Skip to main content
Log in

Scientific Research: Commodities or Commons?

  • Published:
Science & Education Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Truth is for sale today, some critics claim. The increased commodification of science corrupts it, scientific fraud is rampant and the age-old trust in science is shattered. This cynical view, although gaining in prominence, does not explain very well the surprising motivation and integrity that is still central to the scientific life. Although scientific knowledge becomes more and more treated as a commodity or as a product that is for sale, a central part of academic scientific practice is still organized according to different principles. In this paper, I critically analyze alternative models for understanding the organization of knowledge, such as the idea of the scientific commons and the gift economy of science. After weighing the diverse positive and negative aspects of free market economies of science and gift economies of science, a commons structured as a gift economy seems best suited to preserve and take advantage of the specific character of scientific knowledge. Furthermore, commons and gift economies promote the rich social texture that is important for supporting central norms of science. Some of these basic norms might break down if the gift character of science is lost. To conclude, I consider the possibility and desirability of hybrid economies of academic science, which combine aspects of gift economies and free market economies. The aim of this paper is to gain a better understanding of these deeper structural challenges faced by science policy. Such theoretical reflections should eventually assist us in formulating new policy guidelines.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. A later correction of March 24, 2009 in the New York Times softened the accusation somewhat, claiming that ‘Reuben fabricated data in some or all of 21 journal articles’.

  2. See Gibbons et al. (1994), Bok (2003), Gould (2003), Slaughter and Rhoades (2004), Nowotny et al. (2005), Greenberg (2007), Tuchman (2009), Radder (2010), Berman (2012).

  3. Arrow (1962), Johnson (1972), Goldman and Shaked (1991), Kealey (1996), Stephan (1996), Wible (1998), Stephan and Audretsch (2000), Audretsch et al. (2002), Foray (2004). See also the related field (and journal) of scientometrics, which deals with the mechanism of scientific research analyzed by means of (e.g. statistical) mathematical methods.

  4. Radder’s ‘Commodification in the broader sense’ is useful, but it is fruitful to expand it even more so that it comes to include phenomena such as bibliometry, used e.g. to measure the value of scientists ‘objectively’. Such techniques, in themselves not directly aimed at increasing economic activity, are often deployed for the economic instrumentalization of science.

  5. For ‘commodity’ see the Oxford English Dictionary (OED). Commodification is ‘The action of turning something into, or treating something as, a (mere) commodity; commercialization of an activity, etc., that is not by nature commercial.’ According to the Online Etymology Dictionary, ‘commodification’ (from commodity + -fication) was first used in 1968, originally in Marxist political theory. It means ‘the assignment of a market value’ and is often used with a negative connotation. According to the Online Etymology Dictionary ‘commoditization’ (from commodity + -ization) is the businessman's form of the word, but the uses mentioned in the OED seem to contradict this.

  6. I should add the caveat that there exist many different kinds of management models, some of which are better adapted to fostering creativity and invention (see also the discussion below). See e.g. the Competing Values Framework by Quinn and Rohrbauch, as well as new calls for leadership at companies instead of management. Historically, however, management was first developed in the factory, where management assured control of the many ‘workers’ needed to perform their task. (Etymologically, management originally meant handling horses and later came to stand for controlling persons.) Without the strict rules defined by management, it was thought that chaos would reign. When knowledge work became more important, management was still the solution for keeping people in line. It is to this original idea of management, aiming at controlling workers by standardization, focussing on efficiency and production, etc., that I will be referring to in this article.

  7. Cf. ‘commodification is the process by which goods or services formerly outside a market enter a market, acquire exchange value, and are subsequently produced for profit’ (Nelson and Barley 1995, p. 623).

  8. This characterization of commodification is different but compatible with the two components of commodification mentioned in Connelly and Gallagher (2007, p. 104): ‘the commodification of academic research has two components: the treatment of research products as interchangeable, and the assignment of a market value to these outputs. That which was once viewed as a ‘craft’ becomes a standardized product.’

  9. Cf. the talk by Sir Tim Wilson, former vice-chancellor and ‘CEO’ of the University of Hertfordshire (and HEFCE board member) at the at the Conference Humboldt’s Model. The Future of Universities in the World of Research. Humboldt-Universität Berlin. 7–9 October 2010.

  10. Although these journals work by means of peer-review, peer-to-peer evaluation is more and more under pressure because reviewers are also scientists under pressure to produce scientific results, and a critical engagement with their colleagues work is hardly valorized. Because almost no credit goes to peer-reviewers, more and more scholars refuse to do the work or they do it less thoroughly. Furthermore, counting discrete evaluations (e.g. acceptance by journals) does not necessarily lead to a good general evaluation (one evident example is self-plagiarism, in which each contribution might be good but the aggregate subpar.).

  11. For market exchange, the parties do not need to agree on the same ‘value’ of the commodity, but they need to agree on a price-setting which is a reduction to a one-dimensional value. Accurate measurement or estimation procedures are crucial for this process. When it is difficult to estimate the value of the assets (e.g. financial assets that are very sensitive to economic conditions, which might be very uncertain in specific periods as in 2007–2008), price-setting breaks down and the markets freeze (cf. the recent market crisis in collateral debt obligations).

  12. Good science usually leads to good effective products, but sometimes false science or pseudo-science is less expensive and a better sales strategy, especially in cases of uncertainty, when clients have no means of assessing the quality of the product (cf. in medicine or the nutrients industry).

  13. Resnik (2007, pp. 91–92), Steneck (2002), Shapin (2008, pp. 86–89). On scientific fraud, see also Judson (2004).

  14. Later in this article I will characterize funding without strings attached as part of a gift economy. Charitable private funding of cancer research obviously presents few problems, but professorial chairs in astrology (cf. the Sophia Project at Bath Spa University) and para-psychology (cf. the chair of parapsychology at Utrecht) funded by interested benefactors or societies are another matter. The creation of the Polanyi Center for fostering Intelligent Design research at Baylor University is also an interesting case. Yet even the charitable private funding of cancer research might generate bias in research topics (cf. Resnik 2007).

  15. For the nonprofit economy, see e.g. Weisbrod (1988), Rose-Ackerman (1986).

  16. Management at some industrial research laboratories and in some creative industries is aware that research results cannot be judged according to the normal standards of efficiency. In a specific set of examples, Shapin (2008, pp. 127–164) estimated that less than a quarter of the companies had formal methods to evaluate the scientific output, and even less calculated whether the benefits outweighed the costs. In these cases, although some of the research products were commodified and sold for profit, the management structure was not.

  17. Personal discussion with Helga Nowotny and discussions at the Conference Humboldt’s Model (see note 9).

  18. For a survey of the evidence and literature, see Frey and Jegen (2001); see also Benkler (2004a).

  19. For the negative effect of managerial culture and the introduction of evaluations, educational testing and extrinsic motivation for education, see e.g. Sahlberg (2011) and Ravitch (2012).

  20. This is not to deny that individual scientists may have all kinds of motives for doing their research. These motives are, however, not institutionalized. For an integrative theory about individual open source software developer motivation, integrating intrinsic and extrinsic motivation, see Krishnamurthy (2006).

  21. Resnik explains that 90 % of biomedical funds are spent on the research of 10 % of the known diseases. These 10 % include the most common diseases but also the (often not live threatening) diseases that affect the wealthy and the diseases typical for the developed world. Money determines which research is executed and which is left aside. See also Carrier (1995) and concretely on biomedical funds, Benatar (2000).

  22. This is not totally surprising, since a lot of research is specifically commissioned to answer specific questions, but the trend is worrying nonetheless (Resnik 2007; Krimsky 2003).

  23. Even if the corporate world, in rare cases, needs to take a longer term view (e.g. the building of a nuclear power plant takes almost a decade), the sciences are one of the few areas were long-term phenomena are studied, from climate change to cosmic time.

  24. Hardin also describes an open access system rather than a commons. The latter is a resource shared between a particular set of people, with boundaries and rules of access in place.

  25. See Ostrom (1990) and case studies in Ostrom and Shivakoti (2002), Ostrom (1992), Bromley et al. (1992).

  26. See Hess and Ostrom (2007) where examples such as the internet, an archive or a library are discussed. See also Brown (2000). For another approach, see Benkler (2004b)

  27. Coase (1960) has argued that externalities can be thought of in terms of the costs of transacting over rights to undertake actions that affect other people. Demsetz (2003) has objected, however that externalities would still exist when transaction costs are zero. For a discussion, see McChesney (2006).

  28. Callon (1994), in contrast, has argued that science is not a public good because of its intrinsic properties, but because being a source of diversity and flexibility.

  29. There are different kinds of knowledge, some more fundamental, applied, technical or practical, etc. In principle, nonrivalrousness and almost nonexcludability hold for most kinds of knowledge (even top secret intelligence knowledge is spread worldwide by Wikileaks, showing that it is nonexcludable) while other properties are more specific for scientific knowledge.

  30. Intellectual property protection allows circulation by prohibiting fee use, and is preferred to trade secrecy, which is a more extreme case of privatization of knowledge. On the tension between knowledge production and circulation, see Foray (2004, pp. 113–118).

  31. For an analysis determining whether commons or market systems are best, depending on the nature of the resources, see Benkler (2003, 2004a). For new research critical of intellectual property rights, see Boldrin and Levine (2002, 2008).

  32. Shapin (2008, pp. 127–164).

  33. Cf. also Shapin (2008, pp. 269–303), who argues that even venture capitalists, often regarded as the wolves or vultures of the capitalist system, know that objective measures do not work for assessing the creative industry. Before they decide to invest, they do not run mathematical models and crunch numbers about efficiency and output; they rather judge the characters of the investigators, their motivations and ideas on a direct and personal basis.

  34. Ironically, many current writers on the commons model their topic on the scientific commons, ignoring the increasing commodification of science.

  35. See Mauss (1924), Malinowski (1932), Sahlins (1972), Macherel (1983), Cheal (1988), Godbout (1992), Godelier (1999); for a historical perspective, see Carrier (1995) and Davis (2000); for the gift in the arts, see Hyde (2007). See also my chapter in Krijnen et al. (2011) on which the following paragraphs are based.

  36. On 18 February 2009, the Dutch philosopher Hans Radder was asked by the Dutch Science Foundation to referee a grant application. In his reply, he states that according to market rates, this kind of consulting would cost 2700 euro for the referee report. In an e-mailed circular, he argued that he wanted to take a stance against the managerial university and the valorization of research, by extrapolating the market reasoning of current research policy, showing that it leads to a reductio at absurdum. In a reaction to the circular, Radder’s colleague Christian Krijnen calculated that at this rate, one funding program of the Dutch Science Foundation would cost 700.000 euro on referee costs only—which would mean an unsustainable cost.

  37. As many social forms, the gift system can of course be cynically manipulated, but if this is publicly expressed or exposed, the exchange of gifts ceases and the manipulator becomes excluded from the gift system.

  38. This is clearly not the case in all professions and there are also big differences within a profession. Within the law, for instance, practicing attorneys receiving high fees for writing papers have a high standing in the profession. For a judge, on the other hand, taking money for writing an opinion is a subversion of his social role and a sign of corruption (Benkler 2004a, p. 327).

  39. Klein (2012): ‘Campaign contributions are part of the cash economy. Lobbyists are hired because they understand how to participate in the gift economy.’

  40. On student lunches, personal discussion with Marcia Angell in 2006; see also Angell (2004) and Lakoff (2004) for other abusive gift giving.

  41. Lessig (2008b) has argued that our youth becomes more and more criminalized by current law, when 70 % of young people obtain digital information from ‘illegal’ sources. Lessig concludes that the law should be changed.

  42. As Benkler (2004a) argues, new technologies can make sharing more efficient than traditional markets, and decentralized social sharing can be an economically attractive modality of production.

  43. Indeed, understanding science as a gift economy can help explaining why academic researchers in general are so surprisingly honest—especially when compared to other domains of society. (See also Benkler and Nissenbaum (2006), who argue that commons-based peer production is conductive to virtuous behavior, and that a society providing opportunities for virtuous behavior will be more conducive to virtuous individuals.) Truthfulness is one of the central values that constitute science socially as well as epistemically. Scientific fraud is at variance with the core norms of academic science, and it is therefore severely punished and perpetrators are ostracized from the scientific community. A gift culture also explains why academic researchers work so hard for a remuneration that is hardly comparable to other jobs of similar qualification. They do not value their contributions according to the standards of the market. Scientists receive a gift from society—the gift of time and resources they can devote to the problems that they are passionate about—and they return this gift in the form of scientific contributions.

  44. The notion of disinterestedness is somewhat fluid in the definition of gifts as well as in science, and its exact meaning depends on the particular situation, the context and the culture. See e.g. the historical examples in Davis (2000).

  45. For an overview of the discussion on secrecy and science, see Vermeir and Margocsy (2012). On open access publishing, e.g. Willetts (2012). Open access databases specifically warn for putting online patentable material.

  46. Quote of an open source contributor, cited in Bergquist and Ljungberg (2001, p. 315). See also Goldman and Gabriel (2005, chapters 8 and 9) for practical advice for companies about the special social norms of open source.

  47. Note, however, that as I have shown above, imbalances and abuse of power exist also in gift economies, especially if they are local and personalized. See also Bergquist and Ljungberg (2001, p. 315) for an interesting case for power abuse in impersonal gift economies, although the actual impact of such power abuse is forcefully put into question by the practitioners themselves. Gift exchange normally confirms the existing social relations, hierarchical or egalitarian, and if a community is based on egalitarian principles, gift exchange will usually not change this.

  48. Note that scientists are not alienated from the results of their work, but this does not mean that these results cannot be common property.

  49. If fraud occurs, it is usually discovered after a while, however, because of the interconnectedness of topics and projects, but this may take a considerable time, as in the story in the introduction of this paper.

  50. Accountability has also a good side, of course: society may expect something back, even in a gift economy. It is only not measurable by a cost-benefit analysis. Furthermore, it is not only economic interest, but also immeasurable benefits such as increase in civilization, culture, knowledge, tolerance, Bildung, etc. that should be accounted for in discussions of accountability.

  51. The much vaunted transparency, objectivity and accountability can just as well become a cover up for bias and abuse of executive power. For discussions about rankings, see e.g. Connelly and Gallagher (2007); about the danger of rankings: the interested parties and the public easily accept rankings because they provide simple information, ready to be consumed (AUBR 2010).

  52. As I have argued, much of science is about the exchange of tacit knowledge, and the positive effects of gift exchange do require a rich social texture, but this social texture should not become too personal and should not be confined to the local level only.

  53. On the one hand, there is the commons of the scientific community, determined by the gift economy that I described above. This gift economy is partly personal (close colleagues), partly impersonal (unknown colleagues, blind review), and exchanges of goods (ideas, drafts, results, sometimes funding) are between peers. On the other hand, there is also the public commons of science, in which scientific research is available to all. This gift economy is impersonal, and involves translations of public funding in scientific results, which should be accessible to the public.

  54. This distinction is also clear in the difference in remuneration between academic service and external consultancy service given by academic scientists (see Sect. 4, and the problems with full commodification, cf. note 36).

  55. The Bayh-Dole Act (1980), the Stevenson-Wydler Act (1980), and the Federal Technology Transfer Act (1986) allow the commodification of scientific products (Cf. Rhoades and Slaughter 2004).

  56. Foray (2004) suggests that different types of knowledge production are useful and a diversity of systems seems to promote productive synergies.

  57. In the past, publishers were paid for the service of distributing scientific knowledge. Recent technological advances seem to suggest that open access is the best way to disseminate scientific knowledge, for instance, and science publishers will have to adapt (Cf. Willetts 2012).

  58. For mechanical objectivity and expert judgment as different regimes of objectivity, see Daston and Galison (2007).

References

  • Angell, M. (2004). The truth about drug companies. New York: Random House.

    Google Scholar 

  • Arrow, K. J. (1962). Economic welfare and the allocation of resources for inventions. In R. Nelson (Ed.), The rate and direction of inventive activity: Economic and social factors (pp. 609–625). Princeton: Princeton University Press.

  • Arrow, K. J. (1972). Gifts and exchanges. Philosophy & Public Affairs, 1(4), 343–362.

    Google Scholar 

  • Arrow, K. J. (1996). The economics of information: An exposition. Empirica, 23(2), 119–128.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • AUBR. (2010). Assessing Europe’s university-based research. K1-NA-24187-EN-N (p. 151). Brussels.

  • Audretsch, D. B., Bozeman, B., Combs, K. L., Feldman, M., Link, A. N., Stephan, P., et al. (2002). The economics of science and technology. Journal of Technology Transfer, 27, 155–203.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Benatar, S. (2000). Avoiding exploitation in clinical research. Cambridge Quarterly of Healthcare Ethics, 9, 562–565.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Benkler, Y. (1998). Overcoming agoraphobia: Building the commons of the digitally networked environment. Harvard Journal of Law & Technology, 11, 287–360.

    Google Scholar 

  • Benkler, Y. (2003). The political economy of commons. Upgrade, IV(3), 6–9.

    Google Scholar 

  • Benkler, Y. (2004a). Sharing nicely: On shareable goods and the emergence of sharing as a modality of economic production. The Yale Law Journal, 114, 273–358.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Benkler, Y. (2004b). Commons-based strategies and the problems of patents. Science, 305, 1110–1111.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Benkler, Y. (2005). Common wisdom: Peer production of educational materials. San Francisco: COSL Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Benkler, Y. (2006). The wealth of networks. How social production transforms markets and freedom. New Haven: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Benkler, Y., & Nissenbaum, H. (2006). Commons-based peer production and virtue. The Journal of Political Philosophy, 14(4), 394–419.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Berdou, E. (2011). Organization in open source communities. New York: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bergquist, M., & Ljungberg, J. (2001). The power of gifts: Organizing social relationships in open source communities. Information Systems Journal, 11(4), 305–320.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Berman, E. P. (2012). Creating the market university. How academic science became an economic engine. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Blank, D. M., & Stigler, G. J. (1957). The demand and supply of scientific personnel. New York: National Bureau of Economic Research.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bok, D. (2003). Universities in the marketplace: The commercialization of higher education. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Boldrin, M., & Levine, D. K. (2002). The case against intellectual property. The American Economic Review, 92(2), 209–212.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boldrin, M., & Levine, D. K. (2008). Perfectly competitive innovation. Journal of Monetary Economics, 55(3), 435–453.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brandt, A. (2009). The cigarette century: The rise, fall, and deadly persistence of the product that defined America. New York: Basic Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bromley, D. W., et al. (Eds.). (1992). Making the commons work: Theory, practice, and policy. San Francisco: ICS Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brown, J. (2000). Privatizing the university: The new tragedy of the commons. Science, 290, 1701–1702.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Caillé, A. (1994). Don, intérêt et désintéressement. Paris: La Découverte.

    Google Scholar 

  • Callon, M. (1994). Is science a public good? Science, Technology, & Human Values, 19(4), 395–424.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carrier, J. (1995). Gifts and commodities: Exchange and western capitalism since 1700. London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cheal, D. (1988). The gift economy. London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Coase, R. H. (1960). The problem of social cost. Journal of Law and Economics, 3(1), 1–44.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Connelly, C. E., & Gallagher, D. G. (2007). Making “The List”: Business school rankings and the commodification of business research. Journal of Curriculum Theorizing, 23, 103–116.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dasgupta, P., & David, P. A. (1994). Toward a new economics of science. Policy Research, 23, 487–521.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Daston, L., & Galison, P. (2007). Objectivity. New York: Zone Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Davis, N. Z. (2000). The gift in sixteenth-century France. Madison: The University of Wisconsin Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Demsetz, H. (2003). Ownership and the externality problem. In T. L. Anderson & F. S. McChesney (Eds.), Property rights: Cooperation, conflict, and law. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Diamond, A. M., Jr. (1996). The economics of science. Knowledge and Policy, 9(2&3), 6–49.

    Google Scholar 

  • Diamond, A. M., Jr. (2008). Economics of science. In S. Durlauf and L. Blume (Eds.), The new palgrave dictionary of economics. Palgrave Macmillan.

  • Foray, D. (2004). The economics of knowledge. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Frey, B. S. (1997). Not just for money. An economic theory of personal motivation. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Frey, B. S. (2001). Inspiring economics. Human motivation in political economy. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Frey, B. S., & Jegen, R. (2001). Motivation crowding theory. Journal of Economic Surveys, 15(5), 589–611.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frey, B. S., & Oberholzer-Gee, F. (1997). The cost of price incentives: An empirical analysis of motivation crowding-out. The American Economic Review, 87(4), 746–755.

    Google Scholar 

  • Friedman, P. J. (2002). The impact of conflict of interest on trust in science. Science and Engineering Ethics, 8(3), 413–420.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gibbons, M., Limoges, C., Nowotny, H., Schwartzman, S., Scott, P., & Trow, M. (1994). The new production of knowledge: The dynamics of science and research in contemporary societies. London: Sage Publications.

    Google Scholar 

  • Godbout, J. T. (1992). L’esprit du don. Paris: Éditions La découverte.

    Google Scholar 

  • Godelier, M. (1999). The Enigma of the gift. Chicago: Chicago University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Goldman, R., & Gabriel, R. (2005). Innovation happens elsewhere. Open source as business strategy. San Francisco: Morgan Kaufmann publications.

    Google Scholar 

  • Goldman, A., & Shaked, M. (1991). An economic model of scientific activity and truth acquisition. Philosophical Studies, 63, 31–55.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gould, E. (2003). The university in a corporate culture. New Haven: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Greenberg, D. S. (2007). Science for sale. The Perils, rewards, and delusions of campus capitalism. Chicago: The University of Chicago Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Gregory, C. A. (1982). Gifts and commodities. London: Academic Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Haerlin, B., & Parr, D. (1999). How to restore public trust in science. Nature, 400(5 August), 499.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hagstrom, W. O. (1982). Gift giving as an organisational principle in science. In B. Barnes & D. Edge (Eds.), Science in context: Readings in the sociology of science (pp. 21–34). Milton Keynes: The Open University.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hardin, G. (1968). The tragedy of the Commons. Science, 162(13 December), 1243–1248.

    Google Scholar 

  • Harris, G. (2009). Doctor’s pain studies were fabricated, hospital says. New York Times, (March 10), A22.

  • Hess, C., & Ostrom, E. (2007). Understanding knowledge as a commons. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hicks, D. (1995). Published papers, tacit competencies and corporate management of the public/private character of knowledge. Industrial and Corporate Change, 4(January), 401–424.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hyde, L. (2007). The gift: Creativity and the artist in the modern world. New York: Random House.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jacob, M. (2009). On commodification and the governance of academic research. Minerva, 47(4), 391–405.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Johnson, H. G. (1972). Some economic aspects of science. Minerva, 10(1), 10–18.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Judson, H. F. (2004). The great betrayal: Fraud in science. New York: Harcourt.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kealey, T. (1996). The economic laws of scientific research. New York: St. Martin’s Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Klein, E. (2012). Corrupt politics: It’s not all money. March: New York Review of Books. 22.

    Google Scholar 

  • Krijnen, C., Lorenz, C., & Umlauf, J. (Eds.). (2011). Wahrheit oder Gewinn?: Über die Ökonomisierung von Universität und Wissenschaft. Würzburg: Königshausen & Neumann.

    Google Scholar 

  • Krimsky, S. (2003). Science in the private interest. Lanham: Rowman and Littlefield.

    Google Scholar 

  • Krishnamurthy, S. (2006). On the intrinsic and extrinsic motivation of free/libre/open source (FLOSS) developers. Knowledge, Technology, & Policy, 18(4), 17–39.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lakoff, A. (2004). The anxieties of globalization: Antidepressant sales and economic crisis in Argentina. Social Studies of Science, 34(2), 247–269.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lessig, L. (2008a). Remix. Making art and commerce thrive in the hybrid economy. London: Bloomsbury Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Lessig, L. (2008b). In defense of piracy. Wall Street Journal, (Oct. 11), W3.

  • Lessig, L. (2011). Republic, lost: How money corrupts congress—and a plan to stop it. New York: Twelve.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lock, G., & Lorenz, C. (2007). Revisiting the university front. Studies in Philosophy and Education, 26(5), 405–418.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Macherel, C. (1983). Don et réciprocité en Europe. Archives européennes de sociologie, 24, 151–166.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Malinowski, B. (1932). Argonouts of the Western Pacific. New York: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mauss, M. (1924). Essai sur le don. Forme et raison de l’échange dans les sociétés archaïques. l’Année Sociologique, seconde série, 1, 30–186.

    Google Scholar 

  • McChesney, F. S. (2006). Coase, Demsetz, and the unending externality debate. Cato Journal, 1, 179–200.

    Google Scholar 

  • McLean, I., & Poulton, J. (1986). Good blood, bad blood, and the market: The gift relationship revisited. Journal of Public Policy, 6(4), 431–445.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Merton, R. K. (1979). The normative structure of science. In R. K. Merton (Ed.), The sociology of science: Theoretical and empirical investigations (pp. 267–278). Chicago: Chicago University Press.

  • Mirowski, P., & Sent, E. M. (Eds.). (2002). Science bought and sold: Essays in the economics of science. Chicago: Chicago University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nowotny, H., Pestre, D., Schmidt-Aßmann, E., Schultze-Fielitz, H., & Trute, H.-H. (Eds.). (2005). The public nature of science under assault: Politics, markets, science and the law. Dordrecht: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Oreskes, N., & Conway, E. M. (2010). Merchants of doubt: How a handful of scientists obscured the truth on issues from tobacco to global warming. New York: Bloomsbury Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ostrom, E. (1990). Governing the commons: The evolution of institutions for collective action. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Ostrom, E. (1992). Crafting institutions for self-governing irrigation systems. San Francisco: ICS Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ostrom, E., & Shivakoti, G. (Eds.). (2002). Improving irrigation governance and management in Nepal. Oakland, CA: ICS Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pigou, A. C. (1920). The economics of welfare. London: MacMillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Proctor, R. (2008). Agnotology: The making and unmaking of ignorance. Stanford: Stanford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Radder, H. (2010). The commodification of academic research. Pittsburgh: University of Pittsburgh Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ravitch, D. (2012). Schools we can envy. New York: The New York Review of Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Readings, W. (1996). The University in ruins. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Resnik, D. B. (2007). The price of truth: How money affects the norms of science. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Rhoades, G., & Slaughter, S. (2004). Academic capitalism in the new economy: Challenges and choices. American Academic, 1(1), 37–60.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rose-Ackerman, S. (Ed.). (1986). The economics of nonprofit institutions. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sahlberg, P. (2011). Finnish lessons: What can the world learn from educational change in Finland? New York: Teachers College Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sahlins, M. (1972). Stone age economics. Chicago: Aldine Publishing Company.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shapin, S. (2008). The scientific life: A moral history of a late modern vocation. Chicago: The University of Chicago Press.

  • Singer, P. (1973). Altruism and commerce: A Defense of Titmuss against Arrow. Philosophy and Public Affairs 1, 2(3), 312–320.

    Google Scholar 

  • Slaughter, S., & Rhoades, G. (2004). Academic capitalism in the new economy. Baltimore: The Johns Hopkins University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith, R. J. (1981). Resolving the tragedy of the commons by creating private property rights in wildlife. Cato Journal, 1(2), 439–468.

    Google Scholar 

  • Steneck, N. (2002). Assessing the integrity of publicly funded research. In N. Steneck & M. Scheetz (Eds.), Proceedings for the Office of Research Integrity’s conference on research on research integrity (pp. 1–16). Washington, D. C.: Office of Research Integrity.

  • Stephan, P. E. (1996). The economics of science. Journal of Economic Literature, 34(3), 1199–1235.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stephan, P. E., & Audretsch, D. B. (Eds.). (2000). The economics of science and innovation. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stiglitz, J. (1989). On the economic role of the state. In A. Heertje (Ed.), The economic role of the state. Oxford: Blackwell.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stiglitz, J. (1999). Knowledge as a global public good. In I. Kaul, I. Grunberg, & M. A. Stern (Eds.), Global public goods (pp. 308–325). New York: Oxford University Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Sztompka, P. (2007). Trust in Science: Robert K. Merton's inspirations. Journal of Classical Sociology, 7(2), 211–220.

    Google Scholar 

  • Thomas, N. (1991). Entangled objects: Exchange, material culture, and colonialism in the pacific. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Titmuss, R. M. (1971). The gift relationship. From human blood to social policy. New York: Pantheon Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tuchman, G. (2009). Wannabe U: Inside the corporate university. Chicago: Chicago University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Vermeir, K., & Margocsy, D. (2012). States of secrecy. British Journal for the History of Science, 45(2), 153–164.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weisbrod, B. A. (1988). The nonprofit economy. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wible, J. R. (1998). The economics of science: Methodology and epistemology as if economics really mattered. London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Willetts, D. (2012). Public access to publicly-funded research. 2 May 2012, Publishers Association annual general meeting, London. http://www.bis.gov.uk/news/speeches/david-willetts-public-access-to-research.

  • Willmott, H. (1995). Managing the academics: Commodification and control in the development of university education in the UK. Human Relations, 48(9), 993–1028.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

I would like to thank Michael Matthews, the general journal editor, Gurol Irzik, the editor of this special issue, and the three anonymous referees for their incisive comments which greatly improved this article. Acknowledgments are also due to the CNRS for the financial and institutional support of this research.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Koen Vermeir.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Vermeir, K. Scientific Research: Commodities or Commons?. Sci & Educ 22, 2485–2510 (2013). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11191-012-9524-y

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11191-012-9524-y

Keywords

Navigation