Skip to main content
Log in

The role of the private sector under insecure property rights

  • Research Article
  • Published:
International Review of Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

It is well known that the so-called voracity effect can be observed in an economy with a weak property rights system. Voracious behavior is regarded as one of the excess uses of the common assets. In this paper, we seek to examine voracious behavior from a different perspective by introducing a new direction of capital flow: from the private sector to the common sector. A government mandates that all competing interest groups invest their private capital in the common sector to mitigate the effects of excess use of the commons. In this situation, we study how this capital flow affects the voracious behavior of the groups and the growth rate of the economy. The main findings are that, while there is no standard voracity effect, an increase in the contribution of the private sector into the common sector causes more voracious behavior and thus reduces economic growth. This suggests that policies designed to preserve the commons can lead to a harmful effect on the economy.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. See Giles (1999) and Schneider and Enste (2000).

  2. Social fractionalization and polarization are important issues in the study of developing countries. Easterly and Levine (1997) and Alesina et al. (2003) empirically show a positive correlation between highly fractionalized societies and low growth rates. Hence, it is natural to assume the presence of n interest groups.

  3. See Assumption 2.

  4. Under Assumption 2, we can confirm that the slope of \({\dot{h}}_{i} = 0\) line is steeper than that of \({\dot{K}} = 0\) line.

  5. See Uzawa (1965) and Lucas (1988).

  6. There is another unknown parameter, \(\beta\), here. If we use the previous appropriation strategy, we cannot identify all the parameters. Thus, we have to eliminate one unknown parameter.

  7. It will be numerically confirmed in Sect. 4.2.

  8. The proof is given in Appendix 4.

  9. In the case where \(\beta\) is negative, it is clear because \(\beta (n - 1) + 1 < 0\). In the case where \(\beta\) is positive, from Lemma 3, we can confirm \(B(1 - u) + n\gamma u - a[ (n - 1)\beta + 1] = \frac{B(1 - u)(\beta - u)}{\beta } + n(\gamma - a)u > 0\).

  10. See Proposition 4.

  11. In case where B is 0.28 or 0.3, the conditions required in Assumption 2 under is not satisfied under \(u = 0\).

References

  • Acemoglu D, Johnson S (2005) Unbundling institutions. J Polit Econ 113:949–995

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Acemoglu D, Robinson JA (2001) A theory of political transitions. Am Econ Rev 91:938–963

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Acemoglu D, Johnson S, Robinson JA (2001) The colonial origins of comparative development: an empirical investigation. Am Econ Rev 91:1369–1401

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Acemoglu D, Johnson S, Robinson JA (2005) Institutions as a fundamental cause of long-run growth. In: Aghion P, Durlauf SN (eds) Handbook of economic growth, vol 1A. North-Holland Publishers, Amsterdam, pp 385–472

    Google Scholar 

  • Alesina A, Devleeschauwer A, Easterly W, Kurlat S, Wacziarg R (2003) Fractionalization. J Econ Growth 8:155–194

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arezki R, Brückner M (2012) Commodity windfalls, polarization, and net foreign assets: panel data evidence on the voracity effect. J Int Econ 86:318–326

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Benhabib J, Radner R (1992) The joint exploitation of a productive asset: a game-theoretic approach. Econ Theory 2:155–190

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Berkes F (1986) Local-level management and the commons problem: a comparative study of Turkish coastal fisheries. Mar Policy 10:215–229

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Di John J (2009) From windfall to curse? Oil and industrialization in Venezuela, 1920 to the present. Penn State University Press, University Park

    Google Scholar 

  • Dutta PK, Sundaram RK (1993) The tragedy of the commons? Econ Theory 3:413–426

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Easterly W, Levine R (1997) Africa’s growth tragedy: policies and ethnic divisions. Q J Econ 112:1203–1250

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Easterly W, Levine R (2003) Tropics, germs, and crops: how endowments influence economic development. J Monet Econ 50:3–39

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Giles DEA (1999) Modelling the hidden economy and the tax-gap in New Zealand. Empir Econ 24:621–640

