Skip to main content
Log in

The Tiebout hypothesis under membership property rights

  • Published:
Theory and Decision Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We consider the problem of producing an impure public good in various jurisdictions formed through the strategic decisions of agents. Our environment inherits two well-known problems: (i) Under individual decisions, there is a tension between stability and efficiency; (ii) Under coalitional decisions, stable jurisdiction structures may fail to exist. The solution, we propose is the use of membership property rights: When a move among jurisdictions is subject to the approval of the agents whom it affects, coalitionally stable jurisdiction structures coincide with those which are efficient.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. As a famous example in this direction, we have the critique of Bewley (1981) who shows that equilibrium district structures may fail to exist or be inefficient.

  2. Buchanan and Goetz (1972) and Flatters et al. (1974) are among the first to point to the possible inefficiency of free-mobility equilibria. The literature contains many explorations about this particular equilibrium concept, among which we have Richter (1982), Greenberg (1983), Konishi (1996) and Konishi et al. (1998).

  3. The idea of being immune to coalitional deviations has been previously used by McGuire (1974) and Wooders (1978).

  4. Guesnerie and Oddou (1981) and Greenberg and Weber (1986, 1993) discuss the existence conditions of strong Tiebout equilibria. The existence of coalitionally stable partitions in an abstract hedonic setting is addressed by Banerjee et al. (2001), Bogomolnaia and Jackson (2002).

  5. We owe this concept to Sertel (1992) whose formulation in an abstract setting has been worked on by Eren (1993) and further treated in detail by Sertel (1998, 2003). The concept has been applied to more structured frameworks, such as the worker-partnership model proposed by Sertel (1982); the pure public good production problem analyzed by Asan and Sanver (2003) and the coalition formation analysis of Ozkal-Sanver (2005), Nizamogullari and Ozkal-Sanver (2011) in matching problems.

  6. Bergstrom et al. (1986) give a detailed analysis of the voluntary contributions solution (VCS) which is well known to pave the way to inefficient allocations. Our choice of VCS as the prevailing allocation rule is rather arbitrary. It can be justified by assuming the non-existence of institutions which implement efficient allocation rules. After all, our interest is not toward the efficiency of the considered public good allocation rule, but toward the efficiency of institutions leading to jurisdiction formations under a given allocation rule. Moreover, we conjecture that our results prevail under any allocation rule which satisfies the population monotonicity condition used by Sertel and Yildiz (1998).

  7. We owe this terminology to Drèze and Greenberg (1980) who call the dependence of an agent’s payoff to only the members of his coalition the “hedonic aspect.” A thorough analysis of hedonic coalition structures is made by Bogomolnaia and Jackson (2002).

  8. i.e., the entrance to a jurisdiction requires the consent of all members of that jurisdiction.

  9. i.e., the exit from a jurisdiction requires the consent of all members of that jurisdiction.

  10. Bergstrom et al. (1986) show that this will be unique in our assumed environment. From now on we let E be the set of economies (with normal private and public goods) where any \(K\subseteq N\) leads to a voluntary contributions allocation \(V(K)\) with \(y^{*}>0\), i.e., there is at least one agent who contributes to the public budget.

  11. A partition of \(K\) is a finite family \(\{K_{t}\}\) of pairwise disjoint subsets of \(K\) such that \(\bigcup K_{t}=K\). While the usual definition requires each \(K_{t}\) to be non-empty, we relax the definition by treating the partitions \(\{K_{t}\}\) and \(\{K_{t}\}\cup \{\emptyset \}\) equivalently.

  12. Individual stability of \(\pi \in \varPi \) under FE–FX is equivalent to the free mobility equilibrium as defined in Conley and Konishi (2002). Bogomolnaia and Jackson (2002) identify, in a general hedonic setting, conditions that ensure the existence of individually stable partitions. Note that individual stability under FE–FX (resp, AE–FX, AE–AX) is called Nash stability (resp., individual stability, contractual individual stability) by Bogomolnaia and Jackson (2002).

  13. \( T\backslash S\) is empty when \(T\subseteq S\). This violates the usual definition of a partition. However, as noted in Footnote 11, we allow partitions to include the emptyset.

  14. The fact that coalitional moves generalize individual moves does not imply that coalitional stability generalizes individual stability. For, conceiving the move of \(i\) from \(\pi (i)\) to \(L\in \pi \) as the \(\rho -\)move of \(L\cup \{i\}\) imposes an implicit approved entry requirement to the individual move of \(i\), as no member of \(L\cup \{i\}\) must be worsed-off by the \(\rho -\)move of \(L\cup \{i\}\). Note that coalitional stability of \(\pi \in \varPi \) under FE–FX is stronger than the Conley and Konishi (2002) definition of strong Tiebout equilibrium.

  15. We say that \(\pi \in \varPi \) is efficient iff there exists no \(\pi ^{\prime }\in \varPi \) such that \(v_{i}(\pi ^{\prime })\ge v_{i}(\pi ) \forall i\in N\) and \(v_{i}(\pi ^{\prime })>v_{i}(\pi )\) for some \(i\in N\). Due to the finiteness of the society (hence the finiteness of the logically possible partitions), every \(e\in E\) admits an efficient jurisdiction structure.

