Skip to main content
Log in

Moral hazard and legal services contracts

  • Research Article
  • Published:
International Review of Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We examine legal services contracts characterized by a contingency fee and an hours reporting requirement in a moral hazard setting. We find that hours reporting requirements in contingency contracts can reduce the rent needed to induce high attorney effort under moral hazard. Under certain conditions, the ability to set hours above the first-best level leads a client to choose a contract inducing high effort when she otherwise would not. The important condition of this result is, however, that hours must be contractible. We apply our model to the 2010 Florida “sunshine” law that requires hours reporting by private attorneys employed on a contingency fee basis by the attorney general. We find the sunshine laws of Florida and other states may, in addition to providing more transparency in government contracting, increase the public benefit from an attorney general’s employment of private attorneys.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. An exception is Garoupa and Gomez-Pomar (2008) who find the hourly fee preferable for interactions between clients and law firms involving a dual agency problem. The attorney, in this case, must balance the interests of the client and the law firm for which he works.

  2. Polinsky and Rubinfeld (2003) consider a model where hours are observable in a mixed contract. In their model, attorneys receive compensation through a contingent fee and receive an additional payment from a third-party administrator that is a function of the attorney’s legal costs.

  3. Fla. Stat. ch. 16.0155 (2010). Several other states have similar “sunshine” laws including Colorado, Connecticut, Kansas, Minnesota, Mississippi, North Dakota, Texas, and Virginia.

  4. Attorneys are assumed to be of uniform quality. See Rubinfeld and Scotchmer (1993) for an analysis of contingent fees where attorneys differ in quality.

  5. Since we assume the market for attorneys is competitive, our results would remain unchanged if we allowed clients to offer take-it-or-leave-it contracts to the attorney.

  6. This assumption is consistent with the literature. See Runbinfeld and Scotchmer (1993), Hay (1996), Santore and Viard (2001), and McKee et al. (2007). See Posner (1986) for a discussion of risk sharing and the contingent fee.

  7. For models analyzing the impact of the fee structure on settlement, see, for example, Miceli (1994), Hay (1997), Polinsky and Rubinfeld (2002), and Helland and Tabarrok (2003). We also do not allow for renegotiation or contract breach. See Edlin and Reichelstein (1996) for a discussion of these issues when trading partners make relationship-specific investments.

  8. If this were not the case, then, as we will see, contingent fees are unnecessary to induce the optimal level of effort.

References

  • Clermont KM, Currivan JD (1978) Improving on the contingent fee. Cornell Law Rev 63:529–639

    Google Scholar 

  • Danzon PM (1983) Contingent fees for personal injury litigation. Bell J Econ 14:213–224

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Edlin AS, Reichelstein S (1996) Holdups, standard breach remedies, and optimal investment. Am Econ Rev 86:478–501

    Google Scholar 

  • Garoupa N, Gomez-Pomar F (2008) Cashing by the hour: why large law firms prefer hourly fees over contingent fees. J Law Econ Organ 24:458–475

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hay BL (1996) Contingent fees and agency costs. J Leg Stud 25:503–533

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hay BL (1997) Optimal contingent fees in a world of settlement. J Leg Stud 26:259–278

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Helland E, Tabarrok A (2003) Contingency fees, settlement delay, and low-quality litigation: empirical evidence from two datasets. J Law Econ Organ 19:517–542

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McKee M, Santore R, Shelton J (2007) Contingent fees, moral hazard, and attorney rents: a laboratory experiment. J Leg Stud 36:253–273

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Miceli TJ (1994) Do contingency fees promote excessive litigation? J Leg Stud 23:211–224

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Polinsky AM, Rubinfeld DL (2002) A note on settlements under the contingent fee method of compensating lawyers. Int Rev Law Econ 22:217–225

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Polinsky AM, Rubinfeld DL (2003) Aligning the interests of lawyers and clients. Am Law Econ Rev 5:165–188

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Posner RA (1986) Economic analysis of law, 3rd edn. Little, Brown, Boston

    Google Scholar 

  • Rubinfeld DL, Scotchmer S (1993) Contingent fees for attorneys: an economic analysis. RAND J Econ 24:343–356

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Santore R, Viard AD (2001) Legal fee restrictions, moral hazard, and attorney rents. J Law Econ 44:549–572

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schwartz ML, Mitchell DJB (1970) An economic analysis of the contingency fee and personal injury litigation. Stanf Law Rev 22:1125–1162

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shavell S (1979) Risk sharing and incentives in the principle agent relationship. Bell J Econ 55:55–73

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

The authors wish to thank Paul Calcott for helpful discussions.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Bradley J. Graham.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Graham, B.J., Robles, J. Moral hazard and legal services contracts. Int Rev Econ 61, 219–230 (2014). https://doi.org/10.1007/s12232-014-0198-4

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s12232-014-0198-4

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation