Skip to main content
Log in

The Great Depression: Mises vs. Fisher

  • Published:
The Quarterly Journal of Austrian Economics

Abstract

Ludwig von Mises established the foundations of modern Austrian economics while Irving Fisher established the foundations of modern mainstream macroeconomics and central bank policy. Fisher helped create and was a proponent of mathematical economics, statistics and index numbers, and a monetary policy that “stabilized” the value of the dollar. Fisher claimed that his scientific approach established a new era of prosperity during the 1920s. Mises published a book in 1928 that critiqued Fisher’s approach and predicted that it would lead to an economic crisis and collapse. Before the stock market crash in 1929 Fisher proclaimed a perpetual prosperity for the economy and continued to recommend investing in stocks long after the market had collapsed. In this important case study, Mises passed the “market test” while Fisher lost his personal fortune during an economic crisis that his economics help create.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. See Lavoie (1981) for a review of the debate. Also see Salerno (1990) and Rothbard (1991) for a more precise explanation of Mises’s contribution and the downfall of socialism.

  2. See Rothbard (2004) and Gertchev (2004) for more information on this subject. See also Hoover (2006) for a mainstream perspective on the microeconomics of macroeconomics. He declares that Mises’s extreme apriorism “provides the underlying vision of modern microeconomics”.

  3. For a more general coverage of who predicted the Great Depression see Skousen (1993).

  4. Tobin (1985, 1987) for example shows the wide-ranging impact of Fisher on modern economics.

  5. Tobin (1987, p. 370) shows that citations to Fisher’s work have been increasing relative to other important Progressive Era economists.

  6. On the connection between Fisher and Friedman (who declared Fisher “the greatest economist of the twentieth century”) see Rothbard (2002a).

  7. See Fisher (1925) where he attempts to empirically show that it is the instability of the purchasing power of the dollar that is the problem, not the business cycle per se. Mainstream economists also dismiss the idea of the business cycle and that it is really just “shocks” and “real factors” that cause changes in the economy. See for example Milton Friedman’s (1993) plucking model.

  8. Fisher’s (1976) paper was reprinted by the Journal of Political Economy in 1976.

  9. On the place of eugenics in economics see Leonard (2005a, 2005b, 2005c).

  10. For more on the impact of the tax cuts see Ekelund and Thornton (1986).

  11. See Parrish (1994) for a description of the important changes in the economy during this period.

  12. Rothbard (2002b, parts 3 & 4) shows how money and banking were changed, and why.

  13. Rothbard (1983). Interestingly, economist Steve Liesman described on CNBC (November 16, 2006) Rothbard’s explanation for the Great Depression when supposedly describing Milton Friedman’s contribution on the cause of the Great Depression.

  14. Friedman and Schwartz (1963, p. 197) show that the money stock increased under the Federal Reserve from less than $20 billion in 1914 to over $60 billion in 1929.

  15. For a further explanation of the Austrian business cycle theory and its application to the Great Depression see Rothbard (1963).

  16. See Thornton (2004a, 2004b, 2004c, 2004d, 2006) for a recap of how well economists predicted these important economic events.

  17. For an in-depth analysis of the role of realism and abstraction in economics that contrasts the methods of Mises and Friedman see Long (2006).

  18. In addition to providing the theoretical building blocks for creating business cycles, Fisher (1956, p. 230; biography by his son, Irving N.) reported that in a conversation with Mussolini that “I am spending $15,000 to $20,000 a year on propaganda for stable money.” The chapters in this biography on business cycles and fighting the depression are particularly revealing, not of economic insight, but in how badly Fisher had failed, as a blind man sifting unfamiliar evidence for a cure for his blindness.

References

  • Ekelund, Robert B., Jr., and Mark Thornton. 1986. “Schumpeterian Analysis, Supply Side Economics, and Macroeconomic Policy in the 1920s.” Review of Social Economy 19(3):221–37.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fisher, Irving. [1892] 1925. Mathematical Investigations in the Theory of Value and Prices. New Haven, Conn.: Yale University Press.

  • Fisher, Irving. 1906. “Economics as a Science.” Science 24(609):257–61.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fisher, Irving. 1907. “Why has the Doctrine of Laissez Faire been Abandoned?” Science 25(627):18–27.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fisher, Irving. 1913. The Purchasing Power of Money: Its Determination and Relation to Credit, Interest, and Crisis. New York: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fisher, Irving. [1922] 1927. The Making of Index Numbers: A Study of their Varieties, Tests, and Reliability. Boston, New York: Houghton Mifflin.

  • Fisher, Irving. 1925. “Our Unstable Dollar and the So-Called Business Cycle.” Journal of the American Statistical Association 20(15):179–202.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fisher, Irving. [1926] 1976. “I Discovered the Phillips Curve: A Statistical Relationship between Unemployment and Price Changes.” Journal of Political Economy 81(2):496–502.

  • Fisher, Irving. 1929a. New York Herald Tribune. 5 September. Reprinted in Edward Angly, Oh Yeah? New York: Viking Press, 1931.

  • Fisher, Irving. 1929b. “Fisher Sees Stocks Permanently High.” New York Times. 16 October. Reprinted in Edward Angly, Oh Yeah? New York: Viking Press, 1931.

  • Fisher, Irving. 1929c. New York Herald Tribune. 22 October. Reprinted in Edward Angly, Oh Yeah? New York: Viking Press, 1931.

  • Fisher, Irving. 1929d. New York Herald Tribute. 24 October. Reprinted in Edward Angly, Oh Yeah? New York: Viking Press, 1931.

  • Fisher, Irving. 1929e. Quoted in “Overeager ‘Shoestring’ Traders Caused Crash in Market, Says Fisher.” New York Herald Tribune. 3 November. Reprinted in Edward Angly, Oh Yeah? New York: Viking Press, 1931.

  • Fisher, Irving. 1932. Booms and Depressions: Some First Principles. New York: Adelphi Company.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fisher, Irving N. 1956. My Father, Irving Fisher. New York: Comet Press Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Formaini, Robert L. 2005. “Irving Fisher: Origins of Modern Central Bank Policy.” Economic Insights 10, no 1. Dallas, Texas: Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas.

    Google Scholar 

  • Friedman, Milton. 1993 “The ‘Plucking Model’ of Business Cycle Fluctuations Revisited.” Economic Inquiry 31(2):171–77.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Friedman, Milton. 1997. “Rx for Japan.” Wall Street Journal. 17 December.

  • Friedman, Milton, and Anna J. Schwartz. 1963. A Monetary History of the United States: 1867–1960. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gertchev, Nikolay. 2004. “Dehomogenizing Mises’ Monetary Thought.” Journal of Libertarian Studies 18(3):57–90.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hoover, Kevin D. 2006. “Microfoundations and the Ontology of Macroeconomics.” (September 24). Available at SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=932945.

  • Lavoie, Don. 1981. “A Critique of the Standard Account of the Socialist Calculation Debate.” Journal of Libertarian Studies 5(1):41–87.

    Google Scholar 

  • Leonard, Thomas C. 2005a. “Retrospectives: Eugenics and Economics in the Progressive Era.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 19(4):207–24.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leonard, Thomas C. 2005b. “Mistaking Eugenics for Social Darwinism: Why Eugenics is Missing from the History of American Economics.” History of Political Economy 37(Supplement):200–33.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leonard, Thomas C. 2005c. “Protecting Family and Race: The Progressive Case for Regulating Women’s Work.” American Journal of Economics and Sociology 64(3):757–91.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Long, Roderick T. 2006. “Realism and Abstraction in Economics: Aristotle and Mises versus Friedman.” Quarterly Journal of Austrian Economics 9(3):3–23.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mises, Ludwig von. [1912] 1981. The Theory of Money and Credit. Indianapolis, Ind.: Liberty Classics.

  • Mises, Ludwig von. [1928] 1978. Geldwertstabilisierung and Konjunkturpolitik [Monetary stabilization and cyclical policy]. Jena: Gustav Fischer. English translation by Bettina Bien Greaves, On the Manipulation of Money and Credit. Dobbs Ferry, N.Y.: Free Market Books.

  • Parrish, Michael E. 1994. The Anxious Decades. New York: W.W. Norton.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rothbard, Murray N. 1963. America’s Great Depression. New York: Richardson & Snyder.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rothbard, Murray N. 1991 “The End of Socialism and the Socialist Calculation Debate Revisited.” Review of Austrian Economics 5(2):51–76.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rothbard, Murray N. [1971] 2002a. “Milton Friedman Unraveled.” Journal of Libertarian Studies 16(4):37–54.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rothbard, Murray N. 2002b. A History of Money and Banking in the United States: The Colonial Era to World War II. Ed. Joseph T. Salerno. Auburn, Ala.: Ludwig von Mises Institute.

  • Rothbard, Murray N. [1962] 2004. Man, Economy, and State with Power and Market. Scholar’s Edition. Auburn, Ala.: Ludwig von Mises Institute.

  • Salerno, Joseph T. 1990. “Postscript: Why a Socialist Economy is Impossible,” in Mises’s Economic Calculation in the Socialist Commonwealth, Auburn, Ala.: Ludwig von Mises Institute. Pp. 51–71.

  • Skousen, Mark. 1991. Economics on Trial: Lies, Myths, and Realities, Homewood, Ill.: Business One Irvin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Skousen, Mark. 1993. “Who Predicted the 1929 Crash?” In The Meaning of Ludwig von Mises: Contributions in Economics, Sociology, Epistemology, and Political Philosophy. Ed. Jeffrey Herbener. Norwell, Mass.: Kluwer Academic Publishers.

  • Thornton, Mark. 2004a. “Uncomfortable Parallels.” www.LewRockwell.com. April 18.

  • Thornton, Mark. 2004b. “The ‘New Economists’ and the Great Depression of the 1970s.” Mises Daily Article. www.Mises.org. May, 7.

  • Thornton, Mark. 2004c. “The Japanese Bubble Economy.” www.LewRockwell.com. May 23.

  • Thornton, Mark. 2004d. “Housing: Too Good to be True.” Mises Daily Article. www.Mises.org, June 4.

  • Thornton, Mark. 2006. “The Economics of Housing Bubbles.” Mises Institute Working Paper. June 12 and forthcoming in America’s Housing Crisis: A Case of Government Failure. Eds. Benjamin Powell and Randall Holcombe. Forthcoming.

  • Tobin, James. 1985. “Neoclassical Economics in America.” American Economic Review 75, no. 6 (December):28–38.

  • Tobin, James. 1987. “Irving Fisher.” The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics. Ed. John Eatwell, Murray Milgate, and Peter Newman. New York: Stockton Press. Vol. 2. Pp 369–76.

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Mark Thornton.

Additional information

Mark Thornton (mthornton@prodigy.net) is Senior Fellow at the Ludwig von Mises Institute. I would like to thank Stephen Carson and Paul Wicks for useful comments and suggestions.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Thornton, M. The Great Depression: Mises vs. Fisher. Quart J Austrian Econ 11, 230–241 (2008). https://doi.org/10.1007/s12113-008-9046-2

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s12113-008-9046-2

Keywords

Navigation