  16. The intuition behind this claim -which we will justify soon- is related to the seminal work of Buchanan (1965) which determines the optimal size of jurisdictions.

  17. The first part of Theorem 4 below follows from Proposition 3 of Bogomolnaia and Jackson (2002) which shows, in a general hedonic setting, that all efficient coalition structures are “contractually individually stable”. (See Footnote 12).

  18. As a matter of fact, the economies in the proof of Theorem 2 do not fit the definition of crowding-convexity. However, they can easily be rendered crowding-convex (by making \(M\) increase with the number of agents within a coalition) without harming the results they establish.

  19. see Footnote 15.

  20. which we non-exhaustively cite.

  21. such as in Bogomolnaia and Jackson (2002). See Footnote 12.

References

  • Asan, G., & Sanver, M. R. (2003). Coalition structural games and the voluntary provision of public goods. In M. R. Sertel & S. Koray (Eds.), Advances in economic design (pp. 251–259). Berlin: Springer-Verlag.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Banerjee, S., Konishi, H., & Sonmez, T. (2001). Core in a simple coalition formation game. Social Choice Welfare, 18, 135–153.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bergstrom, T., Blume, L., & Varian, H. (1986). On the private provision of public goods. Journal of Public Economics, 29, 25–49.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bewley, T. (1981). A critique of Tiebout’s theory of local public expenditure. Econometrica, 49, 713–740.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bogomolnaia, A., & Jackson, M. O. (2002). The stability of hedonic coalition structures. Games and Economic Behavior, 38(2), 201–230.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. M. (1965). An economic theory of clubs. Economica, 32, 1–14.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. M., & Goetz, C. (1972). Efficiency limits of fiscal mobility. Journal of Public Economics, 1, 25–45.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Conley, J. P., & Konishi, H. (2002). Migration proof Tiebout equilibrium: Existence and asymptotic efficiency. Journal of Public Economics, 86, 243–262.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Drèze, J., & Greenberg, J. (1980). Hedonic coalitions: Optimality and stability. Econometrica, 48, 987–1003.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eren, Nİ. (1993). Coalition structural games and stability under membership property right axioms. Unpublished M.A. Thesis, Boğaziçi University

  • Flatters, F., Henderson, V., & Mieszkowski, P. (1974). Public goods, efficiency and regional fiscal equalization. Journal of Public Economics, 3, 99–112.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Greenberg, J. (1983). Local public goods with mobility: Existence and optimality of a general equilibrium under. Journal of Economic Theory, 30, 17–33.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Greenberg, J., & Weber, S. (1986). Strong Tiebout equilibrium under restricted preference domain. Journal of Economic Theory, 28, 101–117.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Greenberg, J., & Weber, S. (1993). Stable coalition structures with unidimensional set of alternatives. Journal of Economic Theory, 60, 62–82.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Guesnerie, R., & Oddou, C. (1981). Second best taxation as a game. Journal of Economic Theory, 25, 67–91.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Konishi, H. (1996). Voting with ballots and feet: Existence of equilibrium in a local public good economy. Journal of Economic Theory, 68, 480–509.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Konishi, H., le Breton, M., & Weber, S. (1998). Equilibria in finite local public good economies. Journal of Economic Theory, 79, 224–244.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McGuire, M. (1974). Group segregation and optimal jurisdictions. Journal of Political Economy, 82, 112–132.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nizamogullari, D., & Ozkal-Sanver, I. (2011). Coalitional stability and efficiency of partitions in matching problems. Theory and Decision, 71(3), 395–407.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ozkal-Sanver, I. (2005). Stability and efficiency of partitions in matching problems. Theory and Decision, 59(3), 193–205.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Richter, D. K. (1982). Weakly democratic regular tax equilibria in a local public goods economy with perfect consumer mobility. Journal of Economic Theory, 27, 137–162.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sertel, M. R. (1982). Workers and incentives (Vol. 140)., Contributions to Economic Analysis Amsterdam, New York: North-Holland.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sertel, M. R. (1992). Membership property rights, efficiency and stability. Istanbul: Bo ğaziçi University Research Papers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sertel, M.R. (1998). Designing rights: Invisible hand and decentralizability theorems. ASSET Lecture delivered at the annual meeting of ASSET in Bologna.

  • Sertel, M. R. (2003). Designing rights. New York: Mimeo.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sertel, M. R., & Yildiz, M. (1998). The Lindahl solution with changing population and resources. Mathematical Social Sciences, 35(2), 151–163.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tiebout, C. (1956). A pure theory of local expenditures. Journal of Political Economy, 64, 416–424.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wooders, M. H. (1978). Equilibria, the core and jurisdictions structures in economies with a local public good. Journal of Economic Theory, 18, 328–348.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Goksel Asan.

Additional information

This paper has been presented at the Eighth International Meeting of the Association for Public Economic Theory, 6–8 July 2007, Nashville and the 29’th Bosphorus Workshop on Economic Design, 25 August–1 September 2007, Bodrum. We thank the participants. Remzi Sanver acknowledges the support of the Turkish Academy of Science Distinguished Young Scientist Award Program (TUBA-GEBİP).

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Asan, G., Sanver, M.R. The Tiebout hypothesis under membership property rights. Theory Decis 78, 457–469 (2015). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11238-014-9430-7

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11238-014-9430-7

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation