Skip to main content
Log in

Climbing up the Social Ladders: Identity, Relative Income, and Subjective Well-being

  • Published:
Social Indicators Research Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This study incorporates the concept of identity to explain the relationship between relative income and subjective well-being. Based upon the theoretical framework of an identity model developed by Akerlof and Kranton Q J Econ 115:715–753, (2000), the empirical findings of this study suggest that an increase in relative income leads to a gain in positional identity and therefore raises the level of subjective well-being. This approach extends our understanding about the connection between positional concern and subjective well-being and explains the importance of social comparison in shaping individuals’ preferences and tastes. People are concerned about their relative income as it represents a positional identity of social status, dependent upon ideals and norms derived from the interactions between an individual and others within a society.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. The ordered probit model is usually can be described as \( y^{*} = \beta^{'} x + \varepsilon \), where \( y^{*} \)is an unobservable latent variable. What can be observed is:

    $$ \begin{array}{*{20}c} {y = 0\;if\;y^{*} \le 0,} \hfill \\ {y = 1\;if\;0 < y^{*} \le \mu_{1} ,} \hfill \\ {y = 2\;if\;\mu_{1} < y^{*} \le \mu_{2} ,} \hfill \\ {y = 3\;if\;\mu_{2} < y^{*} \le \mu_{3} ,} \hfill \\ \cdot \hfill \\ \cdot \hfill \\ {y = J\;if\;\mu_{J - 1} \le y^{*} ,} \hfill \\ \end{array} $$

    where \( \mu \)’s are unknown parameters to be estimated with \( \beta \). In an ordered probit estimation, the marginal effects of the regressors x on the probabilities are not equal to the coefficients. Since there are four possible values (very satisfied = 3, satisfied = 2, somewhat satisfied or somewhat dissatisfied = 1, dissatisfied or very dissatisfied = 0 about the level of life satisfaction) for the dependent variable (y, Satisfaction) in our ordered probit estimation, the marginal effects of an explanatory variable (x) indicating the changes in the probabilities of each possible values of the dependent variable caused by a one-unit change of the explanatory variable can be calculated by \( \frac{\partial Prob(y = 3)}{\partial x},\frac{\partial Prob(y = 2)}{\partial x},\frac{\partial Prob(y = 1)}{\partial x} , {\text{and}}\;\frac{\partial Prob(y = 0)}{\partial x} \), (Greene 2000). The marginal effects of the regressors x (explanatory variables) from our ordered probit estimations are found to be very similar to the coefficients from the OLS regressions. To save space, they are not reported in the paper, but they are available from the author upon request.

References

  • Akerlof, G. (1997). Social distance and social decisions. Econometrica, 65, 1005–1027.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Akerlof, G., & Kranton, R. (2000). Economics and identity. Quarterly Journal of Economics., 115, 715–753.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Akerlof, G., & Kranton, R. (2010). Identity conomics. Princeton, New Jersey: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Alpizar, F., Carlsson, F., & Johansson-Stenman, O. (2005). How much do we care about absolute versus relative income and consumption? Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 56, 405–421.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bjørnskov, C. (2006). The multiple facets of social capital. European Journal of Political Economy, 22(1), 22–40.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bjørnskov, C., Dreher, A., Fischer, J., & Schnellenbach, J. (2009). On the relation between income inequality and happiness: Do fairness perception matter? MPRA paper no. 19502.

  • Blanchflower, D. G., & Oswald, A. J. (2004). Well-being over time in Britain and the USA. Journal of Public Economics, 88, 1359–1386.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Booth, A. L., & van Ours, J. C. (2009). Hours of work and gender identity: does part-time work make the family happier. Economica, 76, 176–196.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Breen, R., & Goldthorpe, J. H. (2001). Class, mobility and merit, the experience of two British birth cohorts. European Sociological Review, 17, 81–101.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brennan, G. (1973). Pareto desirable redistribution: the case of malice and envy. Journal of Public Economics, 2, 173–183.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brown, R. W. (1986). Social psychology: The second edition. New York: Free Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brown, G., Gardner, J., Oswald, A., & Qian, J. (2008). Does wage rank affect employees’ well-being? Industrial Relations, 47(3), 355–389.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bygren, M. (2004). Pay reference standards and pay satisfaction: What do workers evaluate their pay against? Social Science Research, 33(2), 206–224.

    Google Scholar 

  • Carlsson, F., Johansson-Stenman, O., & Martinsson, P. (2007). ‘Do you enjoy having more than others? Survey evidence of positional goods’, Economica, 74, 586–598.

    Google Scholar 

  • Carlsson, F., Gupta, G., & Johansson-Stenman, O. (2008). Keeping up with the Vaishyas? Caste and relative standing in India. Oxford Economic Papers, 61, 52–73.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carlsson, F., Gupta, G., & Johansson-Stenman, O. (2009). Keeping up with the Vaishyas? Caste and relative standing in India. Oxford Economic Papers, 61, 52–73.

    Google Scholar 

  • Clark, A. E. (1997). Job satisfaction and gender: why are women so happy at work? Labour Economics, 4, 341–372.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clark, A., & Oswald, A. (1994). Unhappiness and unemployment. Economic Journal, 104(424), 648–659.

    Google Scholar 

  • Clark, A. E., & Oswald, A. J. (1996). Satisfaction and comparison income. Journal of Public Economics, 61, 359–381.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clark, A., & Senik, C. (2010). ‘Who compares to whom? The anatomy of income comparison in Europe. Economic Journal, 120, 573–594.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clark, A., Frijters, P., & Shields, M. (2008). Relative income, happiness and utility: an explanation for the Easterlin Paradox and other puzzles. Journal of Economic Literature, 46, 95–144.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clark, A., Kristensen, N., & Westergård-Nielsen, N. (2009). Economic satisfaction and income rank in small neighbourhoods. Journal of the European Economic Association, 7(2–3), 519–527.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cole, H. L., Mailath, G. J., & Postlewaite, A. (1998). Class systems and the enforcement of social norms. Journal of Public Economics, 70, 5–35.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cooper, B., Funk, P., & Garcia-Penalosa, C. (2001). Status effects and negative utility growth. Economic Journal, 111(473), 642–665.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Davis, J. B. (2006). Social identity strategies in recent economics. Journal of Economic Methodology, 13(3), 371–390.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Davis, J. B. (2007). Akerlof and Kranton on identity in economics: inverting the analysis. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 31, 349–362.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Duesenberry, J. S. (1949). Income, savings and the theory of consumer behavior. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Easterlin, R. A. (1974). Does economic growth improve the human lot? some empirical evidence. In R. David & R. Reder (Eds.), Nations and households in economic growth: Essays in honor of Moses Abramovitz (pp. 89–125). New York: Academic Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Easterlin, R. A. (1995). Will raising the incomes of all increase the happiness of all? Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 27, 35–47.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Easterlin, R. A. (2001). Income and happiness: towards a unified theory. Economic Journal, 111, 465–484.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ellison, C. G. (1991). Religious Involvement and subjective well-being. Journal of Health and Social Behavior, 32, 80–99.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ferrer-i-Carbonell, A. (2005). Income and well-being: an empirical analysis of the comparison income effect. Journal of Public Economics, 89, 997–1019.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frank, R. (1991). Positional externalities. In R. Zeckhauser (Ed.), Strategy and choice: Essays in honor of Thomas C. Schelling (pp. 25–47). Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

  • Frank, R. H. (1985a). Choosing the right pond: Human behavior and the quest for status. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Frank, R. H. (1985b). The demand for unobservable and other nonpositional goods. American Economic Review, 75, 101–116.

    Google Scholar 

  • Frey, B. S., & Stutzer, A. (2000). Happiness, economy and institutions. Economic Journal, 110, 918–938.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Glaeser, E., Laibson, D., & Sacerdote, B. (2002). An economic approach to social capital. Economic Journal, 112, F437–F458.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Greene, W. H. (2000). Econometric Analysis (4th ed.). NJ: Prentice-Hall.

    Google Scholar 

  • Helliwell, J. F. (2007). Well-being and social capital: does suicide pose a puzzle? Social Indicators Research, 81, 455–496.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hirschman, A., & Rothschild, M. (1973). The changing tolerance for income inequality in the course of economic development. Quarterly Journal of Economics., 87, 544–566.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Johansson-Stenman, O., Carlsson, F., & Daruvala, D. (2002). Measuring future grandparents’ preferences for equality and relative standing. Economic Journal, 112, 362–383.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman, D., Krueger, A., Schkade, D., Schwarz, N., & Stone, A. (2006). ‘Would you be happier if you were richer? A focusing illusion. Science, 312, 1908–1910.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Klor, E., & Shayo, M. (2010). Social identity and preferences over redistribution. Journal of Public Economics, 94, 269–278.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Knight, J., Song, L., & Gunatilaka, R. (2009). Subjective well-being and its determinants in rural China. China Economic Review, 20(4), 635–649.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Luttmer, E. F. (2005). Neighbors as negatives: relative earnings and well-being. Quarterly Journal of Economics., 120(3), 963–1002.

