Skip to main content
Log in

The Role of Non-standard Work Status in Parental Caregiving for Young Children

  • Article
  • Published:
Eastern Economic Journal Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper uses data from the American Time Use Survey to examine the effect of the timing of parents’ daily work schedules on their caregiving time on weekdays. Since the timing of employment is a choice, the decision to work non-standard hours is modeled jointly with caregiving. We find that high-wage non-standard mothers provide more caregiving than lower-wage non-standard mothers, while caregiving time performed by standard-time working mothers is not responsive to their wages. For fathers, caregiving is shown to be strongly related to marital status, the age of his children and the presence of other adults in the household.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Figure 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. We use data drawn from the Survey of Income and Program Participation to instrument our childcare price measures.

  2. Presser [2003] explains that structural labor demand shifts as well as the evolution of societal norms have contributed to the increase in non-standard jobs.

  3. See also Han [2005] and Grosswald [2004] for discussions of the implications of parental non-standard work schedules for children and families.

  4. Han [2004] also finds that mothers working non-standard shifts rely heavily on paternal childcare for their children. Henly et al. [2006] extend Han's work by focusing on low-income mothers. They find that low-income mothers who work in the evening use less center care but more total hours of non-parental care per year.

  5. We define caregiving as the time parents devote to caregiving reported as the primary activity in the ATUS.

  6. Gelbach [2002] finds an important role for public school eligibility in determining maternal labor supply.

  7. In fact, some school systems still switch the child from morning to afternoon halfway through the school year.

  8. Owing to the way caregiving is coded, it is possible for the mother to record caregiving minutes even if the child is asleep, if for example, she spent 15 min on the phone looking for a babysitter. However, the vast majority of caregiving time is done with children present.

  9. The criteria for defining mothers or fathers are the same — a respondent with the time diary who lives in a household with at least one child under the age of 13 years where the child is recorded as “own household child.”

  10. These means are unweighted because they reflect estimation sample descriptive statistics.

  11. In the SIPP Wave 4 topical module, employed women with children under the age of 5 years were asked about their expenditure on childcare for their youngest child. In addition, employed women with children between the ages of 6 and 14 years were asked about their expenditure on childcare for their youngest child in that age range. We eliminated those whose youngest child was the age of 13 or 14 years and those who were either currently in the military, in school, or unemployed. We used the resulting sample to estimate the price of childcare for children aged 5 years or under and separately for children between the ages of 6 and 12 years. We retain these two childcare expenditure measures as separate regressors because the availability of 5 or 6 h of school time, which doubles as non-parental childcare time, makes childcare for 6–12 year olds very different from that for children aged 5 years and under. The procedure we used to estimate the hourly price of childcare is a standard bivariate selection correction model, described by Tunali [1986] and used by Connelly and Kimmel [2003a, 2003b]. The results of this bivariate selection correction model are available from the authors.

  12. More specifically, we use the dot product of the predicted coefficients and values of the independent variables from the mothers in the ATUS sample. As is well known, incorporating generated regressors in this way produces biased standard errors. Owing to the complexity of our model, we have not corrected the estimated standard errors for this bias.

  13. The sample omits a small group of parents who work all their non-standard employment hours at home. The rationale for omitting these respondents is that they may be working away from the home during standard work hours and then bringing work home to do in the evenings. This type of work at home may be more easily juggled with caregiving time than non-standard hours worked outside the home. The analysis is largely unchanged when they are included. For a full discussion of working at home simultaneously with care provision, see Callister and Singley [2004], who conclude that the bulk of such work serves more as a double burden than as a reflection of choices made to facilitate work/family balance.

  14. Note that we are speaking here of the work schedule reported on the diary day, not a “usual” work schedule. Rapoport and Le Bourdais [2008] focus on the endogeneity of the usual schedule while treating the schedule reported on the diary day as exogenous.

  15. According to Stewart [2009], “the zeroes in time-use data arise from a mismatch between the reference period of the data (the diary day) and the period of interest, which is typically longer.” However, for our interest, the reference period of the data coincides exactly with the period of interest. We focus on how non-standard work on the single diary relates to caregiving on that same single diary day. We are not interested in examining a longer time period. Thus, we feel that the tobit model is an appropriate choice for our research project.

  16. We did estimate an alternative model in which we use an endogenous switch to estimate caregiving time use simultaneously with total paid work hours (both modeled as tobits) to incorporate the jointness of those two time choices. The coefficient estimates in the caregiving equations were nearly identical to the findings reported in this paper.

  17. It could also be coming from the price of time effects on non-employed mothers. Mothers with no employment hours on a weekday diary day are excluded from our analysis here, but were included in Kimmel and Connelly [2007].

  18. Diary data from the child-based Panel Survey of Income Dynamics might be more appropriate for considering this question.

  19. Results available from the authors.

  20. Bianchi et al. [2005] show that “child in room” minus primary caregiving time is similar to the secondary caregiving in past time diaries. Not all primary caregiving happens when the child is in the room, since primary caregiving may include making phone calls to secure a babysitter or meeting with the child's teacher, but most primary caregiving does coincide with having a child in the room. What is missing is when one is supervising children playing in a different room and what is included that perhaps should not be is “hanging out time,” such as watching TV together.

  21. Full results available for the authors.

  22. Stewart [2010] examines another aspect of the time of day of parental caregiving by considering the time of day of parent–child interactions. He argues that children are most alert around 11 am when most employed parents are not with them.

References

  • Beers, T.M . 2000. Flexible Schedules and Shift Work: Replacing the “9-to-5” Workday? Monthly Labor Review, 123 (6): 33–40.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bianchi, Susan . 2000. Maternal Employment and Time with Children: Dramatic Change or Surprising Continuity? Demography, 37 (4): 401–414.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bianchi, Suzanne, Vanessa Wight, and Sara Raley . 2005. Maternal Employment and Family Caregiving: Rethinking Time with Children in the ATUS, Paper presented at ATUS Early Results Conference, Bethesda, MD, December.

  • Blau, David, and Alison Hagy . 1998. The Demand for Quality in Child Care. Journal of Political Economy, 106 (1): 104–146.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Callister, Paul, and Susan G. Singley . 2004. A Double Burden or the Best of Both Worlds? A Research Note on Simultaneous Paid Work and Childcare in New Zealand, Unpublished manuscript, Victoria University of Wellington, 17 pages.

  • Casper, Lynne, and Martin O’Connell . 1998. Work, Income, the Economy, and Married Fathers as Child-care Providers. Demography, 35 (2): 243–250.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Collins, Ann M., Jean J. Layzer, J. Lee Kreader, Alan Werner and Fred B. Glantz . 2000. National Study of Child Care for Low-income Families, State and Community Substudy Interim Report, Abt Associates, http://eric.ed.gov/PDFS/ED447964.pdf.

  • Connelly, Rachel . 1992. The Effect of Child Care Costs on Married Women's Labor Force Participation. Review of Economics and Statistics, 74 (1): 83–90.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Connelly, Rachel, and Jean Kimmel . 2003a. Marital Status and Full-time/Part-time Work Status in Child Care Choices. Applied Economics, 35 (7): 761–777.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Connelly, Rachel, and Jean Kimmel . 2003b. The Effect of Child Care Costs on Employment and Welfare Recipiency of Single Mothers. Southern Economic Journal, 69 (3): 498–519.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Connelly, Rachel, and Jean Kimmel . 2009. Spousal Influences on Parents’ Non-market Time Choices. Review of Economics of the Household, 7 (4): 361–394.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Connelly, Rachel, and Jean Kimmel . 2011. The Time Use of Mothers in the United States at the Beginning of the 21st Century. Kalamazoo: W.E. Upjohn Institute for Employment Research.

    Google Scholar 

  • Craig, Lyn . 2007. How Employed Mothers in Australia Find Time for Both Market Work and Childcare. Journal of Family and Economic Issues, 28 (1): 69–87.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fisher, Kimberly . 2005. Comments on ‘Maternal Employment and Family Caregiving: Rethinking Time with Children in the ATUS’, Presented at ATUS Early Results Conference, Bethesda, MD, December.

  • Folbre, Nancy, Jayoung Yoon, Kade Finnoff, and Allison Sidle Fuligni. 2005. By What Measure? Family Time Devoted Children in the United States. Demography, 42 (2): 373–390.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fortson, Kenneth N . 2004. The Diurnal Pattern of On-the-job Injuries. Monthly Labor Review, 127 (9): 8–25.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gelbach, Jonah . 2002. Public Schooling for Young Children and Maternal Labor Supply. American Economic Review, 92 (1): 307–322.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grosswald, Blanche . 2004. The Effects of Shift Work on Family Satisfaction. Families in Society, 85 (3): 413–423.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Han, Wen-Jui . 2004. Nonstandard Work Schedules and Child Care Decisions: Evidence from the NICHD Study of Early Child Care. Early Childhood Research Quarterly, 19 (2): 231–256.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Han, Wen-Jui . 2005. Maternal Nonstandard Work Schedules and Child Cognitive Outcomes. Child Development, 76 (1): 137–154.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heckman, James . 1979. Sample Selection Bias as a Specification Error. Econometrica, 147 (1): 153–161.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hedges, Janice Neipert, and Edward S. Sekscenski . 1979. Workers on Late Shifts in a Changing Economy. Monthly Labor Review, 102 (9): 14–22.

    Google Scholar 

  • Henly, Julia R., Elizabeth O. Ananat, and Sandra K. Danziger . 2006. Nonstandard Work Schedules, Child Care Subsidies, and Child Care Arrangements, Unpublished manuscript, University of Chicago.

  • Howie, Peter, John Wicks, John M. Fitzgerald, Douglas Dalenberg, and Rachel Connelly . 2006. Mothers’ Time Spent in Care of Her Children and Market Work: A Simultaneous Model with Attitudes as Instruments. Applied Economics Letters, 3 (8): 503–506.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jacobsen, Joyce P., and Peter Kooreman . 2005. Timing Constraints and the Allocation of Time: The Effects of Changing Shopping Hours Regulations in the Netherlands. European Economic Review, 49 (1): 9–27.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kimmel, Jean, and Lisa M. Powell . 2006a. Nonstandard Work and Child Care Choices of Married Mothers. Eastern Economic Journal, 32 (3): 397–419.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kimmel, Jean, and Lisa M. Powell . 2006b. Nonstandard Work and Child Care Choices: Implications for Welfare Reform, in From Welfare to Child Care, edited by Natasha J. Cabrera, Robert Hutchens and H. Elizabeth Peters. Mahwah, NJ: Lawrence Erlbaum Associates, Inc, 129–148.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kimmel, Jean, and Rachel Connelly . 2007. Determinants of Mothers’ Time Choices in the United States: Caregiving, Leisure, Home Production, and Paid Work. Journal of Human Resources, 42 (3): 643–681.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Polivka, Anne 2008. Day, Evening, and Night Workers: A Comparison of What They Do in Their Non-work Hours and with Whom They Interact, in How Do We Spend Our Time? edited by Jean Kimmel. Kalamazoo, MI: W.E. Upjohn Institute for Employment Research Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Presser, Harriet B. 1988. Shift Work and Child Care among Young Dual-earner American Parents. Journal of Marriage and the Family, 50 (1): 133–148.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Presser, Harriet B. . 2003. Working in a 24/7 Economy: Challenges for American Families. New York: Russell Sage Foundation.

    Google Scholar 

  • Presser, Harriet B. . 2004. The Economy that Never Sleeps. Contexts, 3 (2): 1–5.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rapoport, Benoit, and Celine Le Bourdais . 2008. Parental Time and Working Schedules. Journal of Population Economics, 21 (4): 903–932.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stewart, Jay 2009. Tobit or Not Tobit, IZA Discussion Paper No. 4588, Bonn, Germany: IZA.

  • Stewart, Jay . 2010. The Timing of Maternal Work and Time with Children. Industrial and Labor Relations Review, 64 (4).

  • Tunali, Insan 1986. A General Structure for Models of Double-selection and an Application to a Joint Migration/Earnings Process with Remigration. Research in Labor Economics, 8B: 235–282.

    Google Scholar 

  • United States Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics. 2005. Workers on Flexible and Shift Schedules in May 2004, USDL 05-1198, July 1.

  • Venn, Danielle 2004. Work Timing Arrangements in Australia in the 1990s: Evidence from the Australian Time Use Survey, Unpublished dissertation, University of Melbourne.

  • Wight, Vanessa R., Sara B. Raley, and Suzanne M. Bianchi . 2008. Time for Children, One's Spouse, and Oneself among Parents Who Work Nonstandard Hours. Social Forces, 87 (September): 243–274.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

The authors thank Suzanne Bianchi, Joyce Jacobsen, Liana Sayer and three anonymous referees from this journal. The paper was part of a larger project funded in part by the W. E. Upjohn Institute for Employment Research.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Connelly, R., Kimmel, J. The Role of Non-standard Work Status in Parental Caregiving for Young Children. Eastern Econ J 37, 248–269 (2011). https://doi.org/10.1057/eej.2010.45

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1057/eej.2010.45

Keywords

JEL Classifications

Navigation