Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Welfare analysis of changing food prices: a nonparametric examination of rice policies in India

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Food Security Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The paper examines the welfare impact of the Indian government’s rice price policies in the light of the global food crisis of 2007–08 using a nonparametric approach for regression and density estimation. In particular, the impact of a ban on export of rice and increased farm gate price support for farmers, implemented to keep domestic consumer prices lower and producer prices higher than they would otherwise have been, was analysed. The net impact of the export ban was positive, as it was able to cushion the Indian population (84 % of whom are net consumers of rice) from the adverse effects of the crisis. However, the extent of welfare varied among different household types, as the poor in India are heterogeneous in nature. Thus agriculture-price policies do not have a homogenous effect on the poor in India. The majority of rice-producing farmers are relatively poor but benefitted from the increase in farm gate prices. Poor households that did not cultivate rice were the worst affected in the food crisis, as their budget share of rice is higher than that of rich households.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7
Fig. 8
Fig. 9
Fig. 10
Fig. 11
Fig. 12
Fig. 13
Fig. 14
Fig. 15
Fig. 16

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. The Indian government passed the food security bill, estimated to cost $4 billion per year and promises to feed 8 million people in the country (Economist, August 2014).

  2. WTO’s de minimis provision caps trade-distorting subsidies to farmers at 10 % of the total production value of a crop (WTO, n.d.).

  3. The levy set by the state governments can range between 30 to 75 % of milled rice (Department of Food & Public Distribution, n.d.).

  4. A combination of production support, import capacity along with the distribution and procurement mechanisms.

  5. FAO defines food security in terms of four dimensions: availability, access, utilisation (related to storage and physiological aspect of nutrition absorption) and stability of the other three dimensions over time (FAO 2008).

  6. Wholesale price index of rice with base 2004–05 (Ministry of Commerce and Industry 2005). Note that this is just an indicator of price inflation for rice in India.

  7. Price of White Broken Rice, Thai A1 Super, f.o.b Bangkok (USD/Ton) is used (FAO 2010)

  8. Also used by Deaton (1989), Budd and John (1993), Barrett and Dorosh (1996), Dávila (2010).

  9. Authors of the paper would like to thank the anonymous reviewers for their helpful and constructive comments that greatly contributed to improving the empirical framework of the paper.

  10. The theoretical details of this approach can be found in the appendix.

  11. There was no household consumer expenditure survey conducted for the year 2008–09.

  12. Based on authors calculations using (NSSO) data.

  13. Based on exchange rate: $1 = Rs45

  14. World prices are sourced from FAO.

  15. Based on authors calculations using (NSSO) data.

  16. Note that the poverty line used in the paper corresponds to the global poverty line of $1.25 or Rs.1687.5 (using an exchange rate of $1 = Rs.45) per day. This is different from the Indian estimates of poverty that stands at Rs. 972 in rural areas and Rs. 1407 in urban areas (Planning Commission, GOI 2014) or from the ones suggested by Ravallion (2008) that stand at Rs. 427.2 for rural and Rs 645.9 for urban areas, based on 2005 consumption purchasing power parity.

  17. Deaton’s paper on rice pricing policy in Thailand uses contour graphs generated on Gauss. This paper has used sunflower plots instead to represent the data. Both graph types are similar as they show the bivariate density. The visual impact of contours may be dominated by information about the tails of the distribution where very few observations exist, which is not the case in sunflower plots as these points are presented by the circles in these plots. Refer to appendix A2 for detailed understanding of the sunflower plots.

  18. The circles represent individual data points as in a conventional scatterplot. The light petal represents one observation, while in the dark petal represents k observations mentioned in the legend for each figure.

  19. Approximately $32 per month per person.

  20. Not all graphs for different household types are shown below.

  21. Note in all the sunflower plots there are circular markers detached from the petals, which represent individual observations in the data. As the density is very low at these points when we present the data in a form of a regression these outliers increase the roughness in the Engel curves. The roughness can be dealt with by widening the bandwidth of the curve. However, that may lead to oversmoothing of the curve and thus de-shape the curve. Therefore, for this graph the households above LMPCE 10 (95 of 143,408 observations) have not been considered for analysis.

  22. Note that net consumers are different from net producers as net producers are those households, which produce rice, however small or large the quantity may be. While, net consumers or net buyers are those households, which irrespective of producing or not producing rice have to go to the market to buy rice for consumption. Net sellers are the households, which produce enough rice for household consumption and also sell rice in the market.

