Skip to main content
Log in

Group Decision Making with Dual Hesitant Fuzzy Preference Relations

  • Published:
Cognitive Computation Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Background/Introduction

Due to the complexity and uncertainty of socioeconomic environments and cognitive diversity of group members, the cognitive information over alternatives provided by a decision organization consisting of several experts is usually uncertain and hesitant. Hesitant fuzzy preference relations provide a useful means to represent the hesitant cognitions of the decision organization over alternatives, which describe the possible degrees that one alternative is preferred to another by using a set of discrete values. However, in order to depict the cognitions over alternatives more comprehensively, besides the degrees that one alternative is preferred to another, the decision organization would give the degrees that the alternative is non-preferred to another, which may be a set of possible values. To effectively handle such common cases, in this paper, the dual hesitant fuzzy preference relation (DHFPR) is introduced and the methods for group decision making (GDM) with DHFPRs are investigated.

Methods

Firstly, a new operator to aggregate dual hesitant fuzzy cognitive information is developed, which treats the membership and non-membership information fairly, and can generate more neutral results than the existing dual hesitant fuzzy aggregation operators. Since compatibility is a very effective tool to measure the consensus in GDM with preference relations, then two compatibility measures for DHFPRs are proposed. After that, the developed aggregation operator and compatibility measures are applied to GDM with DHFPRs and two GDM methods are designed, which can be applied to different decision making situations.

Results and Conclusions

Each GDM method involves a consensus improving model with respect to DHFPRs. The model in the first method reaches the desired consensus level by adjusting the group members’ preference values, and the model in the second method improves the group consensus level by modifying the weights of group members according to their contributions to the group decision, which maintains the group members’ original opinions and allows the group members not to compromise for reaching the desired consensus level. In actual applications, we may choose a proper method to solve the GDM problems with DHFPRs in light of the actual situation. Compared with the GDM methods with IVIFPRs, the proposed methods directly apply the original DHFPRs to decision making and do not need to transform them into the IVIFPRs, which can avoid the loss and distortion of original information, and thus can generate more precise decision results.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  1. Meng F, Chen X. Correlation coefficients of hesitant fuzzy sets and their application based on fuzzy measures. Cogn Comput. 2015;7(4):445–63.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  2. Meng F, Wang C, Chen X. Linguistic interval hesitant fuzzy sets and their application in decision making. Cogn Comput. 2016;8(1):52–68.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  3. Xu ZS, Zhao N. Information fusion for intuitionistic fuzzy decision making: an overview. Inf Fusion. 2016;28:10–23.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  4. Lee VK, Harris LT. How social cognition can inform social decision making. Front Neurosci. 2013;7:259.

    PubMed  PubMed Central  Google Scholar 

  5. Yang L, Jiang M. Dynamic group decision making consistence convergence rate analysis based on inertia particle swarm optimization algorithm. In: International joint conference on artificial intelligence, Hainan Island, 2009. p. 492–496.

  6. Brabec CM, Gfeller JD, Ross MJ. An exploration of relationships among measures of social cognition, decision making, and emotional intelligence. J Clin Exp Neuropsychol. 2012;34(8):887–94.

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  7. Czubenko M, Kowalczuk Z, Ordys A. Autonomous driver based on an intelligent system of decision-making. Cogn Comput. 2015;7(5):569–81.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  8. Hei YQ, Li WT, Li M, Qiu Z, Fu WH. Optimization of multiuser MIMO cooperative spectrum sensing in cognitive radio networks. Cogn Comput. 2014;7(3):359–68.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  9. Haikonen POA. Yes and no: match/mismatch function in cognitive robots. Cogn Comput. 2014;6(2):158–63.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  10. Orlovsky SA. Decision-making with a fuzzy preference relation. Fuzzy Sets Syst. 1978;1(3):155–67.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  11. Herrera F, Herrera-Viedma E, Chiclana F. Multiperson decision-making based on multiplicative preference relations. Eur J Oper Res. 2001;129(2):372–85.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  12. Xu ZS. Compatibility analysis of intuitionistic fuzzy preference relations in group decision making. Group Decis Negot. 2013;22(3):463–82.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  13. Liao HC, Xu ZS, Xia MM. Multiplicative consistency of interval-valued intuitionistic fuzzy preference relation. J Intell Fuzzy Syst. 2014;27(6):2969–85.

    Google Scholar 

  14. Xia MM, Xu ZS. Managing hesitant information in GDM problems under fuzzy and multiplicative preference relations. Int J Uncertain Fuzzy Knowl Based Syst. 2013;21(6):865–97.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  15. Torra V. Hesitant fuzzy sets. Int J Intell Syst. 2010;25(6):529–39.

    Google Scholar 

  16. Zhu B, Xu ZS, Xia MM. Dual hesitant fuzzy sets. J Appl Math. 2012;11:2607–45.

    Google Scholar 

  17. Chen N, Xu ZS, Xia MM. Interval-valued hesitant preference relations and their applications to group decision making. Knowl Based Syst. 2013;37:528–40.

    Article  CAS  Google Scholar 

  18. Wei GW, Zhao XF. Induced hesitant interval-valued fuzzy Einstein aggregation operators and their application to multiple attribute decision making. J Intell Fuzzy Syst. 2013;24(4):789–803.

    Google Scholar 

  19. Qian G, Wang H, Feng XQ. Generalized hesitant fuzzy sets and their application in decision support system. Knowl Based Syst. 2013;37(4):357–65.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  20. Yu DJ. Triangular hesitant fuzzy set and its application to teaching quality evaluation. J Inf Comput Sci. 2013;10(7):1925–34.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  21. Zhu B, Xu ZS. Some results for dual hesitant fuzzy sets. J Intell Fuzzy Syst. 2014;26(4):1657–68.

    Google Scholar 

  22. Ju Y, Zhang W, Yang S. Some dual hesitant fuzzy Hamacher aggregation operators and their applications to multiple attribute decision making. J Intell Fuzzy Syst. 2014;27(5):2481–95.

    Google Scholar 

  23. Wang H, Zhao X, Wei G. Dual hesitant fuzzy aggregation operators in multiple attribute decision making. J Intell Fuzzy Syst. 2014;26(5):2281–90.

    Google Scholar 

  24. Yu D. Some generalized dual hesitant fuzzy geometric aggregation operators and applications. Int J Uncertain Fuzzy Knowl Based Syst. 2014;22(3):367–84.

    Article  CAS  Google Scholar 

  25. Singh P. A new method for solving dual hesitant fuzzy assignment problems with restrictions based on similarity measure. Appl Soft Comput. 2014;24:559–71.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  26. Ye J. Correlation coefficient of dual hesitant fuzzy sets and its application to multiple attribute decision making. Appl Math Model. 2014;38(2):659–66.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  27. Ren ZL, Wei CP. A multi-attribute decision-making method with prioritization relationship and dual hesitant fuzzy decision information. Int J Mach Learn Cybern. 2015. doi:10.1007/s13042-015-0356-3.

    Google Scholar 

  28. Yu DJ, Li DF. Dual hesitant fuzzy multi-criteria decision making and its application to teaching quality assessment. J Intell Fuzzy Syst. 2014;27(4):1679–88.

    Google Scholar 

  29. Lehner P, Seyed-Solorforough MM, Connor MFO, Sak S, Mullin T. Cognitive biases and time stress in team decision making. IEEE Trans Syst Man Cybern A Syst Hum. 1997;27(5):698–703.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  30. Mohammed S. Toward an understanding of cognitive consensus in a group decision-making context. J Appl Behav Sci. 2001;37(4):408–25.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  31. Mohammed S, Ringseis E. Cognitive diversity and consensus in group decision making: the role of inputs, processes, and outcomes. Organ Behav Hum Decis Process. 2001;85(2):310–35.

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  32. James LR, Demaree RG, Wolf G. Estimating within-group interrater reliability with and without response bias. J Appl Psychol. 1984;69(1):85–98.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  33. Allison PD. Measures of inequality. Am Sociol Rev. 1978;43:865–80.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  34. Xu ZS, Cai X. Group consensus algorithms based on preference relations. Inf Sci. 2011;181(1):150–62.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  35. Saaty TL, Vargas LG. Dispersion of group judgements. Comput Math Model. 2007;46(7):918–25.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  36. Xu ZS. On compatibility of interval fuzzy preference relations. Fuzzy Optim Decis Mak. 2004;3(3):217–25.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  37. Jiang Y, Xu ZS, Yu XH. Compatibility measures and consensus models for group decision making with intuitionistic multiplicative preference relations. Appl Soft Comput. 2013;13(4):2075–86.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  38. Chen H, Zhou L, Han B. On compatibility of uncertain additive linguistic preference relations and its application in the group decision making. Knowl Based Syst. 2011;24(6):816–23.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  39. Roubens M. Fuzzy sets and decision analysis. Fuzzy Sets Syst. 1997;90(90):199–206.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  40. Wang C, Li Q, Zhou X. Multiple attribute decision making based on generalized aggregation operators under dual hesitant fuzzy environment. J Appl Math. 2014;2:2577–92.

    Google Scholar 

  41. Ju Y, Yang S, Liu X. Some new dual hesitant fuzzy aggregation operators based on Choquet integral and their applications to multiple attribute decision making. J Intell Fuzzy Syst. 2014;27(6):2857–68.

    Google Scholar 

  42. Zhang Y. Research on the computer network security evaluation based on the DHFHCG operator with dual hesitant fuzzy information. J Intell Fuzzy Syst. 2015;28(1):199–204.

    Google Scholar 

  43. Xu Y, Rui D, Wang H. Dual hesitant fuzzy interaction operators and their application to group decision making. J Ind Prod Eng. 2015;32(4):273–90.

    Google Scholar 

  44. Xia MM, Xu ZS. Entropy/cross entropy-based group decision making under intuitionistic fuzzy environment. Inf Fusion. 2012;13(1):31–47.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  45. Harsanyi JC. Cardinal welfare, individualistic ethics, and interpersonal comparisons of utility. Netherlands: Springer; 1980.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  46. Xu ZS. On consistency of the weighted geometric mean complex judgment matrix in AHP. Eur J Oper Res. 2000;126(3):683–7.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  47. Xu ZS. A method based on linguistic aggregation operators for group decision making with linguistic preference relations. Inf Sci. 2004;166(1):19–30.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  48. Ben-Arieh D, Chen Z. Linguistic-labels aggregation and consensus measure for autocratic decision making using group recommendations. IEEE Trans Syst Man Cybern A Syst Hum. 2006;36(3):558–68.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  49. Hwang CL, Yoon K. Multiple attributes decision making methods and applications. Berlin: Springer; 1981.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  50. Herrera-Viedma E, Herrera F, Chiclana F. A consensus model for multiperson decision making with different preference structures. IEEE Trans Syst Man Cybern A Syst Hum. 2002;32(3):394–402.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

The work was supported by the National Natural Science Foundation of China (Nos. 61273209 and 71571123), the Fundamental Research Funds for the Central Universities (No. KYLX_0207) and the Scientific Research Foundation of Graduate School of Southeast University (No. YBJJ1527).

