Skip to main content
Log in

Bioeconomics of schooling fishes: selfish fish, quasi-free riders, and other fishy tales

  • Published:
Environmental Biology of Fishes Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Applying the economic theory of clubs to the biological literature on schooling fish, this paper develops a 'selfish fish' club-theoretic paradigm of why fish join a fish school, and arrive at the following conclusions. A selfish fish: (a) joins the fish school because it derives hydrodynamic benefits (a club good); the selfish fish is a 'quasi-free rider'; (b) has no incentive to completely free ride on the benefits of the club good, because it will be, literally, left behind by the school; the fish school is a self-enforcing exclusive club; (c) has no incentive to shirk leadership role in the school because of the role reversibility of leaders and followers; (d) derives benefits from defense, another club good, via the many anti-predator defensive devices provided by club members; (e) has no incentive to discriminate against odd-looking outsiders, since odd-looking fish in a fish school are attacked by predators more frequently than look alikes. But outsiders display xenophobia toward insiders because outsiders do not wish to become prime targets for predators; the result is the formation of homotypic fish schools. Finally, (f) since escape is the main anti-predator defense manoeuvre, the 'any-one leader' rule for making collective choice of escape is the optimal decision-making rule for members of a fish school; this explains the leaderless, completely decentralized form of organization of fish schools. This paper thus contribute to new and deeper insights into various aspects of the bioeconomics of schooling fish.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

References cited

  • Abrahams, M.V. & P.W. Colgan. 1985. Risk of predation, hydrodynamic efficiency and their influence on school structure. Env. Biol. Fish. 13: 195–202.

    Google Scholar 

  • Allan, I.R. & T.I. Pitcher 1986. The influence of species composition on behaviour in mixed-species cyprinid shoals. J. Fish Biol. 29: 97–106.

    Google Scholar 

  • Baily, J. 1988. Mimicry and camouflage. Facts On File Publications, New York, 61 pp.

    Google Scholar 

  • Barnard, C.J. & R.M. Sibly. 1981. Producers and scroungers: a general model and its application to captive flocks of house sparrows. Anim. Behav. 29: 543–550.

    Google Scholar 

  • Belyayev, V.V. & G.V. Zuyev. 1969. Hydrodynamic hypothesis of school formation in fishes. J. Ichthyol. 9: 578–584.

    Google Scholar 

  • Boulier, B.L. & R.S. Goldfarb. 1991. Pisces economicus: the fish as economic man. Econ. Phil. 7: 83–86.

    Google Scholar 

  • Breder, C.M. Jr. 1959. Studies of social grouping in fishes. Bull. Amer. Mus. Nat. Hist. 177: 397–481.

    Google Scholar 

  • Breder, C.M. Jr. 1965. Vortices and fish schools. Zoologica 50: 97–114.

    Google Scholar 

  • Breder, C.M. Jr. 1967. On the survival value of fish schools. Zoologica 52: 25–40.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brock, V.E. & R.H. Riffenburgh. 1960. Fish schooling: a possible factor in reducing predation. J. Cons. Perm. Int. Explor. Mer. 25: 307–317.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J.M. 1965. An economic theory of clubs. Economica 32: 1–14.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J.M. & G. Tullock. 1962. The calculus of consent. The University of Michigan Press, Ann Arbor. 361 pp.

    Google Scholar 

  • Carr, J. & J.T. Landa. 1983. The economics of symbols, clan names, and religion. J. Legal Studies 12: 135–156.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cushing, D.H. & F.R. Harden-Jones. 1968. Why do fish school? Nature 218: 918–920.

    Google Scholar 

  • Eaton, R.C., R.A. Bombardieri & D.L. Meyer. 1977. Teleost startle responses. J. Exp. Biol. 66: 65–81.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ferguson, M.M. & D.L.G. Noakes. 1981. Social grouping and genetic variation in the common shriner Notropis cornulus. Env. Biol. Fish. 6: 357–360.

