Skip to main content
Log in

Bourdieu and organizational analysis

  • Published:
Theory and Society Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Despite some promising steps in the right direction, organizational analysis has yet to exploit fully the theoretical and empirical possibilities inherent in the writings of Pierre Bourdieu. While certain concepts associated with his thought, such as field and capital, are already widely known in the organizational literature, the specific ways in which these terms are being used provide ample evidence that the full significance of his relational mode of thought has yet to be sufficiently apprehended. Moreover, the almost complete inattention to habitus, the third of Bourdieu’s major concepts, without which the concepts of field and capital (at least as he deployed them) make no sense, further attests to the misappropriation of his ideas and to the lack of appreciation of their potential usefulness. It is our aim in this paper, by contrast, to set forth a more informed and comprehensive account of what a relational – and, in particular, a Bourdieu-inspired – agenda for organizational research might look like. Accordingly, we examine the implications of his theoretical framework for interorganizational relations, as well as for organizations themselves analyzed as fields. The primary advantage of such an approach, we argue, is the central place accorded therein to the social conditions under which inter- and intraorganizational power relations are produced, reproduced, and contested.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. For example, not one of the 38 articles in the encyclopedic Blackwell Companion to Organizations (Baum 2002) mentions Bourdieu. Among the rare attempts to draw on Bourdieu’s framework for the purposes of organizational analysis are Kurunmaki (1999) and Oakes et al. (1998).

  2. It was DiMaggio, instrumental in interpreting Bourdieu’s work for American sociologists before the translation of Distinction in 1984, who was the first to use the concept of organizational field. In an early article (1983: 149), he proposed that the organizational field be thought of “in the dual sense in which Bourdieu uses ‘champ,’ to signify both common purpose and an arena of strategy and conflict.” Though the concept is now widely used in organization theory, few scholars besides DiMaggio have acknowledged the original connection between Bourdieu’s field concept and that of the organizational field, and almost none has used the concept as part of the theoretical triad to which it belongs.

  3. Among the rare instances in which the habitus concept has been employed in organizational analysis are Corsun and Costen (2001), Ciborra (1996), Mutch (2003), and Hallett (2003).

  4. By the “neo-institutionalist” tradition, we mean the approach to organizational analysis first articulated in the 1970s and 1980s by scholars such as DiMaggio and Powell (1991a [1983]), Meyer and his collaborators (e.g., Meyer and Rowan 1991 [1977]; and Meyer and Scott 1983), and Zucker (e.g., 1977, 1983), who were themselves building on the earlier institutionalism of Dalton (1959), Gouldner (1954), and Selznick (1949, 1957). We also mean more recent work by the above (e.g., DiMaggio 1991; Meyer 1994; Meyer et al. 1994; Powell 1991; Scott 1991; 1994a) as well as by scholars who subsequently expanded upon the initial neo-institutionalist formulations (e.g., Dobbin 1994a, 1995; Fligstein 1990, 2001; Guillén 1994, 2001; Hoffman and Ventresca 1999; Mezias 1990, 1995). By the “resource dependence” tradition, we mean the approach to organizational analysis originally articulated by Pfeffer and Salancik (2003 [1978]) and subsequently expanded by organization theorists such as Burt (1982), Mizruchi and Stearns (1988), and Gulati and Gargiulo (1999).

  5. The approach we are advocating points beyond the limitations of “middle-range” theories, for a key feature of relational thinking is its refusal to remain content with formulation of small or partial “laws of the middle range,” the mode of theorizing so dear to Merton: scientific propositions have significance “only within the theoretical system they constitute, not in isolation. Science admits only systems of laws” (Bourdieu and Wacquant 1992: 96).

  6. For discussions of the concept of relationality, see Emirbayer (1997) and Somers (1995).

  7. Bourdieu calls the limit case of fields in which struggles over power have largely been extinguished apparatuses; he suggests that Luhmann’s systems theory pertains more to the latter than it does to fields proper. He adds, however, that the limit of apparatus “is never actually reached” (Bourdieu and Wacquant 1992: 102). Moreover, the degree to which a given configuration of relations has field-like—as opposed to apparatus-like—properties is strictly a matter for empirical investigation. Historical sociologists of organizations can sometimes even discern a historical transition from the one state to the other, as in the cases of French painting during the mid-nineteenth century, when the apparatus-like ascendancy of the French Academy was broken by the symbolic revolution of Manet (Bourdieu 1993b), or of American sociology during the mid-twentieth century, when the “Capitoline” ruling triad of Parsons, Merton, and Lazarsfeld was supplanted by the warring theoretical and methodological tendencies of the 1970s and thereafter (Bourdieu 1991).

  8. In the importance to Bourdieu’s field concept of struggles for dominance, one can see similarities to a number of past organization-theoretic approaches that likewise emphasized competition and struggle. Examples include Zald’s (1970) concept of “political economies” (see also Wamsley and Zald 1973 and Benson 1975); Levine and White’s (1961) concept of “interorganizational exchange”; Yuchtman and Seashore’s (1967) “system resource” approach; Warren’s (1967) concept of “interorganizational field”; and Pfeffer and Salancik’s (2003 [1978]) “resource dependence” approach. The rise of the neo-institutionalist paradigm, however, tended to draw attention away from conflict both within and between organizations, as neo-institutionalists themselves (e.g., Brint and Karabel 1991) came to recognize. We believe that the renewed attention to struggle and conflict stimulated by a Bourdieu-inspired approach goes far toward answering recent calls (e.g., Morrill et al. 2003) for a renewal of the attention to conflict so central to those earlier organization studies.

  9. Social network analysis, at least since its early elaboration by the Manchester school of social anthropology (e.g., Barnes 1954; Mitchell 1956), has recognized with great clarity this issue regarding the demarcation of boundaries. However, it has not always taken sufficient account of the accompanying issue of contestation and struggle. In Bourdieu, these two issues always and necessarily go hand in hand. We shall have more to say shortly about the social networks tradition.

  10. For an overview of the state of, and relations among, the academic disciplines engaged in the study of opera organizations, see Johnson (2007a). While it is difficult to imagine sophisticated practitioners of organizational analysis making such an error, disciplinary specialization means that scholars studying organization-based phenomena in many fields, not just musicology, are, in fact, often susceptible to such naivete.

  11. Organizational fields sometimes, of course, include individual actors who act in the absence of organizational affiliations. Just as the presence of such actors has correctly been acknowledged in past research that relies on the concept of organizational field, the field-theoretic approach here under consideration requires that we not presume that the fields in which organizations are active are composed entirely of organizations. It does, however, require that we approach individual actors in a fundamentally relational manner, ascertaining in each case their positions in and trajectories through the fields in which they are active. We have in The Rules of Art, in fact, a book-length template for studying the impact of a single actor (the novelist Gustave Flaubert) on a field composed in part of organizations (the literary field in nineteenth-century France). It should be noted, however, that it is increasingly difficult to distinguish the impact of individuals in these fields from the impact of the organizations they head. How, for example, are we to distinguish the influence of Donald Trump’s person from that of his companies when examining the organizational fields in which Trump himself is active? How, similarly, can we explain the appearance of a nineteenth-century Russian novel (Anna Karenina) at the very top of the U.S. best-seller list in 2004, just 1 week after Oprah—an individual social actor, but also the head of an entertainment company whose name is, tellingly, her own first name spelled backwards—announced it was “her” new book selection?

  12. While this approach to locating the boundaries of the field superficially resembles network-analytic methods insofar as the latter proceed by means of an empirical mapping of relations between organizations rather than a nominalist imposition of boundaries around a population of organizations (see, e.g., Lincoln and Gerlach 2004), the emphasis of network analysis on concrete ties clearly distinguishes it from Bourdieu’s focus on relations among organizations that may have no concrete ties to one another but that are, nevertheless, participants in the relations of force and contestation structuring the field as a whole.

  13. Under pressure to bound populations for the purpose of empirical research, organizational scholars frequently sidestep the lengthy inquiry that would in fact be required to reconstruct thoroughly the (shifting) power relations that allow certain players in the field to impose their own conception of the field on other participants. Among neo-institutionalist theorists who have acknowledged the delicacy of demarcating boundaries are DiMaggio (1983, 1986) and Fligstein (1990).

  14. One notable exception is Baker et al.’s (1998) theoretical and empirical synthesis of dimensions of organizations often studied independently—namely, competition, power, and institutions.

  15. Brass et al. (2004) provide a useful overview of the current state of network-analytic research on organizations.

  16. Bourdieu has by no means been alone in levying such criticisms. Others have similarly argued, but from a resource dependence perspective, that network analysis has focused too often on observed interactions, while failing to analyze “the context of institutions, including rules and roles,” in which interaction takes place (Salancik 1995: 2).

  17. The final part of this sentence is a paraphrase of one of Bourdieu’s own favorite formulations. Bourdieu’s statements of this formulation, it should be pointed out, never include the words “at least partly.” His way of stating the matter, in contrast to our own, arguably exposes Bourdieu to the charge that, in the end, he replaces the interactionist fallacy with an equally problematic structuralist fallacy. Does he not fall short of his own dialectical standards by insisting so one-sidedly on the priority of structure over interaction? This is one respect in which Bourdieu’s theoretical framework quite possibly requires careful reconstruction.

  18. A substantive illustration of this point—and of much of the rest of what is discussed in this section—can be found in Emirbayer and Williams (2005).

  19. Here again one can see how Bourdieu’s field concept could reinvigorate useful work initiated by earlier theorists of organizations, in this case, work regarding interorganizational struggles over the power to determine the structure, membership, and boundaries of organizational “environments” or “domains.” Most prominently, these earlier theorists included Blau (1955, 1964; see also Blau and Scott 1962), Thompson (1967), Aldrich (1971, 1979), and Pfeffer and Salancik (2003) [1978]. More recently, Fligstein (1996) has elaborated a model closely analogous to Bourdieu’s, one that focuses on the tensions between “incumbents” and “invaders.”

  20. The phrases “goodwill investment” and “brand loyalty” appear in English in the original.

  21. Contributions that might prove particularly useful in exploring the concept of symbolic capital on the organizational level have come from scholars working on the related but distinct topics of reputation, status, prestige, legitimacy, and branding. Key studies on reputation, which has to do with outside assessments of an organization’s past performance, include Shrum and Wuthnow (1988), Zajac and Westphal (1996), Staw and Epstein (2000), and Whetten and Mackey (2002); on status, which refers to an organization’s position in a network or other social structure, see, e.g., Podolny (1993), Stuart et al. (1999), and Jensen (2003); on the closely related concept of prestige, see Perrow (1961), Thompson (1967), Pfeffer (1981), and D’Aveni (1990); on legitimacy, which refers to the normative approval or cognitive acceptance of an organization’s purpose and practices, see Meyer and Rowan (1991 [1977]), DiMaggio and Powell (1991a [1983]), Ruef and Scott (1998), Glynn and Abzug (1998), and Lounsbury and Glynn (2001); finally, on branding, a process through which organizations consciously attempt to enhance their reputation, status, prestige, or legitimacy, see especially Aaker (1991, 1992).

  22. While we cannot specify an instance in which Bourdieu deploys the concept of a “field of power” at the meso-level of organizational fields (although he does come close in his analysis of the organization of the field of institutions of higher education in France according to the division between the grande porte and the petite porte [Bourdieu 1996a (1989): 142–52]), we feel justified in extending this idea to the meso-level because of (a) the general logic of Bourdieu’s theory of fields; and (b) his own use of this very concept in speaking of even more circumscribed fields, namely, what we shall go on to term organizations-as-fields: “We can speak of the logic of the struggle within the field of power in the firm, that is to say, the competition between those holding one of the relevant powers. Everything [takes] place as if the structure of the field of power was organized at every moment in terms of different oppositions which, particularly in moments of crisis, could crystallize into strategic alliances among the holders of the various different forms of power” (2005 [2000]: 218). However, despite this usage on the part of Bourdieu himself, we carefully refrain in what follows from speaking of an organizational “field of power” because we do not wish to confuse it with the macro-level arena of struggle to which he more commonly applies the term. We speak instead of a “space of struggle for organizational power,” or at most of an organization’s “internal field of power,” thereby sacrificing elegance of style and economy of language for what we believe is a gain in conceptual clarity.

  23. One potentially important way in which Bourdieu’s framework could be further elaborated and reconstructed is by adding to these analytic domains of social relations and culture a third homologous domain of collective emotions, also understood in semiotic terms as a space of relations of opposition and difference. There is much in Bourdieu that already makes such a step both feasible and desirable, in particular his keen attentiveness to the affectual dimensions of life, which, as he makes clear, are a terrain for socioanalysis every bit as much as for psychoanalysis (see Emirbayer and Goldberg 2005). Theoretical and empirical work has already begun along these lines, often but not always aligned with work on gender in organizations (Fineman 1993; see also Albrow 1997). In what follows, we restrict our attention to social relations and culture, to positions and position-takings, leaving for future work the pursuit of this additional and, we feel, highly intriguing possibility.

  24. For example, he asserts that “in a situation of equilibrium, the space of positions tends to command the space of position-takings” (Bourdieu and Wacquant 1992: 105; italics in original).

  25. Besides organizational ecology, there were two other strands emerging around this time that evidenced a greater sensitivity to historical questions than most organizational research. Work on labor relations by scholars such as Marglin (1974), Goldman and Van Houten (1976), Jacoby (1978), Edwards (1979), and Burawoy (1979) was firmly grounded in a neo-Marxist concern with the long sweep of capitalism. And studies of authority and managerial control—inspired by Bendix’s (1956) classic comparative-historical study of industrialization and labor, as well as by Chandler’s (1962, 1977) profoundly influential work on the rise of managerial capitalism in the United States—examined historical transformations in organizational control structures. (Among the latter were Rumelt 1974, Williamson 1975, and Barley and Kunda 1992.) Such historically informed research, however, was overshadowed by the contemporary focus of most organizational analysis.

  26. In addition to the classic studies (e.g., Zucker 1991 [1977], 1983 DiMaggio and Powell 1991a [1983], and Meyer and Rowan (1991 [1977]), more recent work on managerial fads (e.g., Abrahamson and Fairchild 1999, Abrahamson 1991, and Barley and Kunda 1992) has underscored this point forcefully. Likewise, debates in the field of corporate governance over precisely what goals organizations actually pursue, and how they do so, have enriched our understanding of the non-rational dimensions of organizational behavior; for an overview of this debate, see Mizruchi (2004).

  27. Here we are advocating an approach quite similar to that taken by Stark and Bruszt in their study of post-Communist East Central Europe, a region that, they argue, “must be regarded as undergoing a plurality of transitions in a dual sense: Across the region, we are seeing a multiplicity of distinctive strategies; within any given country, we find not one transition but many occurring in different domains—political, economic, and social—and the temporality of these processes is often asynchronous and their articulation seldom harmonious” (Stark and Bruszt 1998: 81).

  28. See, for example, Meyer and Rowan (1991 [1977]), Jepperson and Meyer (1991), Meyer et al. (1994), and Meyer (1994).

  29. One might also bear in mind here that changes in organizational fields exert as well, for their own part, significant pressures on spaces of societal actors, dispositions, and position-takings.

  30. A Bourdieu-inspired program of inquiry can learn much in this respect from the growing wave of research on race, class, and gender within the social sciences in general and, admittedly still to a more limited extent, within organizational studies in particular. The neo-Marxist tradition in organizational studies (e.g., Burawoy 1979) always highlighted class relations within organizational life. More recently, authors such as Acker (1990) and Martin (2003)—inspired by the seminal work of Kanter (1977)—have devoted increasing analytic attention to gender-based relations. Still somewhat weak in organizational analysis, by comparison, has been the investigation of race and the study of intersections among class, gender, and race.

  31. As Baker and Faulkner (2004) point out, for example, social network analysts disagree among themselves about the conditions under which network ties give rise to the positive effects associated with the concept of social capital and those under which such ties are actually the source of harm or exploitation. The approach we are advocating suggests that such issues can never be completely resolved until researchers conceive of networks and capital as deriving their value and producing their effects through the structure and dynamics of the field(s) in which they are embedded. On the other hand, of course, one must be careful not to move so far in this structuralist direction that one also loses sight of the (dialectically equally significant) moment of interaction.

  32. A substantive illustration of this point—as indeed of much of the rest of what is discussed in this section—can once again be found in Emirbayer and Williams (2005).

  33. Among the most influential early work on network forms of organization were Piore and Sabel (1984), Sabel (1989), Powell (1990), Gerlach (1992), Lincoln and Gerlach (1992), and Lincoln et al. (1992).

  34. Relevant in this context as well are the Manchester school’s early applications of social network analysis to the challenge of demarcating boundaries (see footnote 9). Whether the concrete object to be investigated is tribal societies or (post-) modern organizations-as-fields, the theoretical challenges involved remain much the same.

  35. It is important to note here that just as a network-based approach to the relationships of individual actors by no means goes hand in hand with the more deeply relational way of thinking that we lay out early in this article, neither does a network approach to interorganizational relations entail such a perspective. The analysis of inter-firm networks is, of course, in the most superficial sense the analysis of a set of relations. However, in the absence of a framework (e.g., the concept of the organization-as-field) for understanding the creation and reproduction of the worth or value of organizational posts or organizational resources, network analysis will tend to divorce the structure of intraorganizational groups and units from the larger societal contexts—organizational and other kinds of fields—through which this structure is produced in the first place.

  36. For articulations of the concept of social capital, see Coleman (1988, 1994), Portes (1998) Burt (2000), and Adler and Kwon (2002). For recent uses of cultural capital, see, e.g., Holt (1998), Throsby (1999), and Lareau and Weininger (2004).

  37. For a useful general discussion of the relevance of Durkheim for the study of organizations-as-fields, see Lincoln and Guillot (2004).

  38. The idea of a space of position-takings opens exciting possibilities for a creative dialogue between Bourdieu-inspired organizational analysts and the considerable number of researchers who have already been contributing to the study of organizational cultures and subcultures. (We mentioned in an earlier note that configurations of collective emotions can be subsumed as well under this idea of a space of position-takings: see Emirbayer and Goldberg 2005.) For comprehensive surveys of the literature on organizational culture, see Smircich (1983), Martin (1992, 2001), Barley and Kunda (1992), and Dobbin (1994b); for perhaps the best-known empirical study of organizational culture, see Kunda (1992).

  39. For recent analyses of how such position-takings are shaped by ethnic and national attitudes to work and professionalism, see the studies by the social psychologist Sanchez-Burks (e.g., 2002, 2004).

  40. One direction in which such inquiry might certainly lead is toward an analysis of gendered dispositions and actions within everyday organizational life; for earlier such studies, see not only the aforementioned work by Kanter, but also Acker (1990) and Martin (2003).

  41. Despite important differences in their theoretical frameworks, Bourdieu’s emphasis on the link between actors’ external trajectories and their position-takings within an organization is anticipated by Crozier’s (1967) analysis of the relation between employees’ extra-organizational “social status” and their attitudes toward their work in a French clerical agency. Likewise, Bourdieu’s approach to the analysis of conflict at the heart of the cement company calls to mind Crozier’s (1967) inquiry into the power struggles among the managers of an organization he labels, for purposes of anonymity, “the Industrial Monopoly.”

  42. “In the particular (and particularly frequent) case in which the habitus is the product of objective conditions similar to those under which it operates, it generates behaviors that are particularly well suited to these conditions without being the product of a conscious, intentional search for adaptation” (Bourdieu 2005 [2000]:213–214).

  43. Needless to say, these methods are not necessarily mutually exclusive. What Bourdieu derides is the tendency of many researchers to act as if they were: “Thus we will find monomaniacs of log-linear modeling, of discourse analysis, of participant observation, of open-ended or in-depth interviewing, or of ethnographic description. Rigid adherence to this or that one method of data collection [and analysis] will define membership in a ‘school’” (Bourdieu and Wacquant 1992: 226).

  44. In The State Nobility (1996 [1989]: 197–214), Bourdieu does provide two illustrations of how “structural histories” of specific organizations can be produced while still remaining within a broader field-theoretic framework, thereby transcending the usual dichotomy between particularizing and generalizing strategies: see his extended discussions of the École des Hautes Études Commerciales and of the École Nationale d’Administration.

References

  • Aaker, D. A. (1991). Managing brand equity. New York: Free Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Aaker, D. A. (1992). The value of brand equity. Journal of Business Strategy, 13, 27–33.

    Google Scholar 

  • Abbott, A. (1998). The system of professions. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Abrahamson, E. (1991). Managerial fads and fashions: The diffusion and rejection of innovations. Academy of Management Review, 16(3), 586–612.

    Google Scholar 

  • Abrahamson, E., & Fairchild, G. (1999). Management fashion: Lifecycles, triggers, and collective learning processes. Administrative Science Quarterly, 44(4), 708–740.

    Google Scholar 

  • Acker, J. (1990). Hierarchies, jobs, bodies. Gender and Society, 4, 139–158.

    Google Scholar 

  • Adler, P. S., & Kwon, S.-W. (2002). Social capital. Academy of Management Review, 27(1), 17–40.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Albrow, M. (1997). Do organizations have feelings? London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Aldrich, H. (1971). Organizational Boundaries and Inter-organizational Conflict. Human Relations, 24, 279–287.

    Google Scholar 

  • Aldrich, H. (1979). Organization and environments. Englewood Cliffs: Prentice-Hall.

    Google Scholar 

  • Alexander, J. C., & Smith, P. (1993). The discourse of American civil society. Theory and Society, 22, 151–207.

    Google Scholar 

  • Baker, W. E., & Faulkner, R. R. (1991). Role as resource in the Hollywood film industry. American Journal of Sociology, 97(2), 279–309.

    Google Scholar 

  • Baker, W. E., & Faulkner, R. R. (2002). Interorganizational networks. In J. A. C. Baum (Ed.) The Blackwell companion to organizations. (pp. 520–540). London: Blackwell.

    Google Scholar 

  • Baker, W. E., & Faulkner, R. R. (2004). Social networks and loss of capital. Social Networks, 26(2), 91–111.

    Google Scholar 

  • Baker, W. E., Faulkner, R. R., & Fisher, G. A. (1998). Hazards of the market. American Sociological Review, 63(2), 147–177.

    Google Scholar 

  • Barley, S. R., & Kunda, G. (1992). Design and devotion: Surges of rational and normative ideologies of control in managerial discourse. Administrative Science Quarterly, 37, 363–399.

    Google Scholar 

  • Barnes, J. A. (1954). Class and committees in a Norwegian island parish. Human Relations, 7, 39–58.

    Google Scholar 

  • Baum, J. A.C. (Ed.) (2002). The Blackwell Companion to Organizations. London: Blackwell.

  • Becker, H. S. (1982). Art worlds. Berkeley: University of California Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bendix, R. (1956). Work and authority in industry. New Brunswick: Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Benson, J. K. (1975). The interorganizational network as a political economy. Administrative Science Quarterly, 20(2), 229–249.

    Google Scholar 

  • Blau, P. (1955). The dynamics of bureaucracy. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Blau, P. (1964). Exchange and power in social life. New York: Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Blau, P., & Scott, W. R. (1962). Formal organizations. San Francisco: Chandler.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bourdieu, P. (1977). Outline of a theory of practice. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bourdieu, P. (1981). Men and machines. In K. Knorr-Cetina, & A. V. Cicourel (Eds.) Advances in social theory and methodology (pp. 304–317). Boston: Routledge and Kegan Paul.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bourdieu, P. (1984) [1979]. Distinction. Translated by Richard Nice. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

  • Bourdieu, P. (1988) [1984]. Homo academicus. Translated by Peter Collier. Stanford: Stanford University Press.

  • Bourdieu, P. (1990) [1987]. Programme for a Sociology of Sport. In M. Adamson (Ed.), In other words (pp. 156–167). Stanford: Stanford University Press.

  • Bourdieu, P. (1991). On the possibility of a field of world sociology. Translated by Loïc J.D. Wacquant. In P. Bourdieu, & J. S. Coleman (Eds.) Social theory for a changing society (pp. 373–387). Boulder, CO: Westview.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bourdieu, P. (1993a). Some properties of fields. In Sociology in Question, translated by Richard Nice (pp. 72–77). London: Sage.

  • Bourdieu, P. (1993b). Manet and the institutionalization of anomie. In R. Johnson (Ed.) The field of cultural production (pp. 238–253). London: Columbia University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bourdieu, P. (1993c). Haute couture and haute culture. In Sociology in Question, translated by Richard Nice (pp. 132–138). London: Sage.

  • Bourdieu, P. (1996a) [1989]. The state nobility. Translated by Lauretta C. Clough. Stanford: Stanford University Press.

  • Bourdieu, P. (1996b). Intellectuals and the internationalization of ideas: An interview with M’Hammed Sabour. International Journal of Contemporary Sociology, 33, 237–254.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bourdieu, P. (1996c) [1992]. The rules of art. Translated by Susan Emanuel. Stanford: Stanford University Press.

  • Bourdieu, P. (1998a) [1994]. Rethinking the state. Translated by Loïc J.D. Wacquant and Samar Farage, pp. 35–63 in Practical Reason. Stanford: Stanford University Press.

  • Bourdieu, P. (2005). [2000]. The social structures of the economy. Translated by Chris Turner. Cambridge: Polity Press.

  • Bourdieu, P. (2001) [1998]. Masculine domination. Translated by Richard Nice. Stanford: Stanford University Press.

  • Bourdieu, P. (2004). Esquisse pour une auto-analyse. Paris: Raisons d’agir.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bourdieu, P., & de Saint Martin, M. (1982). La sainte famille. Actes de la recherche en sciences socials, 44/45, 2–53.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bourdieu, P., & Wacquant, L. J. D. (1992). An invitation to reflexive sociology. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bourdieu, P., et al. (1999) [1993]. The weight of the world. Translated by Priscilla Parkhurst Ferguson, et al. Stanford: Stanford University Press.

  • Brass, D. J., Galaskiewicz, J., Greve, H. R., & Tsai, W. (2004). Taking stock of networks and organizations. Academy of Management Journal, 47(6), 795–819.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Breiger, R. L. (1974). The duality of persons and groups. Social Forces, 53, 181–190.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brint, S., & Karabel, J. (1991). Institutional origins and transformations: The case of American community colleges. In W. W. Powell, & P. J. DiMaggio (Eds.) The new institutionalism in organizational analysis (pp. 337–360). Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Burawoy, M. (1979). Manufacturing consent. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Burt, R. S. (1982). Toward a structural theory of action. New York: Academic.

    Google Scholar 

  • Burt, R. S. (1992). Structural holes. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Burt, R. S. (2000). The network structure of social capital. Research in Organizational Behavior 22: 345–433, edited by Robert I. Sutton and Barry M. Staw. Greenwich, CT: JAI Press.

  • Carroll, G. R., & Hannan, M. T. (2000). The demography of corporations and industries. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chandler, A. D. (1962). Strategy and structure: Chapters in the history of the industrial enterprise. Cambridge: MIT.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chandler, A. D. (1977). The visible hand: The managerial revolution in American business. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ciborra, C. U. (1996). The platform organization. Organization Science, 7(2), 103–118.

    Google Scholar 

  • Coleman, J. S. (1988). Social capital in the creation of human capital. American Journal of Sociology, 94(Suppl. S), S95–S120.

    Google Scholar 

  • Coleman, J. S. (1994). Foundations of social theory. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Corsun, D. L., & Costen, W. M. (2001). Is the glass ceiling unbreakable? Journal of Management Inquiry, 10(1), 16–25.

    Google Scholar 

  • Crozier, M. (1967). The bureaucratic phenomenon. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Crozier, M. (1971). The world of the office worker. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dalton, M. (1959). Men who manage. New York: Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • D’Aveni, R. A. (1990). Top managerial prestige and organizational bankruptcy. Organization Science, 1(2), 121–142.

    Google Scholar 

  • Davis, G. F. (2005). Firms and environments. In N. Smelser, & R. Swedberg (Eds.) Handbook of economic sociology ((pp. 478–502)2nd ed.). Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dewey, J. (1988a) [1927]. The public and its problems. In J. A. Boydston (Ed.), The later works of John Dewey, 1925–1953, Volume 2 (pp. 235–372). Carbondale and Edwardsville: Southern Illinois University Press.

  • Dewey, J. (1988b) [1922]. Human nature and conduct. The middle works of John Dewey, 1899–1924, Volume 14. In J. A. Boydston (Ed.), Carbondale and Edwardsville: Southern Illinois University Press.

  • DiMaggio, P. J. (1983). State expansion and organizational fields. In R. H. Hall, & R. Quinn (Eds.) Organizational theory and public policy (pp. 147–161). Beverly Hills: Sage.

    Google Scholar 

  • DiMaggio, P. J. (1986). Structural analysis of organizational fields. Research in Organizational Behavior, 8, 335–370.

    Google Scholar 

  • DiMaggio, P. J. (1991). Constructing an organizational field as a professional project: U.S. art museums, 1920–1940. In W. W. Powell, & P. J. DiMaggio (Eds.) The new institutionalism in organizational analysis (pp. 267–292). Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • DiMaggio, P. J., & Powell, W. W. (1991a [1983]). The iron cage revisited. In W. W. Powell, & P. J. DiMaggio (Eds.) The new institutionalism in organizational analysis (pp. 63–82). Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • DiMaggio, P. J., & Powell, W. W. (1991b). Introduction. In W. W. Powell, & P. J. DiMaggio (Eds.) The new institutionalism in organizational analysis (pp. 1–38). Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dobbin, F. R. (1994a). Cultural models of organization. In D. Crane (Ed.) The sociology of culture (pp. 117–142). Oxford: Blackwell.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dobbin, F. R. (1994b). Forging industrial policy. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dobbin, F. R. (1995). The origins of economic principles: Railway entrepreneurs and public policy in 19th-century America. In W. R. Scott, & S. Christensen (Eds.), The institutional construction of organizations (pp. 277–301).

  • Dobbin, F. R. (2001). Why the economy reflects the polity. In M. Granovetter, & R. Swedberg (Eds.) The Sociology of Economic Life ((pp. 401–424)2nd ed.). Boulder, CO: Westview.

    Google Scholar 

  • Durkheim, E. (1977) [1904–1905]. The evolution of educational thought. Translated by Peter Collins. London: Routledge and Kegan Paul.

  • Edwards, R. C. (1979). Contested terrain: The transformation of the workplace in the twentieth century. New York: Basic.

    Google Scholar 

  • Emirbayer, M. (1992). Beyond structuralism and voluntarism. Theory and Society, 21(5), 621–664.

    Google Scholar 

  • Emirbayer, M. (1997). Manifesto for a relational sociology. American Journal of Sociology, 103(2), 281–317.

    Google Scholar 

  • Emirbayer, M., & Williams, E. M. (2005). Bourdieu and social work. Social Service Review, 79(4), 689–724.

    Google Scholar 

  • Emirbayer, M., & Goldberg, C. (2005). Pragmatism, Bourdieu, and collective emotions in contentious politics. Theory and Society, 34, 469–518.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fineman, S. (ed.) (1993). Emotion in organizations. London: Sage.

  • Fligstein, N. (1985). The spread of the multidivisional form among large firms, 1919–1979. American Sociological Review, 50, 377–391.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fligstein, N. (1990). The transformation of corporate control. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fligstein, N. (1996). Markets as politics. American Sociological Review, 61(4), 656–673.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fligstein, N. (2001). The architecture of markets. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Galaskiewicz, J., & Wasserman, S. (1989). Mimetic processes within an interorganizational field. Administrative Science Quarterly, 34(3), 454–479.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gerlach, M. (1992). Alliance capitalism: The social organization of Japanese business. Berkeley: University of California Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Glynn, M. A., & Abzug, R. (1998). Isomorphism and competitive differentiation in the organizational name game. Advances in Strategic Management, 15, 105–128.

    Google Scholar 

  • Goffman, E. (1961). Asylums. Garden City, NY: Anchor Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Goldman, P., & Van Houten, D. R. (1976). Managerial strategies and the worker: A Marxist analysis of bureaucracy. Sociological Quarterly, 18(1), 108–125.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gouldner, A. (1954). Patterns of industrial bureaucracy. Glencoe, IL: Free Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Granovetter, M. (1985). Economic action and social structure. American Journal of Sociology, 91, 481–510.

    Google Scholar 

  • Granovetter, M. (1992). Economic institutions as social constructions. Acta Sociologica, 35, 3–11.

    Google Scholar 

  • Guillén, M. F. (1994). Models of management. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Guillén, M. F. (2001). The limits of convergence. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gulati, R. & Gargiulo, M. (1999). Where do Interorganizational Networks Come From? American Journal of Sociology, 104(5), 1439–1493.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hallett, T. (2003). Symbolic Power and Organizational Culture. Sociology Theory, 21(2), 128–149.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hannan, M. T. (1997). Inertia, density, and the structure of organizational populations. Organization Studies, 18, 193–228.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hannan, M. T., & Freeman, J. (1984). Structural inertia and organizational change. American Sociological Review, 49, 149–164.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hoffman, A. J., & Ventresca, M. J. (1999). The institutional framing of policy debates: Economics versus the environment. American Behavioral Scientist, 42(8), 1368–1392.

    Google Scholar 

  • Holt, D. B. (1998). Does cultural capital structure American consumption? The Journal of Consumer Research, 25(1), 1–25.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jacoby, R. (1978). Political economy and class unconsciousness. Theory and Society, 5(1), 11–18.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jensen, M. (2003). The role of network resources in market entry. Administrative Science Quarterly, 48(3), 466–497.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jepperson, R. L., & Meyer, J. W. (1991). The public order and the construction of formal organizations. In W. W. Powell, & P. J. DiMaggio (Eds.) The new institutionalism in organizational analysis (pp. 204–31). Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Johnson, V. (2007a). Introduction: Opera and the Academic Turns. In V. Johnson, J. F. Fulcher, & T. Ertman (Eds.) Opera and Society in Italy and France from Monteverdi to Bourdieu (pp. 1–28). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Johnson, V. (2007b). What is organizational imprinting? Cultural entrepreneurship in the founding of the Paris Opera. American Journal of Sociology, 113(1), 97–127.

    Google Scholar 

  • Johnson, V. (2006). Introduction: Opera and the Academic ‘Turns.’ In Opera and Society from Monteverdi to Bourdieu, edited by Victoria Johnson, Jane Fulcher, and Thomas Ertman. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press (in press).

  • Kanter, R. M. (1977). Men and women of the corporation. New York: Basic.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kunda, G. (1992). Engineering culture. Philadelphia: Temple University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kurunmaki, L. (1999). Professional vs. financial capital in the field of health care. Accounting, Organizations and Society, 24(2), 95–124.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lareau, A., & Weininger, E. B. (2004). Cultural capital in educational research. In D. L. Swartz, & V. L. Zolberg (Eds.) After Bourdieu (pp. 105–144). Dordrecht: Kluwer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Laumann, E. O., & Knoke, D. (1987). The organizational state. Madison: University of Wisconsin Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Levine, S., & White, P. E. (1961). Exchange as a conceptual framework for the study of interorganizational relationships. Administrative Science Quarterly, 5(4), 583–601.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lincoln, J. R., & Gerlach, M. L. (1992). The organization of business networks in the US and Japan. In Networks and Organizations (pp. 491–520). Boston: Harvard Business School Press.

  • Lincoln, J. R., Gerlach, M. L., & Takahashi, P. (1992). Keiretsu networks in the Japanese Economy: A dyad analysis of intercorporate ties. American Sociological Review, 57, 561–585.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lincoln, J. R., & Guillot, D. (2004). Durkheim and organizational culture (unpublished manuscript).

  • Lounsbury, M., & Glynn, M. A. (2001). Cultural entrepreneurship. Strategic Management Journal, 22(6–7), 545–564.

    Google Scholar 

  • Marglin, S. A. (1974). What do bosses do? The origins and functions of hierarchy in capitalist production. Review of Radical Political Economics, 6(2), 33–60.

    Google Scholar 

  • Martin, J. (1992). Cultures in organizations. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Martin, J. (2001). Organizational culture: Mapping the terrain. London: Sage.

    Google Scholar 

  • Martin, P. Y. (2003). ‘Said and Done’ Versus ‘Saying and Doing’. Gender and Society, 17, 342–366.

    Google Scholar 

  • Meyer, J. W. (1994). Rationalized environments. In W. R. Scott, J. W. Meyer, & Associates (Eds.) Institutional environments and organizations (pp. 28–54). London: Sage.

    Google Scholar 

  • Meyer, J. W., Boli, J., & Thomas, G. M. (1994). Ontology and rationalization in the Western cultural account. In W. R. Scott, J. W. Meyer, & Associates (Eds.) Institutional Environments and Organizations (pp. 9–27). London: Sage.

    Google Scholar 

  • Meyer, J. W., & Rowan, B. (1991) [1977]. Institutionalized organizations. In W. W. Powell, & P. J. DiMaggio (Eds.), The new institutionalism in organizational analysis (pp. 41–62). Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

  • Meyer, J. W., & Scott, W. R. (1983). Centralization and the legimitacy problem of local government. In J. W. Meyer, & W. R. Scott (Eds.) Organizational environments: Ritual and rationality (pp. 199–215). Beverly Hills: Sage.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mezias, S. J. (1990). An institutional model of organizational practice: Financial reporting at the fortune 200. Administrative Science Quarterly, 35, 431–457.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mezias, S. J. (1995). Using institutional theory to understand for-profit sectors: The case of financial reporting standards. In W. R. Scott, & S. Christensen (Eds.), The Institutional Construction of Organizations (pp. 164–196)

  • Mitchell, J. C. (1956). The Kalela dance. Manchester: Manchester University Press for Rhodes-Livingstone Institute.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mizruchi, M. S. (1992). The structure of corporate political action. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mizruchi, M. S. (2004). Berle and Means revisited: The governance and power of large U.S. corporations. Theory and Society, 33, 579–617.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mizruchi, M. S. & Stearns, L. B. (1988). A Longitudinal Study of the Formation of Interlocking Directorates. Administrative Science Quarterly, 33(2), 194–210.

    Google Scholar 

  • Morrill, C., Zald, M. N., & Rao, H. (2003). Covert political conflict in organizations. Annual Review of Sociology, 29, 391–415.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mutch, A. (2003). Communities of practice and habitus. Organization Studies, 24, 383–303.

    Google Scholar 

  • Oakes, L. S., Townley, B., & Cooper, D. J. (1998). Business planning as pedagogy. Administrative Science Quarterly, 43(2), 257–292.

    Google Scholar 

  • Perrow, C. (1961). Organizational prestige: Some functions and dysfunctions. American Journal of Sociology, 66(4), 335–341.

    Google Scholar 

  • Perrow, C. (1999) [1984]. Normal accidents. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

  • Pfeffer, J. (1981). Power in organizations. Marshfield, MA: Pitman.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pfeffer, J. (1992). Managing with power. Boston: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pfeffer, J., & Salancik, G. (2003) [1978]. The external control of organizations: A resource dependence approach. Stanford: Stanford University Press.

  • Piore, M. J., & Sabel, C. F. (1984). The second industrial divide: Possibilities for prosperity. New York: Basic.

    Google Scholar 

  • Podolny, J. M. (1993). A status-based model of market competition. American Journal of Sociology, 98(4), 829–872.

    Google Scholar 

  • Portes, A. (1998). Social capital. Annual Review of Sociology, 24, 1–24.

    Google Scholar 

  • Powell, W. W. (1990). Neither market nor hierarchy: Network forms of organization. Research in Organizational Behavior, 12, 295–356.

    Google Scholar 

  • Powell, W. W. (1991). Expanding the Scope of Institutional Analysis. In W. W. Powell & P. J. DiMaggio (Eds.) The New Institutionalism in Organizational Analysis (pp. 183–203). Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ruef, M., & Scott, W. R. (1998). A multidimensional model of organizational legitimacy. Administrative Science Quarterly, 43(4), 877–904.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rumelt, R. P. (1974). Strategy, structure, and performance. Boston: Harvard Business School Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sabel, C. F. (1989). Flexible specialization and the re-emergence of regional economies. In P. Hirst, & J. Zeitlin (Eds.) Reversing Industrial Decline? (pp. 17–70). Oxford: Berg.

    Google Scholar 

  • Salancik, G. (1995). Wanted: A good network theory of organizations. Administrative Science Quarterly, 40, 345–349.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sanchez-Burks, J. (2002). Protestant relational ideology and (in)attention to relational cues in work settings. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 83(4), 919–929.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sanchez-Burks, J. (2004). Protestant relational ideology: The cognitive underpinnings and organizational implications of an American anomaly. Research in Organizational Behavior, 26, 267–308.

    Google Scholar 

  • Scott, W. R. (1991). Unpacking Institutional Arguments. In W. W. Powell, & P. J. DiMaggio (Eds.) The New Institutionalism in Organizational Analysis (pp. 164–182). Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Scott, W. R. (1992). The organization of environments. In J. W. Meyer, & W. R. Scott (Eds.) Organizational Environments (pp. 155–175). London: Sage.

    Google Scholar 

  • Scott, W. R. (1994a). Institutional analysis: Variance and process theory approaches. In W. R. Scott, & J. W. Meyer (Eds.) Institutional environments and organizations (pp. 81–99). London: Sage.

    Google Scholar 

  • Scott, W. R. (1994b). Conceptualizing organizational fields. In H.-U. Derlien, U. Gerhardt, & F. W. Scharpf (Eds.) Systemrationalität und Partialinteresse (pp. 203–221). Baden-Baden: Nomos Verlagsgesellschaft.

    Google Scholar 

  • Scott, W. R. (1996). The mandate is still being honored. Administrative Science Quarterly, 41, 163–171.

    Google Scholar 

  • Scott, W. R. (2003). Organizations: Rational, natural, and open systems (5th ed.). Upper Saddle River, NY: Prentice-Hall.

    Google Scholar 

  • Scott, W. R. (2004). Reflections on a half-century of organizational sociology. Annual Review of Sociology, 30, 1–21.

    Google Scholar 

  • Selznick, P. (1949). TVA and the grass roots. Berkeley: University of California Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Selznick, P. (1957). Leadership in Administration. Evanston, IL: Row and Peterson.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shrum, W., & Wuthnow, R. (1988). Reputational status of organizations in technical systems. American Journal of Sociology, 93(4), 882–912.

    Google Scholar 

  • Simmel, G. (1955). Conflict and the web of group-affiliations. Translated by Kurt H. Wolff and Reinhard Bendix. New York: Free Press.

  • Smircich, L. (1983). Concepts of Culture and Organizational Analysis. Administrative Science Quarterly, 28(3), 339–358.

    Google Scholar 

  • Somers, M. R. (1995). What’s political or cultural about political culture and the public sphere? Sociological Theory, 13, 113–144.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stark, D. (2001). Ambiguous assets for uncertain environments. In P. J. DiMaggio (Ed.) The twenty-first-century firm (pp. 69–104). Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stark, D., & Bruszt, L. (1998). Postsocialist pathways. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Staw, B. M., & Epstein, L. D. (2000). What bandwagons bring: Effects of popular management techniques on corporate performance, reputation, and CEO pay. Administrative Science Quarterly, 45(3), 523–556.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stern, R. N., & Barley, S. R. (1996). Organizations and social systems. Administrative Science Quarterly, 41, 146–162.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stinchcombe, A. L. (1965). Social structure and organizations. In J. G. March (Ed.) Handbook of organizations (pp. 142–193). New York: Rand McNally.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stinchcombe, A. L. (1997). On the virtues of the old institutionalism. Annual Review of Sociology, 23, 1–18.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stuart, T. E., Hoang, H., & Hybels, R. C. (1999). Interorganizational endorsements and the performance of entrepreneurial ventures. Administrative Science Quarterly, 44, 316–349.

    Google Scholar 

  • Thompson, J. D. (1967). Organizations in action. New York: McGraw-Hill.

    Google Scholar 

  • Throsby, D. (1999). Cultural capital. Journal of Cultural Economics, 23, 3–12.

    Google Scholar 

  • Vaughan, D. (2002). Signals and interpretive work. In K. A. Cerulo (Ed.) Culture in mind (pp. 28–54). New York: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wacquant, L. J. D. (1993). From ruling class to field of power: An interview with Pierre Bourdieu on La noblesse d’Etat. Theory, Culture, and Society, 10, 19–44.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wamsley, G. L., & Zald, M. N. (1973). The political economy of public organizations. Public Administration Review, 33(1), 62–73.

    Google Scholar 

  • Warren, R. L. (1967). The interorganizational field as a focus for investigation. Administrative Science Quarterly, 12(3), 396–419.

    Google Scholar 

  • Weick, K. E. (1994). Sensemaking in organizations. London: Sage.

    Google Scholar 

  • Whetten, D. A., & Mackey, A. (2002). A social actor conception of organizational identity and its implications for the study of organizational reputation. Business and Society, 41(4), 393–414.

    Google Scholar 

  • White, H. C. (1992). Identity and control. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • White, H. C., Boorman, S., & Breiger, R. L. (1976). Social structure from multiple networks, I. American Journal of Sociology, 81, 730–780.

    Google Scholar 

  • Williamson, O. E. (1975). Markets and hierarchies: Analysis and antitrust implications. New York: Free Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Yuchtman, E., & Seashore, S. E. (1967). A system resource approach to organizational effectiveness. American Sociological Review, 32(6), 891–903.

    Google Scholar 

  • Zajac, E. J., & Westphal, J. D. (1996). Director Reputation, CEO-Board Power, and the Dynamics of Board Interlocks. Administrative Science Quarterly, 41(3), 507–529.

    Google Scholar 

  • Zald, M. N. (1970). Organizational change: The political economy of the YMCA. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Zald, M. N. (1990). History, theory, and the sociology of organizations. In J. E. Jackson (Ed.) Institutions in American Society (pp. 81–108). Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Zucker, L. G. (1983). Organizations as institutions. In S. B. Bacharach (Ed.) Research in the Sociology of Organizations (pp. 1–42). Greenwich, CT: JAI.

    Google Scholar 

  • Zucker, L. G. (1991 [1977]). The Role of Institutionalization in Cultural Persistence. In W. W. Powell & P. J. DiMaggio (Eds.) The New Institutionalism in Organizational Analysis (pp. 83–107). Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

We wish to thank the following persons for their very helpful comments: Wayne Baker, Neil Brenner, Michael Cohen, Matthew Desmond, Jane Dutton, Joseph Galaskiewicz, Michael Jensen, Shamus Khan, Jason Owen-Smith, Erik Schneiderhan, David Stark, Klaus Weber, Mayer Zald, and the participants in the ICOS Seminar at the University of Michigan.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Mustafa Emirbayer.

Additional information

Emirbayer and Johnson are equal co-authors of this article

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Emirbayer, M., Johnson, V. Bourdieu and organizational analysis. Theor Soc 37, 1–44 (2008). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11186-007-9052-y

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11186-007-9052-y

Keywords

Navigation