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Zeshui Xu.

Ethics declarations

Conflict of Interest

Na Zhao, Zeshui Xu and Fengjun Liu declare that they have no conflict of interest.

Informed Consent

Informed consent was not required as no human or animals were involved.

Human and Animal Rights

This article does not contain any studies with human or animal subjects performed by any of the authors.

Appendix

Appendix

According to the fact that the envelope of the DHFE d = (h, g) is the IVIFV ([γ , γ +], [η , η +]), where γ and η are the minimum elements in h and g, respectively, and γ + and η + are the corresponding maximum elements [21], the DHFPRs U (1)U (3) are transformed into the following IVIFPRs \( \widetilde{U}^{(1)} - \widetilde{U}^{(3)} \):

$$ \widetilde{U}^{(1)} = \left( {\begin{array}{*{20}c} {([0.5,0.5],[0.5,0.5])} & {([0.2,0.5],[0.3,0.5])} & {([0.2,0.4],[0.1,0.6])} & {([0.2,0.7],[0.1,0.2])} & {([0.2,0.5],[0.1,0.5])} & {([0.1,0.8],[0.1,0.2])} \\ {([0.3,0.5],[0.2,0.5])} & {([0.5,0.5],[0.5,0.5])} & {([0.25,0.8],[0.1,0.2])} & {([0.3,0.3],[0.1,0.7])} & {([0.3,0.5],[0.15,0.4])} & {([0.2,0.3],[0.2,0.7])} \\ {([0.1,0.6],[0.2,0.4])} & {([0.1,0.2],[0.25,0.8])} & {([0.5,0.5],[0.5,0.5])} & {([0.3,0.6],[0.1,0.4])} & {([0.2,0.5],[0.1,0.5])} & {([0.3,0.6],[0.2,0.4])} \\ {([0.1,0.2],[0.2,0.7])} & {([0.1,0.7],[0.3,0.3])} & {([0.1,0.4],[0.3,0.6])} & {([0.5,0.5],[0.5,0.5])} & {([0.1,0.3],[0.2,0.6])} & {([0.4,0.6],[0.1,0.3])} \\ {([0.1,0.5],[0.2,0.5])} & {([0.15,0.4],[0.3,0.5])} & {([0.1,0.5],[0.2,0.5])} & {([0.2,0.6],[0.1,0.3])} & {([0.5,0.5],[0.5,0.5])} & {([0.55,0.8],[0.05,0.2])} \\ {([0.1,0.2],[0.1,0.8])} & {([0.2,0.7],[0.2,0.3])} & {([0.2,0.4],[0.3,0.6])} & {([0.1,0.3],[0.4,0.6])} & {([0.05,0.2],[0.55,0.8])} & {([0.5,0.5],[0.5,0.5])} \\ \end{array} } \right), $$
$$ \widetilde{U}^{(2)} = \left( {\begin{array}{*{20}c} {([0.5,0.5],[0.5,0.5])} & {([0.3,0.7],[0.15,0.3])} & {([0.4,0.6],[0.3,0.4])} & {([0.2,0.7],[0.1,0.3])} & {([0.1,0.4],[0.1,0.6])} & {([0.3,0.9],[0.05,0.1])} \\ {([0.15,0.3],[0.3,0.7])} & {([0.5,0.5],[0.5,0.5])} & {([0.1,0.7],[0.1,0.3])} & {([0.15,0.4],[0.05,0.6])} & {([0.1,0.6],[0.2,0.4])} & {([0.1,0.45],[0.2,0.55])} \\ {([0.3,0.4],[0.4,0.6])} & {([0.1,0.3],[0.1,0.7])} & {([0.5,0.5],[0.5,0.5])} & {([0.3,0.5],[0.2,0.5])} & {([0.3,0.6],[0.15,0.4])} & {([0.1,0.7],[0.1,0.3])} \\ {([0.1,0.3],[0.2,0.7])} & {([0.05,0.6],[0.15,0.4])} & {([0.2,0.5],[0.3,0.5])} & {([0.5,0.5],[0.5,0.5])} & {([0.1,0.2],[0.3,0.7])} & {([0.4,0.6],[0.1,0.2])} \\ {([0.1,0.6],[0.1,0.4])} & {([0.2,0.4],[0.1,0.6])} & {([0.15,0.4],[0.3,0.6])} & {([0.3,0.7],[0.1,0.2])} & {([0.5,0.5],[0.5,0.5])} & {([0.5,0.8],[0.15,0.2])} \\ {([0.05,0.1],[0.3,0.9])} & {([0.2,0.55],[0.1,0.45])} & {([0.1,0.3],[0.1,0.7])} & {([0.1,0.2],[0.4,0.6])} & {([0.15,0.2],[0.5,0.8])} & {([0.5,0.5],[0.5,0.5])} \\ \end{array} } \right), $$
$$ \widetilde{U}^{(3)} = \left( {\begin{array}{*{20}c} {([0.5,0.5],[0.5,0.5])} & {([0.1,0.65],[0.1,0.35])} & {([0.1,0.3],[0.25,0.65])} & {([0.2,0.7],[0.05,0.3])} & {([0.15,0.35],[0.5,0.65])} & {([0.25,0.8],[0.1,0.2])} \\ {([0.1,0.35],[0.1,0.65])} & {([0.5,0.5],[0.5,0.5])} & {([0.3,0.8],[0.15,0.2])} & {([0.2,0.2],[0.1,0.8])} & {([0.1,0.4],[0.3,0.6])} & {([0.1,0.3],[0.1,0.7])} \\ {([0.25,0.65],[0.1,0.3])} & {([0.15,0.2],[0.3,0.8])} & {([0.5,0.5],[0.5,0.5])} & {([0.2,0.6],[0.3,0.4])} & {([0.3,0.3],[0.05,0.7])} & {([0.1,0.6],[0.1,0.4])} \\ {([0.05,0.3],[0.2,0.7])} & {([0.1,0.8],[0.2,0.2])} & {([0.3,0.4],[0.2,0.6])} & {([0.5,0.5],[0.5,0.5])} & {([0.2,0.3],[0.2,0.7])} & {([0.1,0.4],[0.2,0.6])} \\ {([0.5,0.65],[0.15,0.35])} & {([0.3,0.6],[0.1,0.4])} & {([0.05,0.7],[0.3,0.3])} & {([0.2,0.7],[0.2,0.3])} & {([0.5,0.5],[0.5,0.5])} & {([0.15,0.6],[0.05,0.4])} \\ {([0.1,0.2],[0.25,0.8])} & {([0.1,0.7],[0.1,0.3])} & {([0.1,0.4],[0.1,0.6])} & {([0.2,0.6],[0.1,0.4])} & {([0.05,0.4],[0.15,0.6])} & {([0.5,0.5],[0.5,0.5])} \\ \end{array} } \right). $$

Then by Eq. (12) in Ref. [12], the transformed IVIFPRs are aggregated into the following collective IVIFPR:

$$ \begin{aligned} \widetilde{U} & = \left( {\begin{array}{*{20}l} {([0.5,0.5],[0.5,0.5])} \hfill & {([0.2,0.6165],[0.1836,0.3835])} \hfill & {([0.2336,0.4336],[0.2165,0.5498])} \hfill \\ {([0.1836,0.3835],[0.2,0.6165])} \hfill & {([0.5,0.5],[0.5,0.5])} \hfill & {([0.2165,0.7666],[0.1166,0.2334])} \hfill \\ {([0.2165,0.5498],[0.2336,0.4336])} \hfill & {([0.1166,0.2334],[0.2165,0.7666])} \hfill & {([0.5,0.5],[0.5,0.5])} \hfill \\ {([0.0834,0.2665],[0.2,0.7])} \hfill & {([0.0833,0.6998],[0.2168,0.3002])} \hfill & {([0.1997,0.4334],[0.2668,0.5666])} \hfill \\ {([0.2326,0.5831],[0.1501,0.4169])} \hfill & {([0.2164,0.4663],[0.1669,0.5002])} \hfill & {([0.1001,0.5329],[0.2665,0.4671])} \hfill \\ {([0.0833,0.1666],[0.2165,0.8334])} \hfill & {([0.1668,0.6499,[0.1335,0.3501])} \hfill & {([0.1335,0.3666],[0.1669,0.6334])} \hfill \\ \end{array} } \right. \\ & \quad \left. {\begin{array}{*{20}l} {([0.2,0.7],[0.0834,0.2665])} \hfill & {([0.1501,0.4169],[0.2326,0.5831])} \hfill & {([0.2165,0.8334],[0.0833,0.1666])} \hfill \\ {([0.2168,0.3002],[0.0833,0.6998])} \hfill & {([0.1669,0.5002],[0.2164,0.4663])} \hfill & {([0.1335,0.3501],[0.1668,0.6499])} \hfill \\ {([0.2668,0.5666],[0.1997,0.4334])} \hfill & {([0.2665,0.4671],[0.1001,0.5329])} \hfill & {([0.1669,0.6334],[0.1335,0.3666])} \hfill \\ {([0.5,0.5],[0.5,0.5])} \hfill & {([0.1332,0.2666],[0.2334,0.6665])} \hfill & {([0.3005,0.5337],[0.1332,0.3661])} \hfill \\ {([0.2334,0.6665],[0.1332,0.2666])} \hfill & {([0.5,0.5],[0.5,0.5])} \hfill & {([0.4007,0.7337],[0.0834,0.2663])} \hfill \\ {([0.1332,0.3661],[0.3005,0.5337])} \hfill & {([0.0834,0.2663],[0.4007,0.7337])} \hfill & {([0.5,0.5],[0.5,0.5])} \hfill \\ \end{array} } \right). \\ \end{aligned} $$

Furthermore, by Eq. (11) in Ref. [12], the compatibility degrees \( c(\widetilde{U}^{(k)} ,\widetilde{U}) \) of \( \widetilde{U}^{(k)} ,k = 1,2,3 \) and \( \widetilde{U} \) are computed:

$$ c(\widetilde{U}^{(1)} ,\widetilde{U}) = 0.9871,\quad c(\widetilde{U}^{(2)} ,\widetilde{U}) = 0.9677,\quad c(\widetilde{U}^{(3)} ,\widetilde{U}) = 0.9502. $$

Since all \( c(\widetilde{U}^{(k)} ,\widetilde{U}) \ge 0.93,k = 1,2,3 \), then by Eq. (14) in Ref. [12], the overall preference values \( \widetilde{{r_{i} }},i = 1,2, \ldots ,6 \) corresponding to the alternatives a i , i = 1, 2, …, 6 are derived:

$$ \begin{aligned} \widetilde{{r_{1} }} & = ([0.2501,0.5834],[0.2166,0.4083]),\quad \widetilde{{r_{2} }} = ([0.2362,0.4668],[0.2139,0.5277]),\quad \widetilde{{r_{3} }} = ([0.2556,0.4917],[0.2306,0.5055]), \\ \widetilde{{r_{4} }} & = ([0.2167,0.45],[0.2584,0.5166]),\quad \widetilde{{r_{5} }} = ([0.2805,0.5804],[0.2167,0.4029]),\quad \widetilde{{r_{6} }} = ([0.1834,0.3859],[0.2863,0.5974]). \\ \end{aligned} $$

Finally, by Eq. (15) in Ref. [12], the closeness coefficients of the overall preference values are calculated:

$$ c(\widetilde{{r_{1} }}) = 0.541,\quad c(\widetilde{{r_{2} }}) = 0.4925,\quad c(\widetilde{{r_{3} }}) = 0.5022,\quad c(\widetilde{{r_{4} }}) = 0.4788,\quad c(\widetilde{{r_{5} }}) = 0.5479,\quad c(\widetilde{{r_{6} }}) = 0.4383 $$

by which the ranking orders of the alternatives a 1, a 2, …, a 6 are achieved: a 5 ≻ a 1 ≻ a 3 ≻ a 2 ≻ a 4 ≻ a 6.

In what follows, Liao et al.’s method [13] will be adopted to resolve the GDM problem described in “Description of the Problem and the Analysis Process” section. Before doing so, it should be pointed out that as Liao et al. [13] measured the consensus of each individual IVIFPR by calculating the distance between the IVIFPR and the collective IVIFPR, and the smaller the distance, the better the consensus of the IVIFPR, here the threshold value is assumed as τ * = 1 − 0.93 = 0.07 for facilitating comparisons with other decision making methods.

Firstly, by Algorithm 2 in Ref. [13], the following multiplicative consistent IVIFPRs \( \widetilde{U}_{*}^{(k)} \) from \( \widetilde{U}^{(k)} ,k = 1,2,3 \) are constructed:

$$ \begin{aligned} \widetilde{U}_{*}^{(1)} & = \left( {\begin{array}{*{20}l} {([0.5,0.5],[0.5,0.5])} \hfill & {([0.2,0.5],[0.3,0.5])} \hfill & {([0.0769,0.8],[0.0455,0.2])} \hfill \\ {([0.3,0.5],[0.2,0.5])} \hfill & {([0.5,0.5],[0.5,0.5])} \hfill & {([0.25,0.8],[0.1,0.2])} \hfill \\ {([0.0455,0.2],[0.0769,0.8])} \hfill & {([0.1,0.2],[0.25,0.8])} \hfill & {([0.5,0.5],[0.5,0.5])} \hfill \\ {([0.0237,0.6044],[0.0968,0.3956])} \hfill & {([0.0122,0.1429],[0.125,0.8571])} \hfill & {([0.1,0.4],[0.3,0.6])} \hfill \\ {([0.0287,0.419],[0.054,0.4663])} \hfill & {([0.0182,0.4833],[0.0593,0.4615])} \hfill & {([0.027,0.5],[0.0455,0.3913])} \hfill \\ {([0.0211,0.3333],[0.1196,0.6101])} \hfill & {([0.0145,0.2325],[0.2172,0.7134])} \hfill & {([0.0084,0.2109],[0.2281,0.75])} \hfill \\ \end{array} } \right. \\ & \quad \left. {\begin{array}{*{20}l} {([0.0968,0.3956],[0.0237,0.6044])} \hfill & {([0.054,0.4663],[0.0287,0.419])} \hfill & {([0.1196,0.6101],[0.0211,0.3333])} \hfill \\ {([0.125,0.8571],[0.0122,0.1429])} \hfill & {([0.0593,0.4615],[0.0182,0.4833])} \hfill & {([0.2172,0.7134],[0.0145,0.2325])} \hfill \\ {([0.3,0.6],[0.1,0.4])} \hfill & {([0.0455,0.3913],[0.027,0.5])} \hfill & {([0.2281,0.75],[0.0084,0.2109])} \hfill \\ {([0.5,0.5],[0.5,0.5])} \hfill & {([0.1,0.3],[0.2,0.6])} \hfill & {([0.4,0.6],[0.1,0.3])} \hfill \\ {([0.2,0.6],[0.1,0.3])} \hfill & {([0.5,0.5],[0.5,0.5])} \hfill & {([0.1196,0.6316],[0.013,0.2727])} \hfill \\ {([0.1,0.3],[0.4,0.6])} \hfill & {([0.013,0.2727],[0.1196,0.6316])} \hfill & {([0.5,0.5],[0.5,0.5])} \hfill \\ \end{array} } \right), \\ \end{aligned} $$
$$ \begin{aligned} \widetilde{U}_{*}^{(2)} & = \left( {\begin{array}{*{20}l} {([0.5,0.5],[0.5,0.5])} \hfill & {([0.3,0.7],[0.15,0.3])} \hfill & {([0.0455,0.8448],[0.0192,0.1552])} \hfill \\ {([0.15,0.3],[0.3,0.7])} \hfill & {([0.5,0.5],[0.5,0.5])} \hfill & {([0.1,0.7],[0.1,0.3])} \hfill \\ {([0.0192,0.1552],[0.0455,0.8448])} \hfill & {([0.1,0.3],[0.1,0.7])} \hfill & {([0.5,0.5],[0.5,0.5])} \hfill \\ {([0.0306,0.3956],[0.1282,0.6044])} \hfill & {([0.027,0.3],[0.0455,0.7])} \hfill & {([0.2,0.5],[0.3,0.5])} \hfill \\ {([0.0514,0.3345],[0.0674,0.6244])} \hfill & {([0.0206,0.5],[0.0297,0.433])} \hfill & {([0.0968,0.7],[0.0455,0.2])} \hfill \\ {([0.026,0.2178],[0.0825,0.7375])} \hfill & {([0.0145,0.1841],[0.0516,0.7617])} \hfill & {([0.0286,0.1695],[0.2592,0.75])} \hfill \\ \end{array} } \right. \\ & \quad \left. {\begin{array}{*{20}l} {([0.1282,0.6044],[0.0306,0.3956])} \hfill & {([0.0674,0.6244],[0.0514,0.3345])} \hfill & {([0.0825,0.7375],[0.026,0.2178])} \hfill \\ {([0.0455,0.7],[0.027,0.3])} \hfill & {([0.0297,0.433],[0.0206,0.5])} \hfill & {([0.0516,0.7617],[0.0145,0.1841])} \hfill \\ {([0.3,0.5],[0.2,0.5])} \hfill & {([0.0455,0.2],[0.0968,0.7])} \hfill & {([0.2592,0.75],[0.0286,0.1695])} \hfill \\ {([0.5,0.5],[0.5,0.5])} \hfill & {([0.1,0.2],[0.3,0.7])} \hfill & {([0.1,0.5],[0.0703,0.3684])} \hfill \\ {([0.3,0.7],[0.1,0.2])} \hfill & {([0.5,0.5],[0.5,0.5])} \hfill & {([0.5,0.8],[0.15,0.2])} \hfill \\ {([0.0703,0.3684],[0.1,0.5])} \hfill & {([0.15,0.2],[0.5,0.8])} \hfill & {([0.5,0.5],[0.5,0.5])} \hfill \\ \end{array} } \right), \\ \end{aligned} $$
$$ \begin{aligned} \widetilde{U}_{*}^{(3)} & = \left( {\begin{array}{*{20}l} {([0.5,0.5],[0.5,0.5])} \hfill & {([0.1,0.65],[0.1,0.35])} \hfill & {([0.0455,0.8814],[0.0192,0.1186])} \hfill \\ {([0.1,0.35],[0.1,0.65])} \hfill & {([0.5,0.5],[0.5,0.5])} \hfill & {([0.3,0.8],[0.15,0.2])} \hfill \\ {([0.0192,0.1186],[0.0455,0.8814])} \hfill & {([0.15,0.2],[0.3,0.8])} \hfill & {([0.5,0.5],[0.5,0.5])} \hfill \\ {([0.0403,0.6202],[0.027,0.3533])} \hfill & {([0.0703,0.1429],[0.0968,0.8571])} \hfill & {([0.3,0.4],[0.2,0.6])} \hfill \\ {([0.0218,0.6029],[0.0322,0.379])} \hfill & {([0.0158,0.7],[0.0968,0.3])} \hfill & {([0.0968,0.6087],[0.0588,0.3913])} \hfill \\ {([0.0232,0.5133],[0.0187,0.4724])} \hfill & {([0.0226,0.5],[0.0287,0.5])} \hfill & {([0.0169,0.555],[0.0438,0.445])} \hfill \\ \end{array} } \right. \\ & \quad \left. {\begin{array}{*{20}l} {([0.027,0.3533],[0.0403,0.6202])} \hfill & {([0.0322,0.379],[0.0218,0.6029])} \hfill & {([0.0187,0.4724],[0.0232,0.5133])} \hfill \\ {([0.0968,0.8571],[0.0703,0.1429])} \hfill & {([0.0968,0.3],[0.0158,0.7])} \hfill & {([0.0287,0.5],[0.0226,0.5])} \hfill \\ {([0.2,0.6],[0.3,0.4])} \hfill & {([0.0588,0.3913],[0.0968,0.6087])} \hfill & {([0.0438,0.445],[0.0169,0.555])} \hfill \\ {([0.5,0.5],[0.5,0.5])} \hfill & {([0.2,0.3],[0.2,0.7])} \hfill & {([0.0423,0.3913],[0.013,0.6087])} \hfill \\ {([0.2,0.7],[0.2,0.3])} \hfill & {([0.5,0.5],[0.5,0.5])} \hfill & {([0.15,0.6],[0.05,0.4])} \hfill \\ {([0.013,0.6087],[0.0423,0.3913])} \hfill & {([0.05,0.4],[0.15,0.6])} \hfill & {([0.5,0.5],[0.5,0.5])} \hfill \\ \end{array} } \right). \\ \end{aligned} $$

Then, by the symmetric interval-valued intuitionistic fuzzy weighted averaging operator in Ref. [13], the multiplicative consistent IVIFPRs are aggregated into the following collective IVIFPR:

$$ \begin{aligned} \widetilde{U}_{ * } & = \left( {\begin{array}{*{20}l} {([0.5,0.5],[0.5,0.5])} \hfill & {([0.1861,0.6197],[0.1692,0.3803])} \hfill & {([0.0543,0.8448],[0.0257,0.1552])} \hfill \\ {([0.1692,0.3803],[0.1861,0.6197])} \hfill & {([0.5,0.5],[0.5,0.5])} \hfill & {([0.2007,0.7697],[0.1147,0.2303])} \hfill \\ {([0.0257,0.1552],[0.0543,0.8448])} \hfill & {([0.1147,0.2303],[0.2007,0.7697])} \hfill & {([0.5,0.5],[0.5,0.5])} \hfill \\ {([0.0308,0.5407],[0.0707,0.45])} \hfill & {([0.0287,0.186],[0.0826,0.814])} \hfill & {([0.1856,0.4329],[0.2639,0.5671])} \hfill \\ {([0.0319,0.45],[0.0491,0.4902])} \hfill & {([0.0181,0.5643],[0.0557,0.3959])} \hfill & {([0.0638,0.6057],[0.0495,0.3193])} \hfill \\ {([0.0233,0.345],[0.0581,0.6126])} \hfill & {([0.0168,0.2897],[0.0712,0.6667])} \hfill & {([0.016,0.2893],[0.1442,0.6595])} \hfill \\ \end{array} } \right. \\ & \quad \left. {\begin{array}{*{20}l} {([0.0707,0.45],[0.0308,0.5407])} \hfill & {([0.0491,0.4902],[0.0319,0.45])} \hfill & {([0.0581,0.6126],[0.0233,0.345])} \hfill \\ {([0.0826,0.814],[0.0287,0.186])} \hfill & {([0.0557,0.3959],[0.0181,0.5643])} \hfill & {([0.0712,0.6667],[0.0168,0.2897])} \hfill \\ {([0.2639,0.5671],[0.1856,0.4329])} \hfill & {([0.0495,0.3193],[0.0638,0.6057])} \hfill & {([0.1442,0.6595],[0.016,0.2893])} \hfill \\ {([0.5,0.5],[0.5,0.5])} \hfill & {([0.1269,0.2636],[0.2303,0.6681])} \hfill & {([0.0804,0.5085],[0.023,0.4106])} \hfill \\ {([0.2303,0.6681],[0.1269,0.2636])} \hfill & {([0.5,0.5],[0.5,0.5])} \hfill & {([0.3757,0.7429],[0.0731,0.2571])} \hfill \\ {([0.023,0.4106],[0.0804,0.5085])} \hfill & {([0.0731,0.2571],[0.3757,0.7429])} \hfill & {([0.5,0.5],[0.5,0.5])} \hfill \\ \end{array} } \right). \\ \end{aligned} $$

Furthermore, by Eq. (34) in Ref. [13], the deviation between each multiplicative consistent IVIFPR and the collective IVIFPR is computed:

$$ d(\widetilde{U}_{*}^{(1)} ,\widetilde{U}_{ * } ) = 0.0501,\quad d(\widetilde{U}_{*}^{(2)} ,\widetilde{U}_{ * } ) = 0.0582,\quad d(\widetilde{U}_{*}^{(3)} ,\widetilde{U}_{ * } ) = 0.0717. $$

Since \( d(\widetilde{U}_{*}^{(3)} ,\widetilde{U}_{ * } ) > 0.07 \), then by Eqs. (35–38) in Ref. [13] (where η = 0.5), the IVIFPR \( \widetilde{U}_{*}^{(3)} \) is modified as:

$$ \begin{aligned} \widetilde{U}_{1*}^{(3)} & = \left( {\begin{array}{*{20}l} {([0.5,0.5],[0.5,0.5])} \hfill & {([0.1375,0.635],[0.1308,0.365])} \hfill & {([0.0497,0.8641],[0.0222,0.1359])} \hfill \\ {([0.1308,0.365],[0.1375,0.635])} \hfill & {([0.5,0.5],[0.5,0.5])} \hfill & {([0.247,0.7852],[0.1313,0.2148])} \hfill \\ {([0.0222,0.1359],[0.0497,0.8641])} \hfill & {([0.1313,0.2148],[0.247,0.7852])} \hfill & {([0.5,0.5],[0.5,0.5])} \hfill \\ {([0.0352,0.581],[0.044,0.4007])} \hfill & {([0.0451,0.1633],[0.0894,0.8367])} \hfill & {([0.2381,0.4163],[0.2304,0.5837])} \hfill \\ {([0.0263,0.5271],[0.0398,0.4338])} \hfill & {([0.0169,0.6348],[0.0737,0.3464])} \hfill & {([0.0788,0.6072],[0.054,0.3545])} \hfill \\ {([0.0233,0.4271],[0.0332,0.5434])} \hfill & {([0.0195,0.3897],[0.0455,0.5858])} \hfill & {([0.0165,0.4161],[0.0808,0.5548])} \hfill \\ \end{array} } \right. \\ & \quad \left. {\begin{array}{*{20}l} {([0.044,0.4007],[0.0352,0.581])} \hfill & {([0.0398,0.4338],[0.0263,0.5271])} \hfill & {([0.0332,0.5434],[0.0233,0.4271])} \hfill \\ {([0.0894,0.8367],[0.0451,0.1633])} \hfill & {([0.0737,0.3464],[0.0169,0.6348])} \hfill & {([0.0455,0.5858],[0.0195,0.3897])} \hfill \\ {([0.2304,0.5837],[0.2381,0.4163])} \hfill & {([0.054,0.3545],[0.0788,0.6072])} \hfill & {([0.0808,0.5548],[0.0165,0.4161])} \hfill \\ {([0.5,0.5],[0.5,0.5])} \hfill & {([0.1601,0.2815],[0.2148,0.6843])} \hfill & {([0.0585,0.4492],[0.0173,0.51])} \hfill \\ {([0.2148,0.6843],[0.1601,0.2815])} \hfill & {([0.5,0.5],[0.5,0.5])} \hfill & {([0.2458,0.6755],[0.0605,0.3245])} \hfill \\ {([0.0173,0.51],[0.0585,0.4492])} \hfill & {([0.0605,0.3245],[0.2458,0.6755])} \hfill & {([0.5,0.5],[0.5,0.5])} \hfill \\ \end{array} } \right). \\ \end{aligned} $$

Then, the obtained new collective IVIFPR \( \widetilde{U}_{1 * } \) is

$$ \begin{aligned} \widetilde{U}_{1 * } & = \left( {\begin{array}{*{20}l} {([0.5,0.5],[0.5,0.5])} \hfill & {([0.205,0.6145],[0.1838,0.3855])} \hfill & {([0.0559,0.8379],[0.027,0.1621])} \hfill \\ {([0.1838,0.3855],[0.205,0.6145])} \hfill & {([0.5,0.5],[0.5,0.5])} \hfill & {([0.1868,0.7643],[0.1096,0.2357])} \hfill \\ {([0.027,0.1621],[0.0559,0.8379])} \hfill & {([0.1096,0.2357],[0.1868,0.7643])} \hfill & {([0.5,0.5],[0.5,0.5])} \hfill \\ {([0.0294,0.5271],[0.0825,0.4666])} \hfill & {([0.0246,0.194],[0.0804,0.806])} \hfill & {([0.1703,0.4384],[0.2756,0.5616])} \hfill \\ {([0.034,0.4248],[0.0526,0.509])} \hfill & {([0.0185,0.5402],[0.0507,0.4129])} \hfill & {([0.0595,0.6052],[0.0481,0.308])} \hfill \\ {([0.0234,0.3195],[0.0698,0.6347])} \hfill & {([0.016,0.2601],[0.0824,0.6917])} \hfill & {([0.0158,0.2527],[0.173,0.6915])} \hfill \\ \end{array} } \right. \\ & \quad \left. {\begin{array}{*{20}l} {([0.0825,0.4666],[0.0294,0.5271])} \hfill & {([0.0526,0.509],[0.034,0.4248])} \hfill & {([0.0698,0.6347],[0.0234,0.3195])} \hfill \\ {([0.0804,0.806],[0.0246,0.194])} \hfill & {([0.0507,0.4129],[0.0185,0.5402])} \hfill & {([0.0824,0.6917],[0.016,0.2601])} \hfill \\ {([0.2756,0.5616],[0.1703,0.4384])} \hfill & {([0.0481,0.308],[0.0595,0.6052])} \hfill & {([0.173,0.6915],[0.0158,0.2527])} \hfill \\ {([0.5,0.5],[0.5,0.5])} \hfill & {([0.1173,0.2579],[0.2357,0.6626])} \hfill & {([0.0892,0.5281],[0.0253,0.3788])} \hfill \\ {([0.2357,0.6626],[0.1173,0.2579])} \hfill & {([0.5,0.5],[0.5,0.5])} \hfill & {([0.4244,0.7631],[0.0777,0.2369])} \hfill \\ {([0.0253,0.3788],[0.0892,0.5281])} \hfill & {([0.0777,0.2369],[0.4244,0.7631])} \hfill & {([0.5,0.5],[0.5,0.5])} \hfill \\ \end{array} } \right). \\ \end{aligned} $$

By Eq. (34) in Ref. [13], the deviations between the IVIFPRs \( \widetilde{U}_{*}^{(1)} \),\( \widetilde{U}_{*}^{(2)} \),\( \widetilde{U}_{1*}^{(3)} \) and the new collective IVIFPR \( \widetilde{U}_{1 * } \) are computed:

$$ d(\widetilde{U}_{*}^{(1)} ,\widetilde{U}_{1 * } ) = 0.0432,\quad d(\widetilde{U}_{*}^{(2)} ,\widetilde{U}_{1 * } ) = 0.0493,\quad d(\widetilde{U}_{1*}^{(3)} ,\widetilde{U}_{1 * } ) = 0.0489. $$

As \( d(\widetilde{U}_{*}^{(1)} ,\widetilde{U}_{1 * } ) \le 0.07 \), \( d(\widetilde{U}_{*}^{(2)} ,\widetilde{U}_{1 * } ) \le 0.07 \) and \( d(\widetilde{U}_{1*}^{(3)} ,\widetilde{U}_{1 * } ) \le 0.07 \), then by the symmetric interval-valued intuitionistic fuzzy averaging operator in Ref. [13], all the interval-valued intuitionistic fuzzy preference values corresponding to the alternatives a i , i = 1, 2, …, 6 are fused into the overall preference values \( \widetilde{{r_{i} }},i = 1,2, \ldots ,6 \):

$$ \begin{aligned} \widetilde{r}_{1} & = ([0.118,0.6052],[0.0686,0.3752]),\quad \widetilde{{r_{2} }} = ([0.1431,0.6063],[0.0733,0.3768]),\quad \widetilde{{r_{3} }} = ([0.134,0.3944],[0.1064,0.5791]), \\ \widetilde{r}_{4} & = ([0.1013,0.397],[0.1452,0.5711]),\quad \widetilde{{r_{5} }} = ([0.1271,0.5878],[0.0983,0.3638]),\quad \widetilde{{r_{6} }} = ([0.0466,0.319],[0.1777,0.6399]). \\ \end{aligned} $$

Finally, according to the comparison laws of IVIFVs [13], the ranking orders of \( \widetilde{{r_{1} }},\widetilde{{r_{2} }}, \ldots ,\widetilde{{r_{6} }} \) are achieved: \( \widetilde{{r_{2} }} \succ \widetilde{{r_{1} }} \succ \widetilde{{r_{5} }} \succ \widetilde{{r_{3} }} \succ \widetilde{{r_{4} }} \succ \widetilde{{r_{6} }} \). Thus, the ranking orders of the alternatives a 1, a 2, …, a 6 are a 2 ≻ a 1 ≻ a 5 ≻ a 3 ≻ a 4 ≻ a 6.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Zhao, N., Xu, Z. & Liu, F. Group Decision Making with Dual Hesitant Fuzzy Preference Relations. Cogn Comput 8, 1119–1143 (2016). https://doi.org/10.1007/s12559-016-9419-3

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s12559-016-9419-3

Keywords

Navigation