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gordon HS (1954) The economic theory of a common-property resource: the fishery. J Polit Econ 62:124–142

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Haurie A, Pohjola M (1987) Efficient equilibria in a differential game of capitalism. J Econ Dyn Control 11:65–78

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Itaya J, Mino K (2007) Insecure property rights and long-run growth under increasing returns. Kyoto Univ RIMS Kokyuroku 1557:45–57

    Google Scholar 

  • Justesen MK (2014) Better safe than sorry: how property rights and veto players jointly affect economic growth. Comp Polit 46:147–167

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Justesen MK (2015) Making and breaking property rights: coalitions, veto players, and the institutional foundation of markets. J Inst Theor Econ 171:238–262

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Justesen MK, Kurrild-Klitgaard P (2013) Institutional interactions and economic growth: the joint effects of property rights, veto players and democratic capital. Public Choice 157:449–474

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Knack S, Keefer P (1995) Institutions and economic performance: cross-country tests using alternative institutional measures. Econ Polit 7:207–227

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lancaster K (1973) The dynamic inefficiency of capitalism. J Polit Econ 81:1092–1109

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lane PR, Tornell A (1996) Power, growth, and the voracity effect. J Econ Growth 1:213–241

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Levhari D, Mirman LJ (1980) The great fish war: an example using a dynamic Cournot-Nash solution. Bell J Econ 11:322–334

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lindner I, Strulik H (2004) Why not Africa?—growth and welfare effects of secure property rights. Public Choice 120:143–167

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lindner I, Strulik H (2008) Social fractionalization, endogenous appropriation norms, and economic development. Economica 75:244–258

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Loayza NV (1996) The economics of the informal sector: a simple model and some empirical evidence from Latin America. Carnegie-Rochester Conf Ser Public Policy 45:129–162

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Long NV, Sorger G (2006) Insecure property rights and growth: the role of appropriation costs, wealth effects, and heterogeneity. Econ Theory 28:513–529

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lucas RE Jr (1988) On the mechanics of economic development. J Monet Econ 22:3–42

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Markus S (2015) Property, predation, and protection: Piranha capitalism in Russia and Ukraine. Cambridge University Press, New York

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Mino K (2006) Voracity vs. scale effect in a growing economy without secure property rights. Econ Lett 93:278–284

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mulligan CB, Sala-i-Martin X (1993) Transitional dynamics in two-sector models of endogenous growth. Q J Econ 108:739–773

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • North DC (1981) Structure and change in economic history. W. W. Norton and Co., New York

    Google Scholar 

  • North DC (1990) Institutions, institutional change and economic performance. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • North DC, Thomas RP (1973) The rise of the western world: a new economic history. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Ostrom E (1990) Governing the commons: the evolution of institutions for collective action. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Pinkerton E (ed) (1989) Co-operative management of local fisheries: new directions for improved management and community development. University of British Columbia Press, Vancouver

    Google Scholar 

  • Reinganum JF, Stokey NL (1985) Oligopoly extraction of a common property natural resource: the importance of the period of commitment in dynamic games. Int Econ Rev 26:161–173

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rodrik D, Subramanian A, Trebbi F (2004) Institutions rule: the primacy of institutions over geography and integration in economic development. J Econ Growth 9:131–165

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schneider F (2008) Shadow economy. In: Rowley C, Schneider F (eds) Readings in public choice and constitutional political economy. Springer, Berlin, pp 511–532

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Schneider F, Enste DH (2000) Shadow economies around the world size, causes, and consequences. IMF-Working Papers No. 00/26: 56

  • Strulik H (2012) Poverty, voracity, and growth. J Dev Econ 97:396–403

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tang SY (1992) Institutions and collective action: self-governance in irrigation. ICS Press, San Francisco

    Google Scholar 

  • Tornell A (1997) Economic growth and decline with endogenous property rights. J Econ Growth 2:219–250

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tornell A (1999) Voracity and growth in discrete time. Econ Lett 62:139–145

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tornell A, Lane PR (1999) The voracity effect. Am Econ Rev 89:22–46

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tornell A, Velasco A (1992) The tragedy of the commons and economic growth: why does capital flow from poor to rich countries? J Polit Econ 100:1208–1231

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Uzawa H (1965) Optimum technical change in an aggregative model of economic growth. Int Econ Rev 6:18–31

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • van der Ploeg F (2010) Voracious transformation of a common natural resource into productive capital. Int Econ Rev 51:365–381

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

We are grateful to three anonymous referees, Akihisa Shibata, Takashi Komatsubara, Takuma Kunieda, Real Arai, Akitoshi Muramoto, Tetsuya Hoshino, and participants in the 87th WEAI annual conference and G-COE seminars for their helpful comments and suggestions. All errors are our own.

Funding

Our research is financially supported by JSPS Grant-in-Aid for Specially Promoted Research (No. 23000001), Grant-in-Aid for JSPS Fellows (No. 26·3190), Grant-in-Aid for Scientific Research (No. 16K03552), and the Keio-Kyoto joint G-COE program, “Raising Market Quality-Integrated Design of Market Infrastructure”.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Yohei Tenryu.

Ethics declarations

Conflict of interest

The author declares that he has no conflict of interest.

Appendices

Appendix 1: Proof of Lemma 1

In the case where the value function is independent of the opponents’ private capital stocks, (11), we obtain

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial V_{i}}{\partial h_{j}} = \frac{\partial ^{2} V_{i}}{\partial h_{j} \partial K} = \frac{\partial ^{2} V_{i}}{\partial h_{j} \partial h_{i}} = \frac{\partial ^{2} V_{i}}{\partial h_{j}^{2}} = 0. \end{aligned}$$

Substituting these appropriation strategies into (10) yields \(\frac{\partial V}{\partial K} \left( Au - (n - 1)\delta \right) = 0\). Since \(\frac{\partial V}{\partial K} \ne 0\), for the equation to be satisfied, \(Au - (n - 1)\delta\) must be zero and thus \(\delta = \frac{Au}{n - 1}\). The optimal condition (7) requires that \(\alpha = 1\) and that the conjectured value function must hold

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial ^{2} V}{\partial K^{2}} = \frac{\partial ^{2} V}{\partial h_{i} \partial K} = \frac{\partial ^{2} V}{\partial h_{i}^{2}} = -\theta \xi (K + \alpha h_{i})^{-\theta - 1}. \end{aligned}$$

These conditions mean that (8) is equivalent to (9), which leads to \(\gamma = \frac{A - B(1 - u)}{n - 1}\).

Next, from the optimal condition (6), the value function (11), and the consumption strategy, we confirm that

$$\begin{aligned} \left( a' + aK + eh_{i} + bZ_{i} \right) ^{-\theta } = c_{i}^{-\theta } = \frac{\partial V_{i}}{\partial K} = \left( \xi ^{-\frac{1}{\theta }}K + \xi ^{-\frac{1}{\theta }}h_{i} \right) ^{-\theta }. \end{aligned}$$

For the condition to be satisfied, \(a' = b = 0\) and \(a = e = \xi ^{-\frac{1}{\theta }}\) are required.

Since we focus on symmetric equilibrium, \(h_{i}\) is equivalent to \(h_{j}\) for \(j \ne i\) at equilibrium. Using this and the results obtained above, we can arrange (8) as follows.

$$\begin{aligned}{}[\rho - B(1 - u)]\frac{\partial V_{i}}{\partial K} = \frac{\partial ^{2}V_{i}}{\partial K^{2}}[B(1 - u)(K + h_{i}) - c_{i}] \iff \rho - B(1 - u) = -\theta B(1 - u) + \theta \xi ^{-\frac{1}{\theta }}. \end{aligned}$$

This leads to

$$\begin{aligned} a = e = \xi ^{-\frac{1}{\theta }} = \left( \frac{\theta - 1}{\theta } \right) B(1 - u) + \frac{\rho }{\theta }. \end{aligned}$$

Appendix 2: Proof of Lemma 3

First, we confirm that, in the case of (18), the optimal condition (7) requires \(\alpha = 1\) and thus the following relations are obtained.

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial V_{i}}{\partial h_{j}}&= \beta \frac{\partial V_{i}}{\partial K}, \quad \frac{\partial ^{2}V_{i}}{\partial K^{2}} = \frac{\partial ^{2}V_{i}}{\partial h_{i}\partial K} = \frac{\partial ^{2}V_{i}}{\partial h_{i}^{2}}, \\ \frac{\partial ^{2}V_{i}}{\partial h_{j}\partial K}&= \frac{\partial ^{2}V_{i}}{\partial h_{j}\partial h_{i}} = \beta \frac{\partial ^{2}V_{i}}{\partial K^{2}}, \quad {\text{and}} \quad \frac{\partial ^{2}V_{i}}{\partial h_{j}^{2}} = \beta ^{2} \frac{\partial ^{2}V_{i}}{\partial K^{2}}. \end{aligned}$$

Next, substituting these and the strategies into Eqs. (8)–(10), we obtain

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial ^{2} V_{i}}{\partial K^{2}}\times F(K, h)&= \{ \rho - A + (1 - \beta )(n - 1)\gamma + a\beta (n -1)\} \frac{\partial V_{i}}{\partial K},\nonumber \\ \frac{\partial ^{2} V_{i}}{\partial K^{2}}\times F(K, h)&= \{ \rho - u[ A - (1 - \beta )(n - 1)\gamma ] - B(1 - u) + a\beta ^{2}(n - 1) \} \frac{\partial V_{i}}{\partial K}, \end{aligned}$$
(23)

and

$$\begin{aligned} \beta \frac{\partial ^{2} V_{i}}{\partial K^{2}}\times F(K, h)&= \{ \beta \rho - u[ A - (1 - \beta )(n - 1)\gamma ] - \beta B(1 - u) + a\beta [ 1 + \beta (n - 2)] \} \frac{\partial V_{i}}{\partial K}, \end{aligned}$$

where the function F(Kh) represents

$$\begin{aligned} F(K, h)&= \{ A - (1 - \beta )(n - 1)\gamma - a[ 1 + \beta (n - 1)] \} K \\&\quad + \{ u[A - (1 - \beta )(n - 1)\gamma ] + B(1 - u) - a[ 1 + \beta ^{2}(n - 1)] \} h_{i} \\&\quad + \{ u[A - (1 - \beta )(n - 1)\gamma ] + \beta B(1 - u) - a\beta [ 2 + \beta (n - 2)] \} Z_{i}. \end{aligned}$$

We can summarize the three equations as follows:

$$\begin{aligned} (1 - \beta )(n - 1)(1 - u)\gamma&= (A - B)(1 - u) - a\beta (n - 1)(1 - \beta ), \end{aligned}$$
(24)
$$\begin{aligned} (1 - \beta )(n - 1)(\beta - u)\gamma&= A(\beta - u) - \beta [B(1 - u) - a(1 - \beta )]. \end{aligned}$$
(25)

The unknown parameters, a, \(\beta\), and \(\gamma\), must satisfy both of the above equations simultaneously. First, if \(\beta = 1\), the above conditions require that the contribution rate u must be a unity because of the assumption \(A > B\). This contradicts the assumption \(u \in (0, 1)\), and thus this is not an equilibrium. Second, we consider the possibility that \(\beta\) is zero. Substituting \(\beta = 0\) into (24) and (25), we get two equations, \((n - 1)\gamma = A - B\) and \((n - 1)\gamma = A\). For the two equations to be satisfied simultaneously, B must be zero, which contradicts the positivity of B. Therefore, \(\beta = 0\) is not an equilibrium. Finally, we consider the case \(\beta \ne 0, 1\). Substituting (24) into (25), we obtain \(a \beta ^{2}(n- 1) -u a \beta (n - 1) + a \beta (1 - u) - uB(1 - u) = 0\). We solve this for a,

$$\begin{aligned} a = \frac{uB(1 - u)}{\beta [(n - 1)\beta + 1 - un]}. \end{aligned}$$

Substituting it into (24), we obtain the appropriation rate \(\gamma\):

$$\begin{aligned} \gamma&= \frac{A - B}{(1 - \beta )(n - 1)} - \frac{uB}{(n - 1)\beta + 1 - un} \nonumber \\&= \frac{A [(n - 1)\beta + 1 - un] -B(1 - u)[(n - 1)\beta + 1]}{(1 - \beta )(n - 1)[ (n - 1)\beta + 1 - un ] }. \end{aligned}$$
(26)

Next, from the optimal condition (6) and (18), and the consumption strategy, we confirm that

$$\begin{aligned} (a' + aK + eh_{i} + bZ_{i}) ^{-\theta } = c_{i}^{-\theta } = \frac{\partial V_{i}}{\partial K} = \left( \xi ^{-\frac{1}{\theta }}K + \xi ^{-\frac{1}{\theta }}h_{i} + \xi ^{-\frac{1}{\theta }}\beta Z_{i} \right) ^{-\theta }, \end{aligned}$$

which leads to \(a' = 0\), \(a = e = \xi ^{-\frac{1}{\theta }}\), and \(b = a\beta\).

Finally, since we focus on symmetric equilibrium, \(h_{i}\) is equivalent to \(h_{j}\) for \(j \ne i\) at equilibrium. We substitute the above results into (23), and after some manipulation, we obtain the following equation:

$$\begin{aligned}&\left[ \rho - B + \frac{(n - 1)uB(\beta - u)}{(n - 1)\beta + 1 -un} \right] \xi (K + h_{i} + \beta Z_{i}) ^{-\theta } \\&\quad = -\theta \xi (K + h_{i} + \beta Z_{i})^{-1-\theta } \left[ \frac{B(1 - u)(\beta - u)[\beta (n - 1) + 1]}{\beta [(n - 1)\beta + 1 - un]} \right] (K + h_{i} + \beta Z_{i}). \end{aligned}$$

It is rewritten as \((n - 1)[\rho + (1 - u)(\theta - 1)B] \beta ^{2} -y \beta - \theta uB(1 - u) = 0\), where \(y \equiv (un - 1)\rho + (1 - u)[n(1+u) + 1] (\theta - 1)B\). Solving the quadratic equation for \(\beta\),

$$\begin{aligned} \beta = \frac{y \pm \sqrt{y^{2} + 4(n - 1)[\rho + (1 - u)(\theta - 1)B]\theta uB(1 - u)}}{2(n - 1)[\rho + (1 - u)(\theta - 1)B]}. \end{aligned}$$

This implies that if the quadratic equation has two different real roots, one is negative and the other is positive.

Appendix 3: Proof of Lemma 4

Let us derive the growth rate of consumption. The consumption of group i is represented by \(c_{i} = \psi ^{*}_{i} = a (K + h_{i} + \beta Z_{i})\). Differentiating this with respect to t and dividing it by \(c_{i}\) yields

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{{\dot{c}}_{i}}{c_{i}} = \frac{{\dot{K}} + {\dot{h}}_{i} + \beta {\dot{Z}}_{i}}{K + h_{i} + \beta Z_{i}}. \end{aligned}$$

The state dynamics of the model are represented as follows.

$$\begin{aligned} {\dot{K}}&= (A - n\gamma )K + (Au - n\gamma u)h_{i} + (Au - n\gamma u)Z_{i}, \\ {\dot{h}}_{i}&= (\gamma - a)K + (B(1 - u) +\gamma u - a)h_{i} + (\gamma u - a\beta )Z_{i}, \\ {\dot{h}}_{j}&= (\gamma - a)K + (\gamma u - a\beta )h_{i} + (B(1 - u) + \gamma u - a)h_{j} + (\gamma u - a\beta )\sum _{k \ne i, j}h_{k}. \end{aligned}$$

Substituting these into the numerator, we obtain

$$\begin{aligned} {\dot{K}} + {\dot{h}}_{i} + \beta {\dot{Z}}_{i}&= [A - \gamma (n - 1) - a + \beta (n - 1)(\gamma - a)]K \\&\quad + [Au - \gamma u (n - 1) + B(1 - u) - a \beta (n - 1)(\gamma u - a\beta )]h_{i} \\&\quad + [Au - \gamma u(n - 1) - a\beta + \beta (B(1 - u) + \gamma u - a) + \beta (n - 2)(\gamma u - a\beta )]Z_{i}, \\&= \frac{B(1 - u)(\beta - u)[\beta (n - 1) + 1]}{\beta [\beta (n - 1) + 1 - un]} (K + h_{i} + \beta Z_{i}). \end{aligned}$$

Therefore, we obtain the following growth rate of consumption,

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{{\dot{c}}_{i}}{c_{i}} = \frac{B(1 - u)(\beta - u)[\beta (n - 1) + 1]}{\beta [\beta (n - 1) + 1 - un]}. \end{aligned}$$

Appendix 4: The sign of \(\gamma - a\)

According to Lemma 3, we can represent \(\gamma - a\) as follows:

$$\begin{aligned} \gamma - a = \frac{A\beta [(n - 1)\beta + 1 - un] - B(1 - u)[nu + (\beta - u)(1 + (n - 1)\beta )]}{(n - 1)(1 - \beta )\beta [(n - 1)\beta + 1 - un]}. \end{aligned}$$
(27)

Similarly, we can represent \(A - n\gamma\) as follows:

$$\begin{aligned} A - n\gamma = \frac{[\beta (n - 1) + 1]\{ nB(1 - u) - A[\beta (n - 1) + 1 - un] \} }{(1 - \beta )(n - 1)[\beta (n - 1) + 1 - un]}. \end{aligned}$$

We subtract \(A - n\gamma\) from the growth rate of consumption, g:

$$\begin{aligned} g - (A - n\gamma ) = \frac{\begin{matrix} [(n - 1)\beta + 1]\{ A\beta [(n - 1)\beta + 1 - un] \\ - B(1 - u)[nu + (\beta - u)(1 + (n - 1)\beta )] \} \end{matrix} }{(n - 1)(1 - \beta )\beta [(n - 1)\beta + 1 - un]}. \end{aligned}$$
(28)

Substituting (28) into (27), we obtain

$$\begin{aligned} \gamma - a = \frac{g - (A - n\gamma )}{(n - 1)\beta + 1}. \end{aligned}$$
(29)

If \(\beta\) is positive, the denominator in the right-hand side is positive and if \(\beta\) is negative, it must be negative because of the need to assure positive growth of consumption.

Furthermore, on the balanced growth path of the model, the growth rate of consumption and common capital must coincide, that is, from (19) and (20),

$$\begin{aligned} g = \frac{{\dot{K}}}{K} = (A - n\gamma ) + n u (A - n\gamma )\frac{h_{i}}{K}, \end{aligned}$$

and therefore we obtain the ratio of private capital to common capital:

$$\begin{aligned} \chi = \frac{h_{i}}{K} = \frac{g - (A - n\gamma ) }{nu(A - n\gamma )}. \end{aligned}$$
(30)

Since \(\chi\) must be positive, the numerator \(g - (A - n\gamma )\) must be also positive. Therefore, from (29), if \(\beta\) is positive, \(\gamma - a\) is positive and if \(\beta\) is negative, \(\gamma - a\) is negative.

Appendix 5: Proof of Proposition 4

First, we derive the symmetric MPE strategies. As discussed in Sect. 4.1, \(\beta\) is positive. Substituting \(\beta\) into the parameters obtained in Lemma 3 yields the MPE parameters. Therefore, the optimal strategies are \(\psi _{i}^{*} = aK + ah_{i} + bZ_{i}\) and \(\phi _{i}^{*} = \gamma \left[ K + uh_{i} + uZ_{i} \right]\).

Next, the ratio of private capital stock to common capital stock is (30) obtained in Appendix 4. To derive the common and private capital growth rates, we divide (20) and (21) by K and \(h_{i}\), respectively.

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{{\dot{K}}}{K}&= (A - n\gamma ) + n u (A - n\gamma )\frac{h_{i}}{K}, \end{aligned}$$
(31)
$$\begin{aligned} \frac{{\dot{h}}_{i}}{h_{i}}&= (\gamma - a)\frac{K}{h_{i}} + B(1 - u) +n\gamma u - a[ (n - 1)\beta + 1]. \end{aligned}$$
(32)

Substituting (30) into (31), we obtain

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{{\dot{K}}}{K} = \frac{B(1 - u)(\beta - u)[\beta (n - 1) + 1]}{\beta [\beta (n - 1) + 1 - un]}. \end{aligned}$$

Also, substituting (30) into (32), we obtain

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{{\dot{h}}_{i}}{h_{i}}&= \frac{1}{(n - 1)\beta + 1} \left[ \{ g -(A - n\gamma ) \} \frac{K}{h_{i}} - nu(A - n\gamma ) \right] + g\\&= \frac{B(1 - u)(\beta - u)[\beta (n - 1) + 1]}{\beta [\beta (n - 1) + 1 - un]}. \end{aligned}$$

Third, we derive the growth rate of appropriation. The appropriation of group i is represented by \(d_{i} = \gamma [K + uh_{i} + uZ_{i}]\). As in the discussion above, since we focus on the symmetric MPE, \(h_{i} = h_{j}\) for all \(j \ne i\). Therefore, differentiating this with respect to t yields

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{{\dot{d}}_{i}}{d_{i}} = \frac{{\dot{K}} + un{\dot{h}}_{i}}{K + un h_{i}}. \end{aligned}$$

On the balanced growth path, the growth rate of the common capital is equivalent to that of the private capital, \({\dot{K}}/K = {\dot{h}}_{i}/h_{i}\), and thus

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{{\dot{d}}_{i}}{d_{i}} = \frac{\frac{{\dot{K}}}{K}\left( 1 + nu\frac{h_{i}}{K}\right) }{1 + nu\frac{h_{i}}{K}} = \frac{{\dot{K}}}{K} = \frac{B(1 - u)(\beta - u)[\beta (n - 1) + 1]}{\beta [\beta (n - 1) + 1 - un]}. \end{aligned}$$

Finally, we check the boundary condition. Note that since the value function \(V_{i}(K, h)\) has the properties \(V_{i}(0, 0) = 0\) and strict concavity, holding the boundary condition (5) guarantees that the transversality conditions are satisfied. In the same manner as the previous section, for the boundary condition to be satisfied,

$$\begin{aligned}&\frac{\xi (K_{0} + h_{i0} + \beta Z_{i0})^{1 - \theta }}{1 - \theta } \lim _{t \rightarrow \infty } \exp \left( \left[ \frac{Bu(1 - u)(1 - \theta )(\beta - 1) }{\beta [(n - 1)\beta + 1 - un]}\right. \right. \\&\quad \left. \left. -\, \{ \rho + (\theta -1)(1 - u)B \} t \right] \right) . \end{aligned}$$

must converge to zero. If \(\theta > 1\), it is easy to verify that this is satisfied. Let us consider the case where \(0< \theta < 1\). According to (26) in Appendix 2, \(\beta\) must be smaller than one to assure positive appropriation, which means that the first term is negative. Under Assumption 3, the equation \(\rho + (\theta - 1)(1 - u)B\) is positive so that the second term is negative. Therefore, the boundary condition is satisfied.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Tenryu, Y. The role of the private sector under insecure property rights. Int Rev Econ 64, 285–311 (2017). https://doi.org/10.1007/s12232-017-0271-x

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s12232-017-0271-x

Keywords

JEL Classifications

Navigation