Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Technological change and the U.S. real interest rate

  • Published:
Journal of Economics and Finance Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Economic theory predicts that the rate of technological growth exerts a positive influence on the real rate of interest. To test this hypothesis, I examine the relationship between the inflation-adjusted yield of the 90-day Treasury-Bill and two measures of innovation: the rate of growth of the stock of patents per worker and R&D spending relative to GDP. As theory predicts, from 1963 to 2008 the rate of interest responds positively to an increase in either measure. The point-estimates imply an elasticity of intertemporal substitution between one and two. The findings suggest that a change in the stance of monetary policy and a wave of innovation both contributed to the rise of real interest rates in the 1980s.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. To get (8) I take logs in (7) and use that if x is small then ln(1 + x) ≈ x.

  2. Klenow (1998) argues that a lower application cost can explain the surge in patenting in the 1990s just as well as the “technological fertility” hypothesis advanced by Kortum and Lerner (1998).

  3. A formal exposition of these ideas is presented in the Appendix.

  4. Using alternative measures like the change in the debt-to-GDP ratio and the rate of growth of M2 results in a worse fit implied by a lower R-squared and higher autocorrelation.

  5. For the debt-to-GDP ratio the trend is significant at the 10 % level. However this result is sensitive to the starting date. By moving it a couple of years back, and closer to WWII, the trend vanishes.

  6. In his paper, this would be the product of parameters γ, σ, and ξ in Table 2 under model II. If ξ = 1, which is a hypothesis Zachariadis cannot reject, then the product is equal 0.18. If it is equal to its estimate of 1.314, then the product is equal to 0.24.

References

  • Aghion P, Howitt P (1998) Endogenous growth theory. MIT Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Alexopoulos M (2011) Read all about it!! What happens following a technology shock? Am Econ Rev 101:1144–1179

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bai J, Perron P (1998) Estimating and testing linear models with multiple structural changes. Econometrica 66:47–78

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barro RJ, Sala-i-Martin X (1991) World real interest rates. NBER Working Paper No. 3317

  • Blanchard OJ, Summers LH (1984) Perspectives on high world real interest rates. Brookings PapEcon Act 2:273–324

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bohn H (1998) The behavior of U.S. public debt and deficits. Q J Econ 113:949–963

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Caballero R, Jaffe A (1993) How high are the giant’s shoulders: an empirical assessment of knowledge spillovers and creative destruction in a model of endogenous growth. NBER Working Paper No. 4370

  • Caporale T, Grier KB (2005) Inflation, presidents, Fed chairs, and regime shifts in the U.S. real interest rate. J Money, Credit, Bank 37:1153–1163

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dinopoulos E, Thompson P (1998) Schumpeterian growth without scale effects. J Econ Growth 3:313–335

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Elliott G, Rothenberg TJ, Stock JH (1996) Efficient tests for an autoregressive unit root. Econometrica 64:813–836

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Engelhardt GV, Kumar A (2009) The elasticity of intertemporal substitution: new evidence from 401(k) participation. Econ Lett 103:15–17

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fleming MJ (2000) The benchmark U.S. Treasury market: Recent performance and possible alternatives. FRBNY Econ Policy Rev, April: 130-145

  • Garcia R, Perron P (1996) An analysis of the real interest rate under regime shifts. Rev Econ Stat 78:111–125

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Griliches Z (1990) Patent statistics as economic indicators: a survey. J Econ Lit 2:1661–1707

    Google Scholar 

  • Gruber J (2006) A tax-based estimate of the elasticity of intertemporal substitution. NBER Working Paper No. 11945

  • Ha J, Howitt P (2007) Accounting for trends in productivity and R&D: a Schumpeterian critique of semi-endogenous growth theory. J Money, Credit, Bank 39:733–774

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jorgenson DW, Ho MS, Stiroh KJ (2008) A retrospective look at the U.S. productivity growth resurgence. J Econ Perspect 22:3–24

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • King RG, Plosser CI, Rebello ST (1988) Production, growth and business cycles: I. The basic neoclassical model. J Monet Econ 21:195–232

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Klenow PJ (1998) Stronger protection or technological revolution: what is behind the recent surge in patenting? A comment. Carnegie Rochester Conf Ser Public Policy 48:305–309

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kliesen KL, Schmid FA (2006) Macroeconomic news and real interest rates. Fed Reserv Bank St Louis Rev 88:133–143

    Google Scholar 

  • Kortum S, Lerner J (1998) Stronger protection or technological revolution: what is behind the recent surge in patenting? Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy 48:247–304

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mulligan C (2002) Capital, interest, and aggregate intertemporal substitution. NBER Working Paper No. 9373

  • National Science Foundation (2010) National patterns of R&D resources: 2008 data update. Arlington, VA

  • Newey WK, West KD (1987) A simple, positive semi-definite, heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation consistent covariance matrix. Econometrica 55:703–708

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Peretto PF (1998) Technological change and population growth. J Econ Growth 3:283–311

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stock JH, Wright JH, Yogo M (2002) A survey of weak instruments and weak identification in generalized method of moments. J Bus Econ Stat 20:518–529

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Young A (1998) Growth without scale effects. J Polit Econ 106:41–63

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zachariadis M (2003) R&D, innovation, and technological progress: a test of the Schumpeterian framework without scale effects. Can J Econ 36:566–586

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zachariadis M (2004) R&D-induced growth in the OECD? Rev Dev Econ 8:423–439

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

I am grateful to two anonymous referees, Charles Evans, Robert King, and Zheng Liu for comments that greatly improved the paper.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Constantine Alexandrakis.