    Google Scholar 

  • Marsh, R. M. (2003). How important is social class identification in Taiwan? Sociological Quarterly, 44(1), 37–59.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McIntosh, J., & Munk, M. D. (2009). Social Class, family background, and intergenerational mobility. European Economic Review, 53, 107–117.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Melenberg, B. (1992). Micro-econometric models of consumer behaviors and welfare. unpublished doctoral thesis, Tilburg University.

  • Miles, D., & Rossi, M. (2007). Learning about one’s relative position and subjective well-being. Applied Economics, 39, 1711–1718.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mui, V.-L. (1995). The economics of envy. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 26, 311–336.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ng, Y.-K. (1997). A case for happiness, cardinalism, and interpersonal comparability. Economic Journal, 107, 1848–1858.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Oswald, A. (1997). Happiness and economic performance. Economic Journal, 107, 1815–1831.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pingle, M., & Mitchell, M. (2002). What motivates positional concerns for income? Journal of Economic Psychology, 23, 127–148.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sen, A. (1985). Goals, commitment and identity. Journal of Law Economics and Organization, 1(2), 341–355.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sen, A. (1999). Reason before identity. New Delhi: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Senik, C. (2004). When information dominates comparison: learning from Russian subjective panel data. Journal of Public Economics, 88, 2099–2123.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Senik, C. (2008). Ambition and jealousy: income interactions in the ‘old’ Europe versus the ‘new’ Europe and the United States. Economica, 75, 495–513.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Senik, C. (2009). Direct evidence on income comparisons and their welfare effects. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 72, 408–424.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Solnick, S., & Hemenway, D. (1998). ‘Is more always better? A survey on positional concerns’, Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 37, 373–383.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Solnick, S., & Hemenway, D. (2005). Are positional concerns stronger in some domains than in others? American Economic Review, 95(2), 147–151.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Solnick, S., Hong, L., & Hemenway, D. (2007). Positional goods in the United States and China. Journal of Socio-Economics, 36, 537–545.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stutzer, A. (2004). The role of income aspirations in individual happiness. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 54, 89–109.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tajfel, H., & Turner, J. (1986). Social identity theory of intergroup behavior. In S. Worchel & W. G. Austin (Eds.), The psychology of intergroup relations. Chicago: Nelson-Hall.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tajfel, H., Billig, M. G., Bundy, R. P., & Flament, C. (1971). Social categorization and intergroup behavior. European Journal of Social Psychology, 1(2), 149–178.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tao, H.-L., & Chiu, S.-Y. (2009). The effects of relative income and absolute income on happiness. Review of Development Economics, 13(1), 164–174.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • van de Stadt, H., Kapteyn, A., & van de Geer, S. (1985). The relativity of utility: evidence from panel data. Review of Economics and Statistics, 67, 179–187.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Van Praag, B. (2011). Well-being inequality and reference groups: an agenda for new research. Journal of Economic Inequality, 9, 111–127.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Varian, H. R. (1974). Equity, envy, and efficiency. Journal of Economic Theory, 9, 63–91.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Veblen, T. (1899). The theory of the leisure class. New York, George Allen and Unwin, London: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Watson, T. & McLanahan, S. (2009). Marriage meets the Joneses: relative income, identity, and marital status. NBER working paper no. 14773.

  • Wetherell, M. (1996). Group conflict and the social psychology of racism. In M. Wetherell (Ed.), Group conflict and the social psychology of racism. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage Publications.

    Google Scholar 

  • Winkelmann, L., & Wilkelmann, R. (1997). Why are the unemployed so unhappy? Evidence from panel data. Economica, 65, 1–15.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Wen-Chun Chang.

Appendices

Appendix 1

See Table 5.

Table 5 Definitions of variables

Appendix 2

See Table 6.

Table 6 Descriptive statistics for the full sample (N = 1,502)

Appendix 3

See Table 7.

Table 7 Descriptive statistics for the subsamples, Position = 1 versus Position = 0

Appendix 4

See Table 8.

Table 8 Income distribution

Appendix 5

See Table 9.

Table 9 Estimation of life satisfaction with an interaction term

Appendix 6

See Table 10.

Table 10 Estimation of life satisfaction with an interaction term reference income sorted by occupation

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Chang, WC. Climbing up the Social Ladders: Identity, Relative Income, and Subjective Well-being. Soc Indic Res 113, 513–535 (2013). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11205-012-0108-7

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11205-012-0108-7

Keywords

Navigation