Skip to main content
Log in

Information aggregation and computational intelligence

Limits to price discovery

  • Article
  • Published:
Evolutionary and Institutional Economics Review Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This study examines the possibility that the computational intelligence (CI) inspired tools can effectively aggregate the rich information generated from the Web 2.0 economy and, thereby, enhance the quality of decision-making. Despite many advancements and commendable applications of CI in recent years, this issue has not been well addressed. We argue that this question is intimately related to the central issue of the socialist calculation debate since the time of Friedrich Hayek. In terms of information aggregation, we examine whether there is a better engineering than the market mechanism. More precisely, we focus on whether the CI-driven sentiment analysis can generate signals like prices and whether CI can process unstructured text data better than the market. We argue that Web 2.0 economy may not be able to set us free from information overload problems that have long coexisted with the presence of markets. We attribute this to the tacitness and subjectivity of knowledge and the recursive (feedback) characteristic of the sentiments. In this sense, Hayek’s fundamental assertion that the effectiveness of the market mechanism may not be so much conditioned on the information and communication technology still applies.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. The term Web 2.0 was popularized by Tim O’Reilly in 2004. O’Reilly and Battelle (O’Reilly and Battelle 2009) provide a systematic guide to the origin and development of Web 2.0.

  2. Unstructured information refers to the absence of a clearly defined data model, such as relational, hierarchical, network etc, according to which the information is organized.

  3. The following can be regarded as an intuitive definition of sentiment analysis: ‘Sentiment analysis or opinion mining is the computational study of peoples opinions, appraisals, attitudes, and emotions toward entities, individuals, issues, events, topics and their attributes. The task is technically challenging and practically very useful. For example, businesses always want to find public or consumer opinions about their products and services. Potential customers also want to know the opinions of the existing users before they use a service or purchase a product.’ - p. 415, Liu and Zhang (2012).

  4. Pooling and processing often assume that the information or knowledge is iid and not interdependent.

  5. Hayek did use the term ‘symbol’ in his discussion on the marvels of the price system. “In abbreviated form, by a kind of symbol, only the most essential information is passed on, and passed on only to those concerned. (Ibid, p. 527; Italics added.)” A broader interpretation of prices as symbols makes it easier to see the relevance of Hayek’s analysis to the modern Web 2.0 economy, in which the use of the sentiment analysis to the big data available in the social media network, such as FinanceTwitter, normally leads to many linguistic-type indices, rather than numerical prices.

  6. A detailed discussion of this feasibility is beyond the size of a chapter. The interested reader is referred to Chen (2015); specifically, those models involve the use of sunspot variables.

  7. The use of statistical tools to understand patterns in textual data has a long history in linguistics. In the 1930s, the American linguist George Kingsley Zipf studied the distribution of words in natural language (Zipf 1936, 1949) and observed that there was a proportional relationship between the frequency of word occurrence and its rank in the frequency list. This relationship is now popularly known as the Zipf’s law.

  8. This can be taken to further granular or advanced levels such as 5-point scale for classifying the opinions based on more precise moods (supportive, confused, excited, sad, and so on).

  9. However, we do not diminish the achievements made in processing opinions or subjective text over the years; see Liu and Zhang (2012), Sects. 3–6.

  10. For instance, Liu and Zhang (2012) notes that

    Moreover, it is also known that human analysis of textual information is subject to considerable psychological biases, e.g., people often pay greater attention to opinions that are consistent with their own preferences. People also have difficulty, owing to their mental and physical limitations, producing consistent results when the amount of information to be processed is large. Automated opinion mining and summarization systems are thus needed, as subjective biases and mental limitations can be overcome with an objective sentiment analysis system. (Ibid, p.415–416; Emphasis added.)

  11. It should be noted that the possibility of ‘emergence’ is another aspect of these systems that make prediction hard, even in theory. For instance, if the changes or shifts in beliefs held by agents in a market or a society are themselves ‘emergent’, then predicting them based on the information concerning micro-states (agents and their tweets) can be a difficult task.

  12. See p. 828, Tables 1 and 2 in Li et al. (2014) for a useful summary.

  13. See Murthy (2015), who argues that twitter feeds play more of a reactive rather than predictive role in elections.

  14. See Otnes (2011) for a detailed discussion on this issue.

  15. Vogt and De Boer Vogt and De Boer (2010) further distinguish two types of agent-based models of language evolution, namely, agent-based analytical model and agent-based cognitive model. For a list of examples on each, the interested reader is referred to Vogt and De Boer (2010), p. 8.

References

  • Aggarwal C, Zhai C (2012a) An introduction to text mining. In: Aggarwal C, Zhai C (eds) Mining text data, chapter 1. Springer, Berlin

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Aggarwal C, Zhai C (2012b) A survey of text clustering algorithms. In: Aggarwal C, Zhai C (eds) Mining text data, chapter 4. Springer, Berlin

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Aghion P, Holden R (2011) Incomplete contracts and the theory of the firm: what have we learned over the past 25 years? J Econ Perspect 25(2):181–197

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Akhtar J, Koshul B, Awais M (2013) A framework for evolutionary algorithms based on Charles Sanders Peirce’s evolutionary semiotics. Inf Sci 236:93–108

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Al-Najjar N, Anderlini L, Felli L (2006) Undescribable events. Rev Econ Stud 73:849–868

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Angeletos G-M, La’O J (2013) Sentiments. Econometrica 81:739779

    Google Scholar 

  • Antenucci D, Cafarella M, Levenstein M, Ré C, Shapiro M (2014) Using Social media to measure labor market flows. NBER Working Paper, No. 20010

  • Arrow K, Bernheim B, Feldstein M, McFadden D, Poterba J, Solow R (2011) 100 years of the American economic review: the top 20 articles. Am Econ Rev 101(1):1–8

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aubert K (1982a) Accurate predictions and fixed point theorems. Soc Sci Inf 21(3):323–348

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aubert K (1982b) Accurate predictions and fixed point theorems: a reply to Simon. Soc Sci Inf 21(4–5):612–622

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aubert K (1987) Fixed-point theorems and public prediction of social behavior. Adv Appl Math 8(1):17

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • (2000) Socialism and the market: the socialist calculation debate revisited, vol 9. Routledge, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Bollen J, Mao H, Zeng X (2011) Twitter mood predicts the stock market. J Comput Sci 2(1):1–8

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bozbay I, Dietrich F, Peter H (2014) Judgment aggregation in search for the truth. Games Econ Behav 87:571–590

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Butler D (2013) When Google got flu wrong. Nature 494:155–156

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chen S-H (2015) Agent-based computational ecnomics: how the idea originated and where it is going. Routledge, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Choi H, Varian H (2012) Predicting the present with Google trends. Econ Rec 88:2–9

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cockshott W, Cottrell A (1997) Information and economics: a critique of Hayek. Res Polit Econ 18(1):177–202

    Google Scholar 

  • Crawford K, Gray M, Miltner K (2014) Critiquing big data: politics, ethics, epistemology—introduction to special section. Int J Commun 8:1663–1672

    Google Scholar 

  • Dietrich F (2006) Judgment aggregation: (im)possibility theorems. J Econ Theory 126(1):286–298

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dredze M (2012) How social media will change public health. IEEE Intell Syst 27(4):81–84

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gayo-Avello D (2012) No, you cannot predict elections with Twitter. IEEE Internet Comput 16(6):91–94

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gong T, Shuai L (2013) Computer simulation as a scientific approach in evolutionary linguistics. Language Sci 40:12–23

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Granovetter M (1973) The strength of weak ties. Am J Sociol 78(6):1360–1380

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hart O, Moore J (1999) Foundations of incomplete contracts. Rev Econ Stud 66(1):115–138

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hayek F (1937) Economics and knowledge. Economica 4:33–54

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hayek F (1945) The uses of knowledge in society. Am Econ Rev 35(4):519–530

    Google Scholar 

  • Hayek F (1952) The sensory order: an inquiry into the foundations of theoretical psychology. University of Chicago Press, Chicago

    Google Scholar 

  • Hodgson R, Maloney J (2013) Bandwagon effects in British elections, 1885–1910. Public Choice 157:73–90

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Holland J, Holyoak K, Nisbett R (1986) Induction: processes of inference, learning and discovery (computational models of cognition and perception). MIT Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Hu X, Liu H (2012) Text anlaytics in social media. In: Aggarwal C, Zhai C (eds) Mining text data, chapter 12. Springer, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Jacoby J, Speller D, Kohn C (1974) Brand choice behavior as a function of information load. J Mark Res 11(1):63–69

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jacoby J, Speller D, Berning C (1974) Brand choice behavior as a function of information load: replication and extension. J Consum Res 1:33–42

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kim S, Kim D (2014) Investor sentiment from internet message postings and the predictability of stock returns. J Econ Behav Organ 107:708–729

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kiss Á, Simonovits G (2014) Identifying the bandwagon dffect in two-round elections. Public Choice 160:327–344

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lavoie D (1985) Rivalry and central planning: the socialist calculation debate reconsidered. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Lekvam T (2014) Co-evolving language and social structure using a genetic algorithm. Master Thesis, Department of Computer and Information Science, Norwegian University of Science and Technology

  • Lekvam T, Gambäck B, Bungum L (2014) Agent-based modeling of language evolution. In: Proceedings of the 5th Workshop on cognitive aspects of computational language learning, pp 49–54

  • Li X, Xie H, Chen L, Wang J, Deng X (2014) News impact on stock price return via sentiment analysis. Knowl Based Syst 69:14–23

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • List C (2012) The theory of judgment aggregation: an introductory review. Synthese 187(1):179–207

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Liu B, Zhang L (2012) A survey of opinion mining and sentiment analysis. In: Aggarwal C, Zhai C (eds) Mining text data, chapter 13. Springer, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Lukoianova T, Rubin V (2014) Veracity roadmap: is big data objective, truthful and credible? Adv Classif Res Online 24(1):4–15

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Metaxas P, Mustafaraj E, Gayo-Avello D (2011) How (not) to predict elections. In: Proceedings of Privacy, Security, Risk and Trust (PASSAT) and 2011 IEEE Third International Conference on Social Computing (SocialCom), 165–171

  • Mian A, Sufi A, Khoshkhou N (2015) Government economic policy, sentiments, and consumption, NBER Working Paper No. 21316

  • Milgram S (1967) The small world problem. Psychol Today 2:60–67

    Google Scholar 

  • Mo SYK, Liu A, Yang SY (2015) News sentiment to market impact and its feedback effect. Available at SSRN 2567433

  • Murthy D (2015) Twitter and elections: are tweets, predictive, reactive, or a form of buzz? Inf Commun Soc 18(7):816–831

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Netzer O, Feldman R, Goldenberg J, Fresko M (2012) Mine your own business: market-structure surveillance through text mining. Mark Sci 31(3):521–543

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nenkova A, McKeown K (2012) A survey of text summarization techniques. In: Aggarwal C, Zhai C (eds) Mining text data, chapter 3. Springer, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Nurse Rainbolt G, Onozaka Y, McFadden D (2012) Consumer motivations and buying behavior: the case of the local food system movement. J Food Prod Mark 18(5):385–396

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Battelle J (2009) Web squared: Web 2.0 five years on. O’Reilly Media, Sebastopol

    Google Scholar 

  • Otnes P (2011) Simon’s finals: can self-defeating predictions be righted beforehand? Sosiol Årbok 1–2:109–126

    Google Scholar 

  • Park D, Lee J (2009) eWOM overload and its effect on consumer behavioral intention depending on consumer involvement. Elect Commer Res Appl 7(4):386–398

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Polanyi M (1966) The tacit dimension. University of chicago Press, Chicago

    Google Scholar 

  • Posner R (2004) Introduction to the Becker-Posner blog. http://www.becker-posner-blog.com/archives/2004/12/introduction_to_1.html, Dec

  • Schroder H, Driver M, Streufert S (1967) Human information processing. Holt, Rinehart and Winston, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Simon H (1954) Bandwagon and underdog effects and the possibility of election predictions. Public Opin Q 18(3):245–253

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Simon H (1971) Designing organizations for an information-rich world. In: Greenberger M (ed) Computers. Communications and the public interest. Johns Hopkins University Press, Baltimore, pp 37–72

    Google Scholar 

  • Simon H (1982a) Accurate predictions and fixed point theorems: comments. Soc Sci Inf 21(4–5):605–612

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Simon H (1982b) A final comment. Soc Sci Inf 21:622–626

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Smith V (1982) Markets as economizers of information: experimental examination of the “Hayek Hypothesis”. Econ Inq 20(2):165–179

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sun Y, Deng H, Han J (2012) Probabilistic models for text mining. In: Aggarwal C, Zhai C (eds) Mining text data, chapter 8. Springer, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Sunstein C (2008) Neither Hayek nor Habermas. Public Choice 134:87–95

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tetlock P (2007) Giving content to investor sentiment: the role of media in the stock market. J Finance 62:1139–1168

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tetlock P, Saar-Tsechansky M, Macskassy S (2008) More than words: quantifying language to measure firms’ fundamentals. J Finance 63:1437–1467

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tirole J (1999) Incomplete contracts: where do we stand? Econometrica 67:741–781

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tumasjan A, Sprenger T, Sandner P, Welpe I (2010) Predicting elections with Twitter: what 140 Characters reveal about political sentiment. In: Proceedings of the fourth international AAAI conference on Weblogs and Social Media, 178–185

  • Velupillai K (2010) Computable foundations for economics. Routledge, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Vogt P, De Boer B (2010) Language evolution: computer models for empirical data. Adapt Behav 18(1):5–11

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Von Mises L (1935) Economic calculation in the socialist commonwealth. In: Hayek F (ed) Collectivist economic planning. Routledge and Kegan Paul, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Vriend N (2002) Was Hayek an ACE? South Econ J 68(4):811–840

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zipf G (1936) The psychobiology of language. Routledge, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Zipf G (1949) Human behavior and the principle of least effort. Addison-Wesley, New York

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Ragupathy Venkatachalam.

Ethics declarations

Conflict of interest

On behalf of all authors, the corresponding author states that there is no conflict of interest.

Additional information

The S.-H. Chen and the R. Venkatachalam are grateful for the research support in the form of Ministry of Science and Technology (MOST) grants, MOST 103-2410-H-004-009-MY3 and MOST 104-2811-H-004-003, respectively. We thank the two anonymous referees for their valuable suggestions that helped to improve the paper. All remaining errors are our own.

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Chen, SH., Venkatachalam, R. Information aggregation and computational intelligence. Evolut Inst Econ Rev 14, 231–252 (2017). https://doi.org/10.1007/s40844-016-0048-z

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s40844-016-0048-z

Keywords

JEL Classification:

Navigation