  23. To predict these values, consumption and production of rice and expenditure levels for July-September 2009 are kept as constant (as we only have production data for 2009–10). Therefore the predicted net benefit is relative to the consumption and production values of July-September 2009, i.e. how much money the household would require in order to maintain the living standards observed during July-September 2009.

  24. For the purpose of the paper it is assumed that the farmers sell and buy rice only.

  25. For a detailed explanation of sunflower plots refer to Hardle (1990).

References

  • Acharya, S. S., Chand, P. S. R., Birthal, S. K., & Negi, D. S. (2012). Market integration and price transmission in India: A case of rice and wheat with special reference to the world food crisis of 2007/08. Rome: Food and Agriculture Organization. http://www.fao.org/3/a-an034e.pdf. Accessed 23 March 2003.

  • Barrett, C., & Dorosh, P. (1996). Farmers’ welfare and changing food prices: nonparametric evidence from rice in Madagascar. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 78(3), 656–669.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baylis, K., Jolejole-Foreman, M.C., & Mallory, M. (2013). Impact of wheat and rice export ban on Indian market integration. Paper presented at the Agricultural & Applied Economics Association’s 2013 AAEA & CAES Joint Annual Meeting, Washington, DC, August 4–6.

  • Budd, John W. (1993). Changing food prices and rural welfare: A nonparametric examination of the Côte D’Ivoire. Economic Development and Cultural Change, Vol. 41, No. 3 (Apr., 1993), P.587-603.

  • Chen, S., & Ravallion, M. (2010). The developing world is poorer than we thought, but no less successful in the fight against poverty. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 125(4), 1577–1625.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Datt, G., & Ravallion, M. (1998). Farm productivity and rural poverty in India. Journal of Development Studies, 34(4), 62–85.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dávila, O. G. (2010). Food security and poverty in Mexico: The impact of higher global food prices. Food Security, 2(4), 383–393.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Deaton, A. (1989). Rice prices and income distribution in Thailand: A Non-parametric analysis. Economic Journal, 99(395), 1–37.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Department of Food & Public Distribution (n.d). Issue of Levy Orders for Procurement of Levy Rice document for 2011–12 and 2012–13. http://Dfpd.Nic.In/?Q=Node/641. Accessed 4 August 2014.

  • Directorate of Rice Development (2013). Problems and prospects of rice export from India. In Rice Export from India booklet. http://drdpat.bih.nic.in/Rice%20Export.htm. Accessed 4 August 2014.

  • Dorosh, P., & Rashid, S. (2013). Trade subsidies, export bans and price stabilization: Lessons of Bangladesh - India rice trade in the 2000s. Food Policy, 41, 103–111.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Economist (August 2014). Bailing out from Bali http://Www.Economist.Com/News/Finance-And-Economics/21611088-Indias-Scuppering-Latest-Trade-Talks-Leaves-No-One-Better-Bailing-Out Accessed 5 August 2014.

  • FAO (2002). Sustainable rice production for food security. Proceedings of the 20th session of the International Rice Commission Bangkok, Thailand, 23–26 July 2002 http://Www.Fao.Org/Docrep/006/Y4751e/Y4751e00.HTM. Accessed 4 August 2014.

  • FAO (2008). An introduction to the basic concepts of food security. The EC - FAO Food Security Programme http://www.fao.org/docrep/013/al936e/al936e00.pdf . Accessed 4 August 2014.

  • FAO (2009). High food prices and the food crisis - Experiences and lessons learned. Rome: Food and Agriculture Organization. ftp://ftp.fao.org/docrep/fao/012/i0753e/i0753e.pdf. Accessed 23 March 2003.

  • FAO (2010). International Commodity Prices Data Base - Source For World Prices. Rome: Food and Agricultural Organization of the United Nations (FAO)

  • Financial Times (2012). India cuts fuel subsidies to curb deficit. September, 2012. Http://Www.Ft.Com/Cms/S/0/15e495a0-Fdbc-11e1-9901-00144feabdc0.Html#Axzz26eboixq4. Accessed 25 September 2013.

  • Geenens, G. (2011). Curse of dimensionality and related issues in nonparametric functional regression. Statistics Surveys, 5(2011), 1–71.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ganguly & Gulati (2013). The political economy of food price policy: The case study of India. WIDER Working WIDER Working Paper 2013/034. Helsinki: UNU-WIDER.

  • Gulati, A., & Dutta, M. (2010). Rice policies in India in the context of the global rice price spike. In D. Dawe (Ed.), The rice crisis: markets, policies and food security (pp. 273–95). London: Earthscan and FAO.

