Skip to main content
Log in

Delegation and pooling in international organizations

  • Published:
The Review of International Organizations Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We conceive authority of an international organization as latent in two independent dimensions: delegation by states to international agents and pooling in collective decision making bodies. We theorize that delegation and pooling are empirically as well as conceptually different. Delegation is an effort to deal with the transaction costs of cooperation which are greater in larger, broader, and correspondingly more complex organizations. Pooling reflects the tension between protecting or surrendering the national veto. This paper theorizes that delegation and pooling are constrained by two basic design features: a) the scope of an IO’s policy portfolio and b) the scale of its membership. We test these hypotheses with a new cross-sectional dataset that provides detailed and reliable information on IO decision making. Our major finding is that the design of international organizations is framed by stark and intelligible choices, but in surprising ways. Large membership organizations tend to have both more delegation and more pooling. The broader the policy scope of an IO, the more willing are its members to delegate, but the less willing they are to pool authority.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. General purpose IOs tend to have more delegation, while task specific IOs tend to have higher pooling (Hooghe et al. forthcoming; Lenz et al. 2014).

  2. The distinction is foreshadowed by the legalization (Abbott et al. 2000) and rational design projects (Koremenos et al. 2001). Abbott and Snidal (1998: 8f) use the concept of centralization to refer to “a concrete and stable organizational structure and a supportive administrative apparatus” while independence refers to “the authority to act with a degree of autonomy, and often with neutrality, in defined spheres.” These attributes have an affinity with our concept of delegation. Koremenos et al. (2001) identify five elements of institutional design: membership rules, scope of issues, flexibility, centralization of tasks, and rules for controlling the institution. The final two overlap with delegation and pooling. Centralization refers to activities “to disseminate information, to reduce bargaining and transaction costs, and to enhance enforcement . . . The least intrusive form of centralization is information collection” (Koremenos et al. 2001: 771–72). Control “focus[es] on voting arrangements as one important and observable aspect of control” (Koremenos et al. 2001: 772).

  3. Recent studies that distinguish pooling and delegation beyond the European Union include Rittberger and Zangl (2006), Brown (2010), and Lenz et al. (2014).

  4. Even ratification has been made less restrictive. Since 1972 the IMO routinely uses the tacit consent procedure whereby a member state is presumed to have ratified unless it objects within a set time period. The new rule was introduced because reaching the two-thirds hurdle became increasingly difficult as membership expanded beyond the initial group of shipping nations (Rosenne 1999).

  5. Two case studies speak to the issue. Pahre (2004: 128) finds that the more players involved in trade negotiation, the more they cluster in groups, and interprets this as support for the hypothesis that larger membership leads to centralization. However, clustering, defined as “a state’s simultaneous negotiations with two or more countries on the same issue” (Pahre 2004: 101), is at best a weak form of centralization and one would be hard-pressed to conceive it as a form of delegation. Richards’ study of the air-traffic regime in the same volume observes that growth in membership has led to less centralization and more “unanimity voting rules govern[ing] annual IATA fare conferences” (Richards 2004: 235, 240–1, 255–6).”

  6. We investigate the formal rules and then determine whether these are translated into institutions in order to narrow the gap in coding between unrealized intention and actual practice (Gray and Slapin 2012; Haftel 2013). However, we do not code practices that have only an informal basis.

  7. As distinct from delegation in dispute settlement, which requires separate treatment.

  8. Delegation is calculated as a summated rating scale ranging from 0 (no delegation) to 9 (maximum delegation) by adding scores across these items, then rescaled from 0 to 1. Please see the online appendix on the webpage of Review of International Organizations for details.

  9. Pooling is calculated for each domain as a function of the decision rule, bindingness, and ratification. The “weakest link”—the most intergovernmental option—prevails. The maximum score is majority voting over a binding decision that does not require ratification. The minimum score is unanimous decision making. Discounts are applied to non-unanimous decisions that are partially binding or non-binding or require partial or full ratification. Super-majoritarian decision rules, partial ratification, and partial bindingness produce intermediate scores. Scores are calculated for each domain and summated on a scale from 0 (no pooling) to 6 (maximum pooling), then rescaled to 0 to 1.

  10. Krippendorff’s (2013) alpha measures agreement among coders and ranges from zero, which indicates no agreement beyond chance, to one, which indicates agreement without exceptions.

  11. The commonly used POLITY2 measure from the Polity IV dataset, which subtracts the autocracy score from the democracy score, is highly correlated at the IO level (r = 0.95) and produces similar results.

  12. A counterargument focuses on major powers as suppliers of international institutions (Hancock 2009; Mattli 1999; Mearsheimer 1994).

  13. Examples of the former are the World Bank, the International Monetary Fund and the European Union. Examples of the latter are the International Atomic Energy Agency (where the ten largest nuclear powers have reserved seats), the United Nations (with reserved seats for the five big powers) and the International Maritime Organization (with reserved seats for the countries with the largest shipping interests).

  14. Controlling for preference heterogeneity among member states has no effect. The only published data source covering the IOs discussed here is the Affinity Index which extracts similarity scores from voting in the United Nations. This is a topic on which valid hypothesis testing must await improved measurement (Voeten 2013).

  15. Niger and Guinea (2009), Ivory Coast (2012), Mali (2011).

  16. Members and Policy scope are quite strongly associated (r = −0.55). In the online appendix we confirm the results of the OLS models presented here in sequential matching models (Ho et al. 2007; Holland 1986). Matching allows one to examine the effects of predictors that are highly correlated by weighting cases to achieve better balance between treated and control groups.

References

  • Abbott, K. W., & Snidal, D. (1998). Why states act through formal international organizations. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 42, 3–32.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Abbott, K., Keohane, R. O., Moravcsik, A., Slaughter, A.-M., & Snidal, D. (2000). The concept of legalization. International Organization, 54, 401–419.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Acharya, A., & Johnston, I. (2007). Comparing regional institutions: An introduction. In A. Acharya & I. Johnston (Eds.), Crafting cooperation: Regional international institutions in comparative perspective (pp. 1–31). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Adcock, R., & Collier, D. (2001). Measurement validity: a shared standard for qualitative and quantitative research. American Political Science Review, 95, 529–546.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Adkisson, R. V. (2003). The Andean group: institutional evolution, intraregional trade, and economic development. Journal of Economic Issues, 37, 371–379.

    Google Scholar 

  • Alter, K., & Helfer, L. R. (2010). Nature or nurture? Judicial law making in the European Court of Justice and Andean Court of Justice. International Organization, 64, 563–592.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ashan, A. (2006). SAARC secretariat: A critique. In I. Alam (Ed.), SAARC: South Asian Association for Regional Cooperation (pp. 142–149). South Asian Policy Analysis Network (SAPANA): Lahore.

    Google Scholar 

  • Barnett, M., & Finnemore, M. (2004). Rules for the world. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Blake, D. J., & Lockwood Payton, A. (2014). Balancing design objectives: analyzing new data on voting rules in intergovernmental organizations. Review of International Organizations.

  • Bradley, C. A., & Kelley, J. G. (2008). The concept of international delegation. Law and Contemporary Problems, 71, 1–36.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brown, R. L. (2010). Measuring delegation. Review of International Organizations, 5, 141–175.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carrubba, C. J., & Volden, C. (2001). Explaining institutional change in the European union: what determines the voting rule in the council of ministers? European Union Politics, 2, 5–30.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cooley, A., & Spruyt, H. (2009). Contracting states: Sovereign transfers in international relations. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • De Lombaerde, P., & Schulz, M. (Eds.). (2009). The EU and world regionalism: The makeability of regions in the 21st century. London: Ashgate.

    Google Scholar 

  • Downs, G. W., Rocke, D. M., & Barsoom, P. N. (1998). Managing the evolution of multilateralism. International Organization, 52, 397–419.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dreher, A. (2004). The influence of IMF programs on the re-election of debtor governments. Economics and Politics, 16, 53–76.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dreher, A., & Gassebner, M. (2012). Do IMF and world bank programs induce government crises? An empirical analysis. International Organization, 66, 329–358.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Drezner, D. (2007). All politics is global. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Goertz, G., & Powers, K. (2012). Regional governance: The evolution of a new institutional form. Paper presented at a workshop on An International Organization Data Base, Wissenschaftszentrum Berlin, February.

  • Gray, J., & Slapin, J. B. (2012). How well do regional trade agreements work? Ask the experts. Review of International Organizations, 7, 309–333.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Haftel, Y. Z. (2012). Regional economic institutions and conflict mitigation: Design, implementation, and the promise of peace. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Haftel, Y. Z. (2013). Commerce and institutions: trade, scope, and the design of regional economic organizations. Review of International Organizations, 8, 389–414.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Haftel, Y. Z., & Thompson, A. (2006). The independence of international organizations: concept and applications. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 50, 253–275.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hancock, K. J. (2009). Regional integration: Choosing plutocracy. New York: Palgrave/MacMillan.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Hasenclever, A., Mayer, P., & Rittberger, V. (1997). Theories of international regimes. Cambridge: CUP.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Hawkins, D. G., Lake, D. A., Nielson, D. L., & Tierney, M. L. (Eds.). (2006). Delegation and agency in international organizations. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ho, D. E., Imai, K., King, G., & Stuart, E. A. (2007). Matching as nonparametric preprocessing for reducing model dependence in parametric causal inference. Political Analysis, 15, 199–236.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Holland, P. W. (1986). Statistics and causal inference. Journal of the American Statistical Association, 81, 945–960.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hooghe, L., & Marks, G. (2001). Multi-level governance and European integration. Lanham: Rowman & Littlefield.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hooghe, L., & Marks, G. (2003). Unraveling the central state, but how? Types of multi-level governance. American Political Science Review, 97, 233–243.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hooghe, L., & Marks, G. (2009a). Efficiency and the territorial structure of government. Annual Review of Political Science, 12, 225–241.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hooghe, L., & Marks, G. (2009b). A postfunctionalist theory of European integration: from permissive consensus to constraining dissensus. British Journal of Political Science, 39, 1–23.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hooghe, L., Marks, G., Lenz, T., Bezuijen, J., Ceka, B., & Derderyan, S. (Forthcoming). Scale and community: The design of international organization. Ms.

  • Johnson, T. (2013). Institutional design and bureaucrats’ impact on political control. Journal of Politics, 75, 183–197.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kahler, M. (1992). Multilateralism with small and large numbers. International Organization, 46, 681–708.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Keohane, R., & Hoffmann, S. (1991). Institutional change in Europe in the 1980s. In R. O. Keohane & S. Hoffmann (Eds.), The new European community: Decisionmaking and institutional change (pp. 1–40). Boulder: Westview Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Keohane, R. O., & Ostrom, E. (Eds.). (1995). Local commons and global interdependence. New York: Sage Publications.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kleine, M. (2013). Informal governance in the European Union. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.

  • Kohler-Koch, B., & Rittberger, B. (Eds.). (2007). Debating the democratic legitimacy of the European Union. Lanham: Rowman & Littlefield.

    Google Scholar 

  • Koremenos, B. (2008). When, what and why do states choose to delegate? Law and Contemporary Problems, 71, 151–192.

    Google Scholar 

  • Koremenos, B., Lipson, C., & Snidal, D. (2001). The rational design of international institutions. International Organization, 55, 761–799.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krasner, S. D. (1991). Global communications and national power: life on the Pareto frontier. World Politics, 43, 336–356.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krippendorff, K. (2013). Content analysis: An introduction to its methodology (3rd ed.). Thousand Oaks: Sage.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lake, D. A. (2007). Delegating divisible sovereignty: sweeping a conceptual minefield. Review of International Organizations, 2, 219–237.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lake, D. A. (2010). Rightful rules: authority, order, and the foundations of global governance. International Studies Quarterly, 54, 587–613.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lenz, T., Bezuijen, J., Hooghe, L., & Marks, G. (2014). Patterns of international organization: task-specific vs. general-purpose. Politische Vierteljahresschrift.

  • Lockwood Payton, A. (2010). Consensus procedures in international organizations. EUI Working Paper MWP 2010/22.

  • Maggi, G., & Morelli, M. (2006). Self-enforcing voting in international organizations. The American Economic Review, 96, 1137–1158.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mansfield, E. D., Milner, H. V., & Rosendorff, B. P. (2000). Free to trade: democracies, autocracies and international trade. American Political Science Review, 94, 305–331.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Marks, G., Hooghe, L., & Blank, K. (1996). European integration and the state: multi-level vs. state centric governance. Journal of Common Market Studies, 34, 341–378.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Marks, G., Hooghe, L., & Schakel, A. (2008). Measuring regional authority. Regional and Federal Studies, 18, 111–120.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Marks, G., Lenz, T., Ceka, B., & Burgoon, B. (2014). Discovering cooperation: a contractual approach to institutional change in regional international organizations. Unpublished ms.

  • Martin, L. (1995). Heterogeneity, linkage and commons problems. In R. O. Keohane & E. Ostrom (Eds.), Local commons and global interdependence (pp. 71–92). New York: Sage Publications.

    Google Scholar 

  • Martin, L. (2000). Democratic commitments. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Mattli, W. (1999). The logic of regional integration: Europe and beyond. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Mearsheimer, J. J. (1994). The false promise of international institutions. International Security, 19, 5–49.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mitchell, R. B. (2006). Problem structure, institutional design, and the relative effectiveness of international environmental agreements. Global Environmental Politics, 6, 72–89.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Moravcsik, A. (1993). Preferences and power in the European Community: a liberal intergovernmentalist approach. Journal of Common Market Studies, 31, 473–524.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Moravcsik, A. (1998). The choice for Europe: Social purpose and state power from Messina to Maastricht. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mueller, D. C. (2003). Public Choice III. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Nordquist, M. H., & Moore, J. M. (Eds.). (1999). Current maritime issues and the international maritime organization. The Hague: Martinus Nijhoff Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Olson, M. (1968). The logic of collective action. New York: Schocken.

    Google Scholar 

  • Osieke, E. (1984). Majority voting systems in the international labour organisation and the international monetary fund. The International and Comparative Law Quarterly, 33, 381–408.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pahre, R. (2004). Most favored-nation clauses and clustered negotiations. In B. Koremenos, C. Lipson, & D. Snidal (Eds.), The rational design of international institutions (pp. 99–130). New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pevehouse, J. C. (2005). Democracy from above? Regional organizations and democratization. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Pollack, M. A. (1997). Delegation, agency and agenda setting in the European community. International Organization, 51, 99–134.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pollack, M. A. (2003). The engines of European integration: Delegation, agency, and agenda setting in the EU. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Powers, K., & Goertz, G. (2011). The economic-institutional construction of regions: conceptualisation and operationalisation. Review of International Studies, 37, 2387–2416.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Prada, F., & Espinoza, A. (2008). Monitoring regional integration and cooperation in the Andean Region. In P. De Lombaerde, A. Estevadeordal, & K. Suominen (Eds.), Governing regional integration for development (pp. 11–30). London: Ashgate.

    Google Scholar 

  • Qvortrup, M., & Hazell, R. (1998). The British-Irish council: Nordic lessons for the council of the isles. London: Constitution Unit.

    Google Scholar 

  • Richards, J. E. (2004). Institutions for flying: How states built a market in international aviation services. In B. Koremenos, C. Lipson, & D. Snidal (Eds.), The rational design of international institutions (pp. 233–258). New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Riches, C. A. (1940). Majority rule in international organization: A study of the trend from unanimity to majority decision. Baltimore: John Hopkins Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rittberger, B. (2005). Building Europe’s parliament. Democratic representation beyond the nation state. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rittberger, V., & Zangl, B. (2006). International organization: polity, politics, and policies. London: Palgrave.

  • Rixen, T., & Zangl, B. (2013). The politicization of international economic institutions in US public debates. Review of International Organizations, 8, 363–387.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rosenne, S. (1999). The international maritime organization interface with the law of the sea convention. In M. H. Nordquist & J. M. Moore (Eds.), Current maritime issues and the international maritime organization (pp. 251–268). The Hague: Martinus Nijhoff Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sandler, T. (2004). Global collective action. Cambridge: CUP.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Sartori, G. (1970). Concept misformation in comparative politics. American Political Science Review, 64, 1033–1053.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schimmelfennig, F., Rittberger, B., Bürgin, A., & Schwellnus, G. (2006). Conditions for EU constitutionalization: a qualitative comparative analysis. Journal of European Public Policy, 13, 1168–1189.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shanks, C., Jacobson, H. K., & Kaplan, J. H. (1996). Inertia and change in the constellation of international governmental organizations, 1981–1992. International Organization, 50, 593–627.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shubik, M. (1982). Game theory in the social sciences. Cambridge: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Singer, J. D. (1987). Reconstructing the correlates of war dataset on material capabilities of states, 1816–1985. International Interactions, 14, 115–132.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Snidal, D. (1995). The politics of scope: endogenous actors, heterogeneity and institutions. In R. O. Keohane & E. Ostrom (Eds.), Local commons and global interdependence (pp. 47–70). New York: Sage Publications.

    Google Scholar 

  • Solingen, E. (2008). The genesis, design and effects of regional institutions: lessons from East Asia and the Middle East. International Studies Quarterly, 52, 261–294.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tallberg, J. (2002). Delegation to supranational institutions: why, how, and with what consequences? West European Politics, 25, 23–46.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tallberg, J. (2010). The power of the chair: formal leadership in international cooperation. International Studies Quarterly, 54, 241–265.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tavares, R. (2008). Monitoring regional cooperation and integration in South Asia. In P. De Lombaerde, A. Estevadeordal, & K. Suominen (Eds.), Governing regional integration for development (pp. 141–160). London: Ashgate;.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tsebelis, G. (2002). Veto players: how political institutions work. Princeton: Princeton University Press & Russell Foundation.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Urpelainen, J. (2012). Unilateral influence on international bureaucrats: an international delegation problem. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 56, 704–735.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Van Leeuwen, J., & Kern, K. (2013). The external dimension of European union marine governance: institutional interplay between the EU and the international maritime organization. Global Environmental Politics, 13, 69–87.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Voeten, E. (2013). Data and analyses of voting in the UN general assembly. In B. Reinalda (Ed.), Routledge handbook of international organization (pp. 54–66). London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Zamora, S. (1980). Voting in international economic organizations. American Journal of International Law, 74, 566–608.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zürn, M., Binder, M., & Ecker-Ehrhardt, M. (2012). International authority and its politicization. International Theory, 4, 69–106.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

This project is financed by the European Research Council Advanced Grant #249543 “Causes and Consequences of Multilevel Governance.” The dataset was created by Liesbet Hooghe, Gary Marks, Jeanine Bezuijen, Besir Ceka, Svet Derderyan, and Tobias Lenz. Emanuel Coman, Catherine de Vries, Benjamin Neudorfer, and Henk-Jan Van Alphen provided research assistance at various stages. Earlier versions were presented at the Hertie School, Berlin; the Free University of Berlin; the 2012 Council of Europeanists, Boston; Munich University; New York University; Nuffield College, Oxford University; the University of North Carolina in Chapel Hill; the Munk Centre, University of Toronto; the VU University Amsterdam; the ETH in Zurich; and the 2014 International Studies Association, Toronto. The authors are grateful for participant comments at these seminars and for individual comments on various drafts. We wish to thank Thomas Bernauer, Tanja Börzel, Eugenia da Conceicao-Heldt, Mark Crescenzi, Ben Crum, Catherine de Vries, Philipp Genschel, Stephen Gent, Gary Goertz, Yoram Haftel, Markus Jachtenfuchs, Judith Kelley, Christiane Lemke, Tobias Lenz, David Levi-Faur, Walter Mattli, Helen Milner, Ron Mitchell, Kimberly Morgan, Kalypso Nicolaidis, Diana Panke, Nils Ringe, Thomas Risse, Berthold Rittberger, Frank Schimmelfennig, Duncan Snidal, Theresa Squatrito, Erik Voeten, Bernhard Zangl, Michael Zürn, and the anonymous referees. We wish to give special thanks to Emanuel Coman for research assistance and to the Kolleg-Forschergruppe ‘The Transformative Power of Europe’, and its co-directors Tanja Börzel and Thomas Risse, for hosting us as postdoctoral fellows.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Gary Marks.

Electronic supplementary material

Below is the link to the electronic supplementary material.

ESM 1

(DOCX 43.8 kb)

ESM 2

(DTA 23.1 kb)

ESM 3

(DO 7.23 kb)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Hooghe, L., Marks, G. Delegation and pooling in international organizations. Rev Int Organ 10, 305–328 (2015). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11558-014-9194-4

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11558-014-9194-4

Keywords

Navigation