    Google Scholar 

  • Foster, W.A. & J.E. Treherne. 1981. Evidence for the dilution effect in the selfish herd from fish predation on a marine insect. Nature 293: 466–467.

    Google Scholar 

  • Giraldeau, L-A. & D. Gillis. 1984. Optimal group size can be stable: a reply to Sibly. Anim. Behav. 33: 666–667.

    Google Scholar 

  • Godin, J.G.J. 1986. Risk of predation and foraging behaviour in shoaling banded killifish (Fundulus diaphanus). Can. J. Zool. 64: 1675–1678.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gould, S.J. 1984. How the zebra gets its stripes. pp. 366–375. In: J.S. Gould (ed.) Hen's Teeth and Horses' Toes, W.W. Norton & Company, New York.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hamilton, W.D. 1971. Geometry for the selfish herd. J. Theor. Biol. 31: 295–311.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hass, F. 1945. Collective mimicry. Ecology 26: 412–413.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hobson, E.S. 1968. Predatory behavior of some shore fishes in the Gulf of California. U.S. Fish. Wildl. Serv. Res. Rep. 73: 1–93.

    Google Scholar 

  • Humble, R. 1989. Warfare in the Middle Ages. Bison Books, London. 192 pp.

    Google Scholar 

  • Keenleyside, M.H.A. 1955. Some aspects of the schooling behaviour of fish. Behaviour 8: 83–248.

    Google Scholar 

  • Krebs, J.R. & N.B. Davis. 1993. An introduction to behavioural ecology. Black well Science Ltd., Oxford. 420 pp.

    Google Scholar 

  • Landa, J.T. 1981. A theory of the ethnically homogeneous middleman group: an institutional alternative to contract law. J. Legal Studies 10;2: 349–362.

    Google Scholar 

  • Landa, J.T. 1986. The political economy of swarming in honeybees: voting-with-the-wings, decision-making costs and the unanimity rule. Public Choice (October): 25–38.

  • Landa, J.T. & A. Wallis. 1988. The socio-economic organization of honeybee colonics: a transaction cost approach. J. Social Biol. Structures 11: 353–363.

    Google Scholar 

  • Landa, J.T. 1994. Trust, ethnicity, and identity: beyond the new institutional economics of ethnic trading networks, contract law, and gift-exchange. The University of Michigan Press, Ann Arbor. 225 pp.

    Google Scholar 

  • Landa, J.T. & G. Tullock. 1995. Why ants do but bees don't construct satellite nests. Paper presented at the 'Bioeconomics' panel, at the Western Econ. Assoc. Intern. Conference, 5–9 July, San Diego.

  • Landeau, L. & J. Terborgh. 1986. Oddity and the 'confusion effect' in predation. Anim. Behav. 34: 1372–1380.

    Google Scholar 

  • Major, P.F. 1978. Predator-prey interaction in two schooling fishes, Caranx ignobillis and Stolephorus purpureus. Anim. Behav. 26: 760–777.

    Google Scholar 

  • Magurran, A.E. & S.L. Girling. 1986. Predator recognition and response habituation in shoaling minnows. Anim. Behav. 34: 510–518.

    Google Scholar 

  • Magurran, A.E. & T.J. Pitcher. 1987. Provenance, shoal size and the sociobiology of predator-evasion behaviour in minnow shaols. Proc. R. Soc. 229B: 439–465.

    Google Scholar 

  • Miller, R.C. 1922. The significance of the gregarious habit. Ecology 3: 122–126.

    Google Scholar 

  • Milinski, M. 1977. Do all members of a swarm suffer the same predation? Z. Tierpsychol. 45: 373–388.

    Google Scholar 

  • Morgan, M.J. & T.G.J. Godin. 1986. Antipredator benefits of schooling behaviour in a cyprinodontid fish, the banded killifish (Fundulus diaphanus). Z. Tierpsychol. 70: 236–246.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mueller, D.C. 1989. Public choice II. A revised edition of Public Choice. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, 518 pp.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ohguchi, O. 1981. Prey density and selection against oddity by three-spined sticklebacks. J. Comp. Ethology (Supplement vn23): 9–79.

    Google Scholar 

  • Olson, M. 1965. The logic of collective action. Harvard University Press, Cambridge, 176 pp.

    Google Scholar 

  • Partridge, B.L. 1980. The effect of school size on the structure and dynamics of minnow schools. Anim. Behav. 28: 68–77.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pitcher, T.J. & J.K. Parrish. 1993. Functions of shoaling behaviour in teleosts. pp. 363–439. In: T.J. Pitcher (ed.) Behaviour of Teleost Fishes, Chapman & Hall, London.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pitcher, T.J., C.J. Wyche & A.F. Magurran. 1982. Evidence for position preferences in schooling mackerel. Anim. Behav. 30: 932–934.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pitcher, T.J. & C.J. Wyche. 1983. Predator-avoidance behaviours of sand-cel schools: why schools seldom split? pp. 193–204. In: D.L.G. Noakes, D.G. Lindquist, G.S. Helfman & J.A. Ward (ed.) Predator and prey in Fishes, Developments in Env. Biol. Fish. 2, Dr. W. Junk Publishers, The Hague.

    Google Scholar 

  • Quinn, T.P. & C.A. Busack. 1985. Chemosensory recognition of siblings in juvenile coho salmon Oncorhynchus kisutch. Anim. Behav. 33: 51–56.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ranta, E. 1993. There is no optimal foraging group size. Anim. Behav. 46: 1032–1035.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sandler, T. 1992. Collective action: theory and applications. The University of Michigan Press, Ann Arbor. 237 pp.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sandler, T. & J. Tschirhart. 1995. Club theory: thirty years later. Paper presented at the Allied Social Science Associations Meetings, 6–9 January, Washington, D.C.

  • Shaw, E. 1962. The schooling of fishes. Sci. Amer. 206: 128–138.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shaw, E. 1978. Schooling fishes. Amer. Sci. 66: 166–175.

    Google Scholar 

  • Spence, A.M. 1974. Market signaling: informational transfer in hiring and related screening processes. Harvard University Press, Cambridge, 221 pp.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sibly, R.M. 1983. Optimal group size is unstable. Anim. Behav. 31: 947–948.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tiebout, C.M. 1956. A pure theory of local expenditures. J. Pol. Econ. 64: 416–424.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tollison, R.P. 1972. Consumption sharing and non-exclusion rules. Economica 39: 271–291.

    Google Scholar 

  • Treisman, M. 1975. Predation and the evolution of gregariousness. I. Models for concealment and evasion. Anim. Behav. 23: 779–800.

    Google Scholar 

  • Trivers, R.I. 1971. The evolution of reciprocal altruism. Quart. Rev. Biol. 46: 35–57.

    Google Scholar 

  • Van Havre, N. & G.J. FitzGerald. 1988. Shoaling and kin recognition in the threespine stickleback (Gasterosteus aculeatus L.). Biol. Behav. 13: 190–201.

    Google Scholar 

  • Webb, P.W. 1976. The effect on size on the fast-start performance of rainbow trout and a consideration of piscivorous predatorprey interactions. J. Exp. Biol. 65: 157–177.

    Google Scholar 

  • Weihs, D. 1973. Hydromechanics of fish schooling. Nature 241: 290–291.

    Google Scholar 

  • Weihs, D. 1975. Some hydrodynamical aspects of fish schooling. pp. 703–718. In: T.Y. Wu, C.J. Broklaw & C. Brennan (ed.) Symposium on Swimming and Flying in Nature, Plenum Press, New York.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Landa, J.T. Bioeconomics of schooling fishes: selfish fish, quasi-free riders, and other fishy tales. Environmental Biology of Fishes 53, 353–364 (1998). https://doi.org/10.1023/A:1007414603324

Download citation

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1023/A:1007414603324

Navigation