    Google Scholar 

  • Headey and Fan (2010). Reflections on the global food crisis: How did it happen? How has it hurt? And how can we prevent the next one?. Research report 165. International Food Policy Research Institute (IFPRI) Indian Economic Survey (2011–12).

  • Hardle, W. (1990). Applied nonparametric regression. Econometric Society Monographs No. 19, Cambridge University Press.

  • Headey, D., Chiu, A., & Kadiyala, S. (2012). Agriculture’s role in the Indian enigma: Help or hindrance to the crisis of undernutrition? Food Security, 4(1), 87–102.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kubo, K (2011). India: The burden of domestic food policy. In Shigetomi, S., Kubo, K., Tsukada, K., & Shigetomi, S. (2011). The world food crisis and the strategies of asian rice exporters. Chiba-Shi, Japón, Institute of Developing Economies, IDE-Jetro.

  • Lipton, M. (1986). Limits of price policy for agriculture: Which way for the World Bank? Development Policy Review, 5, 197–215.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ministry of Commerce & Industry (2005) Wholesale Price Index Base Year 2004–05.

  • National Statistical Survey Office (NSSO). 64th And 66th (Type-1) Consumer Household Expenditure Survey.

  • Planning Commission, GOI (2014). Report of the expert group to review the methodology for measurement of poverty, Government of India

  • Pons, N. (2011). Food and prices in India: Impact of rising food prices on welfare. Delhi: Centre De Sciences Humaines.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ravallion (2008). A global perspective on poverty in India. Economics and Political Weekly

  • Reuters (2008). WRAPUP 1-Vietnam Lifts Rice Export Ban, Manila Seals Deal, 18 June 2008. http://In.Reuters.Com/Article/2008/06/18/Rice-Idinsp7387020080618 Accessed 25 September 2013.

  • Ruel, M. T., Garrett, J. L., Hawkes, C., & Cohen, M. J. (2010). The food, fuel, and financial crises affect the urban and rural poor disproportionately: a review of the evidence. The Journal of Nutrition, 140, 170S–176S.

    Article  CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  • Sharma (2011). Food export restrictions: review of the 2007-2010 experience and considerations for disciplining restrictive measures, FAO commoduty and trade policy research working paper No.32

  • The Economics Times (2012). Government allows exports of more non-basmati rice and sugar. February 2012 http://Articles.Economictimes.Indiatimes.Com/2012-02-08/News/31037673_1_Minimum-Export-Price-Vijay-Setia-Rice-Exports. Accessed 25 September 2012.

  • USDA (2007). Indian wheat and rice sector policies and the implications of reform. Economic Research Report United States. Dept. of Agriculture. Economic Research Service.

  • USDA (2008). Indian rice export imbroglio. Unpublished Report Dated May 21, 2008

  • Wailes, E. J. (2005). Rice: global trade, protectionist policies, and the impact of trade liberalization. In Aksoy, M. A & Beghin, J. C, Global agricultural trade and developing countries. Pp. 177–193

  • World Bank. (1994). Adjustment in Africa: Reforms, results and the road ahead. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • WTO (n.d.). Uruguay round agreement on agriculture. Http://Www.Wto.Org/English/Docs_E/Legal_E/14-Ag.Pdf. Accessed August 2014.

Download references

Conflict of interest

The author declares that they do not have a conflict of interest.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Ben Groom.

Appendices

Appendix

Derivation of the net benefit ratio (NBR)

Let us consider a household that consumes and possibly produces rice and participates in the economy by producing and selling other commodities and/or participating in the labour market. The household living standards can be represented by the indirect utility function given as

$$ {u}_h=\theta \left( wt+T+\pi, p\right) $$
(1)

Where u h is utility (or real income) of household h, w is the wage rate, t is the total time available, T is rental income, property income, or transfers, p is a price vector of commodities consumed, and \( \pi \) is the household’s profits from producing rice or other economic activities. As profits are maximised, \( \pi \) is taken as the value of a profit function, π(p, v, w) where v is a price vector of input prices, w is the wage rate, or vector of household wages, and p in this context is the vector of output prices for commodities produced by the household. The impact of change in price on the profits is captured by a standard property of the profit function given below.

$$ \frac{\partial {\pi}_h}{\partial {p}_i}={y}_i $$
(2)

Where \( {y}_i \) is the (gross) production of good i by the household h. If price of i, i.e. rice changes the effect on the real income of the household h, can be derived by taking the first derivative of the indirect utility function given by Eq. (1).

$$ \frac{\partial {u}_h}{\partial {p}_i}=\frac{\partial \theta }{\partial T}\;\frac{\partial \pi }{\partial {p}_i}+\frac{\partial \theta }{\partial {p}_i}=\frac{\partial \theta }{\partial {p}_i}\left({y}_i-{q}_i\right) $$
(3)

where q i is the consumption of good i (rice), and the second part of the equation is derived from the Roy’s identity.

The welfare benefit is defined as the amount of money (positive or negative) required by the household in order to maintain its previous level of living. So, if the change in price is \( d{p}_i \), then the required compensation \( dB \) is given by the equation,

$$ d\beta =\left({q}_i-{y}_i\right)d{p}_i={p}_i\left({q}_i-{y}_i\right)d\; ln\;{p}_i $$
(4)

dβ can be expressed as a fraction of household expenditure x, we divide the above equation by x to get,

$$ \frac{d\beta }{x}=\left({S}_i-\frac{p_i{y}_i}{x}\right)d\; ln\;{p}_i $$
(5)

Where Si = (pi qi/x) is the budget share of good i, and piyi/x is the value of production of i as a fraction (or multiple) of total household expenditure.Footnote 24

Or

$$ \frac{d\beta }{x}=NBR=\left(\frac{Total\ expenditure\ on\ rice- Value\ of\ rice\ produced}{Monthly\ per\ capita\ expenditure\mathrm{x} Household\ size}\right)d\; ln\;{p}_i $$

This equation will be used as a measure of welfare for households. \( \frac{d\beta }{x} \) is called the net benefit ratio (NBR) in the paper. The equation calculates the elasticity of the cost of living with respect to the price of good i (rice).

For the purpose of this paper the above formula was modified to accommodate changes in prices of both PDS and non-PDS rice. The final formula used to calculate the net benefit ratio is given below.

$$ \begin{array}{l}NBR\\ {}\kern0.36em =\left(\frac{Expenditure\ on\ PDS\ rice}{Total\ Household\ Expenditure}\right)\;d\; ln{p}_{PDS\; rice}\\ {}\kern3.58em +\left(\frac{Expenditure\ on\ nonPDS\ rice- Value\ of\ rice\ produced}{Total\ Household\; Expenditure}\right)\;d\ ln\ {p}_{nonPDS\; rice}\end{array} $$

Sunflower plots

figure c

Scatter plots of the entire data are very unclear and do not show the areas where the data are concentrated, due to overstriking of plot symbols (Dupont and Plummer, 2005). It is thus desirable to have a technique that allows us to see the areas where the data is concentrated. The sunflower plot allows us to do so. The sunflower plot is based on the number of squares covering the (X, Y) space and the number of observations that lie in disjoint squares. The number of spikes in the hexagon shaped sunflower blossom or hexagon is equal to the number of petals in the sunflower. The petals correspond to the number of observations in the square around the sunflower. That is, it shows the empirical distribution of the underlying data (Hardle 1990)..Footnote 25

The Figure A1 and A2 map the budget share of rice and the log of monthly per capita expenditure (LMPCE) for the whole dataset (both rounds). When we compare the local polynomial smooth figure A1, which is essentially a scatter plot of the two variables we are only able to see the various points where the data are observed. We are also able to the see that the regression line cuts the area mapped in the graph in the lower half of the grey shaded area, indicating that majority of the observations are in the lower half of the shaded area. However, when we look at the sunflower plot below (figure A2) we can see that the regions where the data is concentrated. This allows us to understand the distribution in a more comprehensive manner. The circles depict the individual observations at their exact location. Light sunflowers are grey and represent one observation for each petal. Dark sunflowers are black and represent 270 observations per petal. This graph not only shows us the density distribution of the observations, but also allows us to determine the number of observations in a particular region with great precision (Dupont and Plummer, 2005).

Through this graph we can thus conclude that the budget share of rice as a percentage of the expenditure is concentrated around 20 % for households on the left of the graph. The sunflower plot also allows us to see the diversity in consumption patterns for households at different expenditure levels. Below the average LMPCE levels (7.03) the households are more diverse in the patterns of consumption of rise. The rice share percentage is generally below 60 %. For LMPCE levels over 7 the rice share percentage drops below 40 %. The density of the graph also increases and is generally consistent in terms of the shading. Thus we conclude that the households below the LMPCE levels of 7 (mean) are more vulnerable to the change in price of rice as their budget share of rice is more diverse ranging between 0.004 and 80 %. The richer households are fairly resilient to the change in price.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Groom, B., Tak, M. Welfare analysis of changing food prices: a nonparametric examination of rice policies in India. Food Sec. 7, 121–141 (2015). https://doi.org/10.1007/s12571-014-0413-x

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s12571-014-0413-x

Keywords

Navigation