Table 3 The table synthesizes the descriptive statistics of the SNA network variables

Phase 2

We used the NetLogo platform to code and run the ABM model. Figure 2 depicts the interface of the model implemented. In the simulation, each one of the 80 agents is used as IP alternatively; moreover, the robustness of the results is proved simulating the diffusion process repeatedly using each IP many times (batches of 20 runs) and taking the means of the simulated data.

Fig. 2
figure 2

The NetLogo interface running the model described. The circles represent the agents (red circles are adopting agents)

Since the main output of the simulation is the number of adopters at the final time, we simulated the number and rate of adopters for each IP at t = 45 (Table 4) for both versions of the model (basic and disappointment).

Table 4 The table shows the number and rate of adopters at the final step of our simulation

We also performed a robustness check of results, simulating the number of adopters and calculating the adoption rates also at t = 68 and 90. The variation is negligible. This means that at t = 45, the process is at its climax with a little part of the dynamic already working. We used the adoption rate at t = 68 and 90 in the estimation of centrality effect (see the “Phase 3” section below) with no variation in the sign and significativeness of coefficients and with almost the same values. We verified also that the threshold at t = 45 is the best end for the model simulation proven that the adoption rate at this time step displays a little more variability than t = 68 and 90 magnifying the difference in the variables estimations.

The number of adopters is around 19 for the base model and 11 for the disappointment version. For both versions, the level of dispersion is very low, that is, excepting little variation, the IPs work in a rather same manner. The maximum rate of adoption is 25% for the basic model and 17% for the disappointment model.

At least for this case study, these results indicate that the individual characteristics of the IPs are not primarily responsible for the diffusion process. Instead, the density and clusterization of the network do the most part of the diffusion work.

Phase 3

In this phase, we estimated the effect of the centrality measures calculated in phase 1 on the adoption rates (AR) simulated in phase 2, by means of a simple model of linear regression, specified as follows:

$$ \mathrm{AR}=\alpha +{\beta}_1\mathrm{Centrality}+{\beta}_2\mathrm{ARD}+{\beta}_3\mathrm{Eigenvector}+{\beta}_4\mathrm{Betweenness}+{\beta}_5\mathrm{LCC}+{\beta}_6\mathrm{Closeness}+\varepsilon $$

where AR is the adoption rate in the base and disappointment models (cfr. Table 4), and the regressors are those specified in Table 3, with ARD standing for average reciprocal distance and LCC standing for local clustering coefficients.

Table 5 reports the results of the regression. What we can firstly observe is that the positive influence of a dense network on the innovation diffusion is confirmed by a high intercept in the base model. The analysis of this model also highlights degree and closeness centralities as the best indicators for effective IPs. Both these measures have in fact a positive effect on the adoption rate and are highly significant. Moreover, their impact is remarkable; an augment of 1% of degree and closeness centrality produces an increase of 30% and 47%, respectively, in the adoption rate. On the contrary, betweenness and eigenvector centralities exhibit a negative. This is a surprising result, proven that betweenness is a measure of how many times an agent acts as a bridge and is considered an important indicator of how the single agent plays the role of broker, while eigenvector is a measure of how central the neighbors of the agent are. High levels of these centralities are supposed to reflect into a great influence on the network with a potential crucial role in passing information and innovation spread dynamics (Borgatti et al. 2013; Hanneman and Riddle 2005). Finally, despite the average reciprocal distance and the clustering coefficient in particular are important network measure capable of providing social reinforce in the new behavior diffusion (Centola 2011) in this case resulted not statistically significant.

Table 5 The table synthesizes the results of the econometric analysis

These partly counterintuitive results are probably due to the specific structure of the real network analyzed. Most part of the literature, indeed, analyzed the effectiveness of the centrality measures on a completely theoretical network (i.e., regular lattice, random, small world), but the morphology of the network is clearly responsible for the whole diffusion dynamic and of the actual power of the single positions. In the network under investigation, the agents with the highest betweenness act as bridges between two major components of the network. These two components differs in size and structure, being the greater (60 nodes) 3.75 times the size of the smaller (16 nodes). Moreover, the former has a pretty random structure highly centralized with many long ties, while the latter is a very clustered network with a highly regular structure. In this context, the most part of the diffusion dynamics happens in the greater component, making relatively more important role of central and close IPs in its core than the role of brokers with the minor component. The supremacy of the network structure over the diffusion dynamics is also confirmed by the results from the disappointment model: when harsher conditions to innovation adoption emerge with disappointment possibility, the positive influence of IPs centrality on adoption rates ceases, while the negative operation of betweenness and eigenvector remains, though reduced.

Being the model we used for the estimation a multiple regression, the findings related to each single centrality measure should not be intended as separate and self-contained but as parts of a comprehensive frame capable of leading to a multifaceted and clear profile of the ideal spreader: central and close to the rest of the network but not “between” the most part of actors, with no or limited bridge toward other very central actors. In other words, in this specific structure, the diffusion of innovation is accelerated when the spreader can exert direct influence through immediate links on a large part of the network and is hindered when this influence is mediated by others.

Concluding remarks

This paper aimed at performing a preliminary analysis of the network features characterizing IPs capable of reaching high adoption rates in the case of the adoption of SBO

mulching films in a rural context. To this end, we combined techniques form SNA, ABM, and linear regression to calculate the centrality measures of the spreaders, simulate the adoption rates of the innovation, and estimate the effect of centralities on the adoption dynamics. These results should be viewed as a first step in identifying the network measures featuring good IPs. We found the most straightforward centrality measures (i.e., centrality degree, closeness) as the most relevant in spreading diffusion. This is not a trivial result proven that more “insightful” measures (i.e., betweenness and eigenvector) resulted to exert an opposite effect on the adoption rates. This contributes to addressing the initial problem of finding those individual centrality measures suitable to identify operative criteria to select the best spreaders. Rather than single specific criterion, we identified an actual profile of the best spreader.

We found that, for the diffusion of sustainable innovation in agriculture, and at least in the case of context and relational structure similar to that studied, it is primarily important how connected the IP is (how high is its immediate influence) and how relatively close it is to the rest of the web. Another major point is the emerged supremacy of the network structure on the diffusion dynamics. It makes the difference on the effectiveness of IPs positions creating positive or negative chance to innovation diffusion. This is very important for policy and marketing decisions, especially in rural areas which are characterized by a highly specific social structure that should carefully be considered to design a successful spreading campaign. The implications of our paper are relevant in terms of rural planning and development. To the extent that innovations are potential drivers of competitiveness, policy interventions should be planned in order to achieve not only efficacy, but also efficiency, exploiting the leverage effect of social capital (Nardone et al. 2010): targeting the best early adopters, capable of enhancing the learning-from-others mechanisms (Santeramo 2018) would help in lowering the costs of policy interventions and increasing the impacts of the rural development measures.

Finally, the fact that no agent reached at least a 25% adoption rate highlights the need to identifying the optimal number of injection point (rather than a single injection point) to maximize the potential diffusion of the technology, also considering the fact that it is costly for advisors to spread the technology among end users. The kind of model used in this paper might help in the design of balanced groups of IPs. A caveat of this study is represented by a limited case study with specific features (density and clusterization). The effects of the individual characteristics on the final rate of adoption should be interpreted on this basis. A more comprehensive analysis should include the investigation of different network structures (e.g., high vs. low density, regular vs. randomized structure, high vs. low average degree). Another area of analysis is represented by the measurement of the impact of exposure number per agent to the word of mouth. The expected result of such a deeper investigation is the achievement of valuable hints for marketing and policy-making actors in the light of the bio-waste valorization.