Appendix

Appendix

In Aghion and Howitt (1998), a single final good (Y) is produced according to:

$$ {Y_t}=Q_t^{{\alpha -1}}\left( {\int_0^{{{Q_t}}} {{A_{it }}x_{it}^{\alpha }di} } \right)L_t^{{1-\alpha }}, $$
(A.1)

where Q t is a measure of the variety of intermediate durables at time t, L t is the labor force, x i is the quantity of durable i, and A i is the productivity of the latest vintage of durable i. Time is continuous. Each durable is produced in its own sector according to:

$$ {x_{it }}=\frac{{{K_{it }}}}{{{A_{it }}}}, $$
(A.2)

where K i is the capital used in sector i. Aghion and Howitt assume that each worker has a constant propensity to imitate, so the variety of durables converges to a level proportional to the population. In math:

$$ {L_t}=l\cdot {Q_t}. $$
(A.3)

Since all sectors face identical cost functions each sector ends up producing the same quantity, which means that:

$$ \int_0^{{{Q_t}}} {x_{it}^{\alpha }di} ={Q_t}\cdot x_t^{\alpha }. $$
(A.4)

Assuming that the capital market clears, so that \( {Q_t}{x_t}={{{{K_t}}} \left/ {{{A_t}}} \right.} \), the production function can be expressed in the Cobb-Douglas form:

$$ {Y_t}=K_t^{\alpha }{{\left( {{A_t}{L_t}} \right)}^{{1-\alpha }}}. $$
(A.5)

Output per worker is therefore equal to

$$ \frac{{{Y_t}}}{{{L_t}}}={A_t}\cdot k_t^{\alpha }, $$
(A.6)

where \( k\equiv {K \left/ {{\left( {A\cdot L} \right)}} \right.} \) is capital per effective worker, and A t is the average productivity of capital at time t. As in the Solow model, the economy converges to a steady state at which capital per effective worker is constant, and economic growth is sustained by the discovery of improved vintages of capital.

To establish a relationship between patent counts and the rate of technological growth, I let ϕ t denote the flow of innovations in each sector at time t, and p t denote the stock of patents. If a constant fraction 1/b of all innovations is patented, then

$$ {{\dot{p}}_t}=\frac{1}{b}\cdot {Q_t}\cdot {\phi_t}, $$
(A.7)

where a dot denotes the change per unit of time. Aghion and Howitt assume that each innovation raises average productivity by a constant factor equal to θ / Q t , so

$$ {{\dot{A}}_t}=\frac{\theta }{{{Q_t}}}{A_t}\cdot b\cdot {{\dot{p}}_t}. $$
(A.8)

Then by (A.3), and as in Kortum (1993), productivity grows at a rate proportional to the flow of patents, since:

$$ \frac{{{{\dot{A}}_t}}}{{{A_t}}}\equiv {g_A}=\psi \cdot \frac{{{{\dot{p}}_t}}}{{{L_t}}}, $$
(A.9)

where \( \psi =l\cdot b\cdot \theta \). Because the types of capital proliferate as the population expands, the flow of patents is scaled by the labor force.

If 0 / Q t is an increment rather than a factor, then productivity growth is proportional to the flow of patents per effective worker, since:

$$ {g_A}=\theta \cdot b\cdot \frac{{{{\dot{p}}_t}}}{{{A_t}{Q_t}}}=\psi \cdot \frac{{{{\dot{p}}_t}}}{{{A_t}{L_t}}} $$
(A.10)

Unfortunately there is no direct measure of A t . However, the stock of patents is given by:

$$ {p_t}\equiv \int_0^t {{{\dot{p}}_s}ds} =\frac{1}{{b\cdot \theta }}\cdot \int_0^t {{Q_s}{{\dot{A}}_s}ds} =\frac{{{Q_t}{{\dot{A}}_t}}}{{b\cdot \theta }}\cdot \int_0^t {{e^{{-\left( {{g_A}+n} \right)\left( {t-s} \right)}}}} ds. $$
(A.11)

The second equality uses that if the stock of technical knowledge is growing at a constant rate g A , and variety is growing at the same rate n as the labor force, then \( {{\dot{A}}_t}={{\dot{A}}_s}{e^{{{g_A}\left( {t-s} \right)}}} \), and \( {Q_t}={Q_s}{e^{{n\left( {t-s} \right)}}} \). Equation (A.11) reduces to:

$$ {p_t}=\frac{{{Q_t}{{\dot{A}}_t}}}{{b\cdot \theta \cdot \left( {{g_A}+n} \right)}}\left( {1-{e^{{-\left( {{g_A}+n} \right)t}}}} \right). $$
(A.12)

As the economy moves further away from the initial date, the second term in the bracket approaches zero. If enough time has elapsed, then Eq. (A.12) becomes:

$$ {p_t}=\frac{{{Q_t}{A_t}}}{{b\cdot \theta }}\cdot \frac{{{g_A}}}{{{g_A}+n}}. $$
(A.13)

Solving (A.13) for Q t A t and plugging the solution into (A.10) yields:

$$ {g_A}=\frac{{{{\dot{p}}_t}}}{{{p_t}}}-n. $$
(A.14)

The rate of growth of the stock of patents is equal to the rate of growth of GDP. In the absence of population growth it is also equal to the rate of growth of income per worker. The perpetual inventory method described in the text generates growth in the stock of patents of 3 % per year during the sample period, very close to the 3.1 % rate of growth of GDP during the same period.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Alexandrakis, C. Technological change and the U.S. real interest rate. J Econ Finan 38, 672–686 (2014). https://doi.org/10.1007/s12197-012-9246-7

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s12197-012-9246-7

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation