Skip to main content
Log in

When do states renegotiate investment agreements? The impact of arbitration

  • Published:
The Review of International Organizations Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Given that their main function is to forge durable commitments, it is notable that many international treaties change over time through the practice of renegotiation. While some agreements have remained intact after their initial conclusion, others are amended, updated, or replaced. Why are some international agreements renegotiated while others remain stable? This paper offers a systematic analysis of treaty renegotiation by presenting theoretical propositions and testing them in the context of bilateral investment treaties (BITs). We argue that states renegotiate when they learn new information about the legal and political consequences of their treaty commitments, and that such learning is most likely to take place when states are involved in investor-state dispute settlement cases. Employing an original data set on renegotiated BITs, we find robust empirical support for the learning argument. We conclude by discussing implications for the study of institutional change and the evolving investment regime.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. “India to Renegotiate all Bilateral Investment Pacts: Nirmala Sitharaman,” Economic Times, July 25, 2016.

  2. “Official Warns EU-US Trade Deal at Risk over Investor Cases,” Financial Times, March 27, 2014.

  3. On obstacles to investment treaty ratification generally, see Haftel and Thompson (2013).

  4. It is possible for any treaty to be renegotiated if all parties can agree on new terms and, indeed, BITs are sometimes renegotiated early. For example, the Israel-Romania and Finland-Poland BITs were renegotiated well before their stipulated duration had expired.

  5. Moser and Rose (2012) find that free trade agreements take longer to negotiate when more states are involved, and Koremenos (2005) argues that renegotiation is costlier with large numbers.

  6. In practice, renegotiation affects a wide variety of BIT provisions, so explaining changes in design would require a comprehensive coding of all initial and renegotiated treaty texts. This is beyond the scope of the current study but we have begun to examine this issue in other research (Broude et al. Forthcoming).

  7. As Alter and Meunier (2009) note, regime complexity contributes to rule ambiguity and forces actors to learn over time about the effects of different policies.

  8. Two good examples are Australia and Canada. See Australian Government (2011), Peterson (2012), and Poulsen (2015, 36–37).

  9. For the text of the new BIT, see: http://investmentpolicyhub.unctad.org/Download/TreatyFile/4811. Accessed December 26, 2016.

  10. We tested the proportional hazard assumption with Schoenfeld residuals and found that it is not violated by any of the models and variables.

  11. Using two-dimensional clustering with the two countries in the dyad does not change the results.

  12. The Appendix is available on the Review of International Organizations website.

  13. Analysis of outliers was conducted with the dfBeta statistic. It indicated that Argentine BITs have an undue influence on the dispute variables. Keeping Argentine BITs in the analysis does not change the results in a meaningful manner.

  14. We thus exclude investment treaties that were signed and then renegotiated before entry into force. In such instances the original treaty was not legally binding.

  15. It is possible that governments react not only to cases in which they are defendants but also to cases in which their investors are claimants. It may also be the case that disputes within the dyad are especially relevant to the renegotiation of a given BIT. An empirical assessment of these intriguing conjectures is complicated by the fact that in almost all cases the claimant is a private investor whose home country is not always evident. That some investors engage in “treaty shopping” (using foreign subsidiaries to launch complaints) further complicates efforts to identify the home country. Thus, coding variables that account for the home country, in either a monadic or a dyadic set up, is necessarily incomplete and perhaps inaccurate. Nevertheless, we used available information on the claimant’s home country to assess the robustness of the results to the number of all monadic disputes (respondent and claimant) and the number of bilateral disputes. The former parallels the results on Dispute Respondent. The latter, on the other hand, is statistically insignificant.

  16. Running similar models with two- and five-year lags does not change the results. The same conclusion holds for similar lagged transformations of Dispute Global.

  17. It is also possible that states learn from disputes involving a subset of countries, such as those that are more proximate. We have examined this idea with a spatial lag of ISDS claims, weighted by geographical distance. The results, reported in the online Appendix, resemble those obtained for Dispute Global.

  18. Investment Treaty News, May 31, 2006.

  19. In line with conventional practice, we define the party with lower income per capita as the host country.

  20. http://unctadstat.unctad.org/ReportFolders/reportFolders.aspx. Accessed January 6, 2013.

  21. Elkins et al. (2006); and Simmons (2009).

  22. Data are from La Porta et al. (2008).

  23. In additional models we included a variable for shared language. This variable was not statistically significant and did not change the results.

  24. Including Dispute Respondent and Dispute Global in the same model does not change the results meaningfully. See the online Appendix.

  25. The calculation is based on Model 6 in Table 1. We use this particular variable because it benefits from greater variation and because it demonstrates the effect of cumulative ISDS experience. One standard deviation below the mean is negative, so we substitute it with the minimum value (zero).

  26. For example, the exclusion of Lagged Renegotiated BITs from models 2 and 8 renders Dispute Global statistically insignificant (but has no effect on Dispute Respondent). Possibly, the negative effect is an artifact of the moderately high correlation between the two variables (R2 = 0.46).

  27. Investment Treaty News, November 21, 2005.

  28. Unlike its counterparts, Romania renegotiated many of its BITs in the 1990s, well ahead of its accession to the EU. Excluding Romanian BITs from the analysis does not change the results.

  29. Testing for shifts to the right and shifts to the left separately indicates that this result is driven mostly by the latter (both have positive coefficients but only a shift to the left is statistically significant). This interesting finding echoes Grieco et al. (2009).

  30. We also tested for the cumulative gap in economic size, measured with GDP. This variable was statistically insignificant and did not change the results.

  31. Author’s interview with an UNCTAD official, September 26, 2013, Geneva, Switzerland.

References

  • Abbott, K. W., & Snidal, D. (2000). Hard and soft law in international governance. International Organization, 54(3), 421–456.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Allee, T., & Peinhardt, C. (2010). Delegating differences: Bilateral investment treaties and bargaining over dispute resolution provisions. International Studies Quarterly, 54(1), 1–26.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Allee, T., & Peinhardt, C. (2011). Contingent credibility: The impact of investment treaty violations on foreign direct investment. International Organization, 65(3), 401–432.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Allee, T., & Peinhardt, C. (2014). Evaluating three explanations for the design of bilateral investment treaties. World Politics, 66(1), 47–87.

  • Alschner, W. (2014). Regionalism and overlap in investment treaty law: Toward consolidation or contradiction? Journal of International Economic Law, 17(2), 271–290.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alschner, W., & Skougarevskiy, D. (2016). Mapping the universe of international investment agreements. Journal of International Economic Law, 19(3), 561–588.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alter, K. J., & Meunier, S. (2009). The politics of international regime complexity. Perspectives on Politics, 7(1), 13–24.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alvarez, J. E. (2002). The new treaty makers. Boston College International and Comparative Law Review, 25, 213–234.

    Google Scholar 

  • Australian Government. (2011). Bilateral and regional trade agreements, Research Report. Productivity Commission. http://www.pc.gov.au/projects/study/trade-agreements/report.

  • Beck, T., Clarke, G., Groff, A., Keefer, P., & Walsh, P. (2001). New tools in comparative political economy: The Database of Political Institutions. World Bank Economic Review, 15(1), 165–176.

  • Blake, D. J. (2013). Thinking ahead: Time horizons and the legalization of international investment agreements. International Organization, 67(4), 797–827.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bonnitcha, J., Poulsen, L.N.S., & Waibel, M. (Forthcoming). The political economy of the international investment treaty regime. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

  • Brooks, S. M., & Kurtz, M. J. (2007). Capital, trade, and the political economies of reform. American Journal of Political Science, 51(4), 703–720.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Broude, T., Haftel, Y. Z., & Thompson, A. (Forthcoming). Who cares about regulatory space in BITs? A comparative international approach. In A Roberts, P-H Verdier, M Versteeg, P. B. Stephan (Eds.), Comparative International Law. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

  • Brown, C., & Miles, K. (Eds.). (2012). Evolution in investment treaty law and arbitration. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Büthe, T., & Milner, H. V. (2008). The politics of foreign direct investment into developing countries: Increasing FDI through international trade agreements? American Journal of Political Science, 52(4), 741–762.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carter, D. B., & Signorino, C. S. (2010). Back to the future: Modeling time dependence in binary data. Political Analysis, 18(3), 271–292.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cooney, R., & Lang, A. T. F. (2007). Taking uncertainty seriously: Adaptive governance and international trade. European Journal of International Law, 18(3), 523–551.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dietz, T., Ostrom, E., & Stern, P. C. (2003). The struggle to govern the commons. Science, 302, 1907–1912.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • DTI. (2009). Bilateral investment treaty policy framework review: A government position paper. Pretoria: Department of Trade and Industry, Republic of South Africa.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dupont, C., & Schultz, T. (2013). Do hard economic times lead to international legal disputes? The case of investment arbitration. Swiss Political Science Review, 19(4), 564–569.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Elkins, Z., Guzman, A. T., & Simmons, B. A. (2006). Competing for capital: The diffusion of bilateral investment treaties, 1960-2000. International Organization, 60(4), 811–846.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • European Union. (2015). Inside TTIP: An overview and chapter-by-chapter guide in plain English. Luxembourg: Publications Office of the EU.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fecák, T. (2011). Czech experience with bilateral investment treaties: Somewhat bitter taste of investment protection. Czech Yearbook of Public and Private International Law, 2, 233–267.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fioretos, O. (2011). Historical institutionalism in international relations. International Organization, 65, 367–399.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gallagher, N., & Shan, W. (2009). Chinese investment treaties: Policies and practice. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gilardi, F. (2010). Who learns from what in policy diffusion processes? American Journal of Political Science, 54(3), 650–666.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goldstein, J., & Steinberg, R. H. (2008). Negotiate or litigate? Effects of WTO judicial delegation on U.S. trade politics. Law and Contemporary Problems, 71, 257–282.

    Google Scholar 

  • Goldstein, J., Kahler, M., Keohane, R. O., & Slaughter, A.-M. (Eds.). (2001). Legalization and world politics. Cambridge: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Goldstein, J. L., Rivers, D., & Tomz, M. (2007). Institutions in international relations: Understanding the effects of the GATT and the WTO on world trade. International Organization, 61(1), 37–67.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grieco, J. M., Gelpi, C. F., & Camber Warren, T. (2009). When preferences and commitments collide: The effect of relative partisan shifts on international treaty compliance. International Organization, 63(2), 341–355.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Guzman, A. T. (1998). Why LDCs sign treaties that hurt them: Explaining the popularity of bilateral investment treaties. Virginia Journal of International law, 38, 640–688.

    Google Scholar 

  • Haftel, Y. Z. (2010). Ratification counts: U.S. investment treaties and FDI flows into developing countries. Review of International Political Economy, 17(2), 348–377.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Haftel, Y. Z., & Hofmann S. C. (2017). Institutional authority and security cooperation within regional economic organizations. Journal of Peace Research. doi:10.1177/0022343316675908.

  • Haftel, Y. Z., & Thompson, A. (2013). Delayed ratification: The domestic fate of bilateral investment treaties. International Organization, 67(2), 355–387.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Helfer, L. R. (2012). Flexibility mechanisms in international agreements. In J. Dunoff & M. A. Pollack (Eds.), International law and international relations: Taking stock. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Henckels, C. (2016). Protecting regulatory autonomy through greater precision in investment treaties: The TPP, CETA, and TPP. Journal of International Economic Law, 19, 27–50.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jandhyala, S., Henisz, W. J., & Mansfield, E. W. (2011). Three waves of BITs: The global diffusion of foreign investment policy. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 55(6), 1047–1073.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jensen, N. M. (2006). Nation-states and the multinational corporation. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jupille, J., Mattli, W., & Snidal, D. (2013). Institutional choice and global commerce. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • King, G., & Zeng, L. (2001). Logistic regression in rare events data. Political Analysis, 9(2), 137–163.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Koremenos, B. (2001). Loosening the ties that bind: A learning model of agreement flexibility. International Organization, 55(2), 289–325.

  • Koremenos, B. (2005). Contracting around international uncertainty. American Political Science Review, 99(4), 549–565.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Koremenos, B., Lipson, C., & Snidal, D. (2001). The rational design of international institutions. International Organization, 55(4), 761–800.

  • Krasner, S. D. (1991). Global communications and national power: Life on the Pareto frontier. World Politics, 43(3), 336–366.

  • Lavopa, F. M., Barreiros, L. E., & Bruno, V. (2013). How to kill a BIT and not die trying: Legal and political challenges of denouncing or renegotiating bilateral investment treaties. Journal of International Economic Law, 16(4), 869–891.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Levy, J. S. (1994). Learning and foreign policy: Sweeping a conceptual minefield. International Organization, 48(2), 279–312.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Manger, M. S., & Peinhardt, C. (2017). Learning and the precision of international investment agreements. International Interactions (in press).

  • March, J. (2010). The ambiguities of experience. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Marshall, Monty G., Keith Jaggers and Ted Robert Gurr. (2010). Polity IV project: Characteristics and transitions, 1800–2009. Dataset Users’ Manual. Center for Systemic Peace.

  • Milner, H. V., & Judkins, B. (2004). Partisanship, trade policy, and globalization: Is there a left–right divide on trade policy? International Studies Quarterly, 48(1), 95–120.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mitchell, S. M. L., & Hensel, P. R. (2007). International institutions and compliance with international agreements. American Journal of Political Science, 51(4), 721–737.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Moser, C., & Rose, A. K. (2012). Why do trade negotiations take so long? Journal of Economic Integration, 27(2), 280–290.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nottage, L. R. (2016). The TPP investment chapter and investor-state arbitration in asia and oceania: Assessing prospects for ratification. Sydney Law School Research Paper No. 16/128.

  • OECD. (2011). Roundtable on freedom of investment 15. Paris: OECD Secretariat.

    Google Scholar 

  • OECD. (2014). Roundtable on freedom of investment 21. Paris: OECD Secretariat.

    Google Scholar 

  • Olivet, C. (2013). A test for European solidarity: The case of intra-EU bilateral investment treaties. Amsterdam: Transnational Institute.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pauwelyn, J. (2014). At the edge of chaos? Foreign investment law as a complex adaptive system: How it emerged and how it can Be reformed. ICSID Review, 29(2), 372–418.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Peterson, L. (2012). Canada announces conclusion of investment treaty with China, but There’s an asterisk. Investment Arbitration Reporter, February, 16, 2012.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pinto, P. M. (2013). Partisan investment in the global economy. New York: Cambridge University Press.

  • Porta, L., Rafael, F. L.-d.-S., & Shleifer, A. (2008). The economic consequences of legal origins. Journal of Economic Literature, 46(2), 285–332.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Poulsen, L. S. (2010). The importance of BITs for foreign direct investment and political risk insurance: Revisiting the evidence. In Yearbook on International Investment Law and Policy 2009/2010, edited by Karl Sauvant. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Poulsen, L. S. (2014). Bounded rationality and the diffusion of modern investment treaties. International Studies Quarterly, 58, 1–14.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Poulsen, L. S. (2015). Bounded rationality and economic diplomacy: The politics of investment treaties in developing countries. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

  • Poulsen, L. S., & Aisbett, E. (2013). When the claim hits: Bilateral investment treaties and bounded rational learning. World Politics, 65(2), 273–313.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Raustiala, K. (2005). Form and substance in international agreements. American Journal of International Law, 99, 581–614.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rixen, T., Viola, L. A., & Zürn, M. (Eds.). (2016). Historical institutionalism and international relations. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Roberts, A. (2010). Power and persuasion in investment treaty interpretation: The dual role of states. American Journal of International Law, 104, 179–225.

  • Rosendorff, P., & Milner, H. (2001). The optimal design of international trade institutions: Uncertainty and escape. International Organization, 55(4), 829–857.

  • Sauvant, K.P., & Sachs, L. (2009). The effect of treaties on foreign direct investment: Bilateral investment treaties, double taxation treaties, and investment flows. New York: Oxford University Press.

  • Schill, S. W. (2009). The multilateralization of international investment law. New York: Cambridge University Press.

  • Schlemmer, E. C. (2016). An overview of South Africa’s bilateral investment treaties and investment policy. ICSID Review, 3(1), 167–193.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Simmons, B. (2000). International law and state behavior: Commitment and compliance in international monetary affairs. American Political Science Review, 94(4), 819–835.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Simmons, B. A. (2009). Mobilizing for human rights: International law in domestic politics. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Singh, K. & Ilge, B. (2016). India overhauls its investment treaty regime, July 15. http://blogs.ft.com/beyond-brics/2016/07/15/india-overhauls-its-investment-treaty-regime/. Accessed 26 December 2016.

  • Solingen, E. (2012). Of dominoes and firewalls: The domestic, regional, and global politics of international diffusion. International Studies Quarterly, 56, 631–644.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stasavage, D. (2002). Private investment and political institutions. Economics and Politics, 14(1), 41–63.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Suchman, M. C., & Edelman, L. B. (1996). Legal rational myths: The new institutionalism and the law and society tradition. Law and Social Inquiry, 21, 903–941.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Thompson, A. (2010). Rational Design in Motion: Uncertainty and flexibility in the global climate regime. European Journal of International Relations, 16(2), 269–296.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Thompson, A., & Verdier, D. (2014). Multilateralism, bilateralism and regime design. International Studies Quarterly, 58(1), 15–28.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tobin, J. L., & Rose-Ackerman, S. (2011). When BITs have some bite: The political-economic environment for bilateral investment treaties. Review of International Organizations, 6, 1–32.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • UNCTAD (2010). Denunciation of the ICSID convention and BITS: Impact on investor-state claims. IIA Issues Note, No. 2 (December).

  • UNCTAD (2011). Latest developments in investor-state dispute settlement. IIA Issues Note, No. 1 (March).

  • UNCTAD (2014). Reform of the IIA regime: Four paths of action and a way forward. IIA Issues Note No. 3 (June).

  • Urpelainen, J. (2011). The enforcement–exploitation trade-off in international cooperation between weak and powerful states. European Journal of International Relations, 17(4), 631–653.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • van Aaken, A. (2009). International investment law between commitment and flexibility: A contract theory analysis. Journal of International Economic Law, 12(2), 507–538.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vandevelde, K. J. (2009). A brief history of international investment agreements. In K. P. Sauvant & L. Sachs (Eds.), The effect of bilateral investment treaties and double taxation treaties on foreign direct investment flows. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Weyland, K. (2008). Toward a new theory of institutional change. World Politics, 60(2), 281–314.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yackee, J. W. (2008). Bilateral investment treaties, credible commitment, and the rule of (international) law: Do BITs promote foreign direct investment? Law and Society Review, 42(4), 805–832.

Download references

Acknowledgements

The authors are listed in alphabetical order. For comments on previous drafts, we thank Todd Allee, Patrick Bayer, Tomer Broude, Raphael Cunha, Cédric Dupont, Virginia Haufler, Raymond Hicks, Robert Keohane, Helen Milner, Lauge Poulsen, Katherine Sawyer, Johannes Urpelainen, Daniel Verdier, Rachel Wellhausen and Jason Young. We also thank the Editor and three anonymous reviewers for their comments. We thank David Carlson, Moshe Goldman, Anahit Gomtsian, and Maayan Morali for helpful research assistance. Yoram Haftel received financial support from the Marie Curie FP7 Integration Grant (Project 333374) within the 7th European Union Framework Programme.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Alexander Thompson.

Electronic supplementary material

ESM 1

(ZIP 1.33 mb)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Haftel, Y.Z., Thompson, A. When do states renegotiate investment agreements? The impact of arbitration. Rev Int Organ 13, 25–48 (2018). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11558-017-9276-1

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11558-017-9276-1

Keywords

Navigation