Skip to main content
Log in

How do people value extended warranties? Evidence from two field surveys

  • Published:
Journal of Risk and Uncertainty Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Extended warranties are popular but expensive. This paper examines how consumers value these warranties, and asks whether economic considerations alone can account for their popularity. Results from two field surveys show that consumers greatly overestimate both the likelihood and the cost of product breakdown. However, these biases alone do not explain their willingness to buy warranties. In fact, we find evidence of probability neglect, in which warranty purchase decision depends on the magnitude of the possible consequences of not having insurance and not on the probability of having to suffer these consequences. The expected emotional benefits from having a warranty was the best predictor of purchase decision and willingness to pay. We also found that people with higher cognitive skills are less likely to overestimate the economic determinants of warranty value, yet are still highly influenced by emotional considerations when deciding whether to purchase a warranty.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Insurance against small cost consumer durables is among the most profitable items sold by commercial electronics stores. In the US, 40–80% of the profit on electronics comes from the sale of these warranties (Consumer Reports 2005). It is often suggested that it is only by selling warranties that commercial electronics stores can stay in business (e.g., Berner 2004; Malester 2004).

  2. We have never seen a brochure advertising extended warranties that has not mentioned “peace of mind.” To investigate this, we conducted a Google search of all sites in the .com domain containing the terms “extended warranty” and “peace of mind” and obtained 115,000 hits—with almost all items in top pages being companies selling warranties. A corresponding search replacing “peace of mind” with “probability” yielded 12,200 hits—with almost all the top items containing anti-warranty consumer advice.

  3. Although there is no necessary relationship between fair price and personal willingness to pay, we expected fair price to be correlated with willingness to pay, and the results of both our studies support this view.

  4. The revealed distribution of subjective breakdown probability in year t+1 first order stochastically dominated that of subjective breakdown probability in year t.

  5. The median subjective actuarial value for a 3-year warranty was £21 although the objective actuarial value is approximately £7. The actual price of a 3-year warranty in Belgium, however, is about £40—eight times as high as its (objective) actuarial value.

  6. We thank the Editorial Board and an anonymous referee for pushing us to distinguish between the components of the numeracy scale. Only the two CRT items reliably predict the warranty value estimates or hypothetical purchase decisions, suggesting that a certain degree of higher-level thinking is called on to make these decisions optimally.

  7. Our finding that the average expected cost of repair, and not the expected probability of breakdown, significantly correlates with the average fair price estimate is consistent with studies elsewhere. Huber et al. (2001) found that when choosing a product, respondents were not particularly interested in precise probabilities if they were not directly supplied. Williamson et al. (2000) found that when deciding whether to buy an extended warranty and invited to ask for information, respondents mainly asked about the cost and the terms and conditions of the policies, again not about the probabilities of breakdown.

  8. Interestingly, CRT is not simply picking up the effect of schooling. When we include a dummy indicating whether the highest grade of schooling completed was (partial) higher education as an explanatory variable in all the regressions that we report in the paper, the coefficient of CRT barely changes (significance levels never change) and the schooling dummy variable is never statistically significant.

  9. Purchase intention cannot be directly inferred from fair price. To see why, imagine we asked people to state the ‘fair price’ for a wheelchair. We would expect prices in the order of £200 or more, but expect that only those who needed one would be willing to pay anything at all.

  10. In our study, of course, we could not emulate the effects of ‘hard sell’ from zealous salespeople.

  11. Domestic consumer market regulations in Belgium have traditionally worked to insulate consumers from product-related risks and thus evolved very differently from those in the UK and US (Trumbull 2006). Therefore, the implicit purchase rate of 22% may be on the high side. In Study 2, however, the implicit rate was even higher for the Belgian than London sample.

  12. This is a Belgian Public Institution for Social Security that disburses unemployment benefits. There are 34 such offices nationwide, including one in Antwerp.

  13. We split our sample into two groups based on individuals’ CRT test score and repeated the same analysis as in Table 7 for each group. The estimated OLS coefficients reveal the same insights as those reported in Table 7. We therefore conclude that CRT does not change the influence of emotional benefits on the warranty purchase decision.

  14. It is perhaps unnecessary to emphasize that Kahneman and Tversky (1979) took a more sophisticated view of matters. As they observe: “A comprehensive theory of insurance behaviour should consider, in addition to pure attitudes toward uncertainty and money, such factors as the value of security [what we would call peace of mind], social norms of prudence, the aversiveness of a large number of small payments spread over time, information and misinformation regarding probabilities and outcomes, and many others.” (p. 286)

  15. As further evidence that probability was not seen to be relevant to warranty pricing, those who gave breakdown probabilities of 0 typically gave positive values for warranty fair price and maximum willingness to pay.

  16. The standardized regression coefficient for EBI, when predicting both fair price and WTP, was greater than that for repair cost. This was true despite the fact that the repair cost was given in the same currency as the value estimate, and always appeared closer in the questionnaire, so any “common method variance” effect would favour repair cost.

  17. We recognise that while this solution is conceptually simple, it is not so easy to implement, and it places a constraint on the freedom of retailers to make their own marketing decisions. But there are precedents in which the use of what might be called local monopoly power has been curtailed by requiring monopolists to provide market access to their rivals (for an example of such procedures see O’Brien 2009). Likewise, the power of organizations such as lending institutions to set interest rates and gambling establishments to set odds are limited by legislation, to protect vulnerable consumers. Extended warranties have long been recognised as a good, like loans and slot machines, for which unprotected consumers are liable to make mistakes.

References

  • Akerlof, G. (1970). The market for lemons: quality uncertainty and the market mechanism. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 84(3), 488–500.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baron, J., Hershey, J. C., & Kunreuther, H. (2000). Determinants of priority for risk reduction: the role of worry. Risk Analysis, 20(4), 413–427.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Benjamin, D., Brown, S. A., & Shapiro, J. (2006). Does cognitive ability reduce psychological bias? mimeo, Harvard University and University of Chicago.

  • Berner, R. (2004). “The warranty windfall,” Business Week 12/20/2004.

  • Camerer, C., Issacharoff, S., Loewenstein, G., O’Donoghue, T., & Rabin, M. (2003). Regulation for conservatives: behavioral economics and the case for ‘asymmetric paternalism’. University of Pennsylvania Law Review, 151, 1211–1254.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Caplin, H., & Healy, J. (2001). Psychological expected utility theory and anticipatory feelings. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 116(1), 55–79.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cawley, J. P., Heckman, J., & Vytlacil, E. (2001). Three observations on wages and measured cognitive ability. Labour Economics, 8, 419–442.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chen, T., Kalra, A., & Sun, B. (2009). Why do consumers buy extended service contracts? Journal of Consumer Research, 36, 611–623.

    Google Scholar 

  • Competition Commission (2003). Extended warranties on domestic electrical goods: A report on the supply of extended warranties on domestic electrical goods within the UK. Inquiry Report: Competition Commission.

  • Competition Commission. (2005). The supply of extended warranties on domestic electrical goods order 2005 regulatory impact assessment. Evaluation Reports.

  • Consumer Reports. (2005). Extended warranties: say yes, sometimes. Consumer Reports, January 2005.

  • Cutler, D., & Zeckhauser, R. (2003). Extending the theory to meet the practice of insurance. mimeo, Harvard University.

  • Eisner, R., & Strotz, R. H. (1961). Flight insurance and the theory of choice. Journal of Political Economy, 69, 350–368.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fang, H., Keane, M., & Silverman, D. (2008). Sources of advantageous selection: evidence from the Medigap insurance market. Journal of Political Economy, 116(2), 303–350.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Finucane, M., Slovic, P., Hibbard, J., Peters, E., Mertz, C., & MacGregor, D. (2002). Aging and decision-making competence: an analysis of comprehension and consistency skills in older versus younger adults considering health-plan options. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making, 15, 141–164.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frederick, S. (2005). Cognitive reflection and decision making. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 19(4), 25–42.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gabaix, X., & Laibson, D. (2006). Shrouded attributes, consumer myopia, and information suppression in competitive markets. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 505–539.

  • Hogarth, R., & Kunreuther, H. (1995). Decision making under ignorance: arguing with yourself. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 10, 15–36.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hsee, C. K., & Kunreuther, H. (2000). The affection effect in insurance decision. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 20(2), 141–159.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Huber, O., Beutter, C., Montoya, J., & Huber, O. W. (2001). Riskdefusing behaviour: Towards an understanding of risky decision making. European Journal of Cognitive Psychology, 13, 409–426.

    Google Scholar 

  • Johnson, E., Hershey, J., Meszaros, J., & Kunreuther, H. (1993). Framing, probability distortions and insurance decisions. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 7, 35–51.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman, D., & Tversky, A. (1979). Prospect theory: an analysis of decision under risk. Econometrica, 47, 263–291.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kovalchik, S., Camerer, C., Grether, D., Plott, C., & Allman, J. (2005). Aging and decision making: a broad comparative study of decision behaviour in neurologically healthy elderly and young individuals. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 58, 79–94.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kunreuther, H., Novemsky, N., & Kahneman, D. (2001). Making low probabilities useful. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 23, 103–120.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lichtenstein, S., Slovic, P., Fischhoff, B., Layman, M., & Combs, B. (1978). Judged frequency of lethal events. Journal of Experimental Psychology: Human Learning and Memory, 4, 551–578.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Loewenstein, G., & Lerner, J. S. (2003). The role of affect in decision making. In R. J. Davidson, R. K. Scherer, & H. H. Goldsmith (Eds.), Handbook of affective sciences. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Loewenstein, G. F., Hsee, C. K., Weber, E. U., & Welch, N. (2001). Risk as feelings. Psychological Bulletin, 127(2), 267–286.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lusardi, A. (2008). Financial literacy: An essential tool for informed consumer choice? Working Paper, Dartmouth College.

  • Lusardi, A., & Mitchell, O. S. (2007a). Baby boomer retirement security: the role of planning, financial literacy, and housing wealth. Journal of Monetary Economics, 54, 205–224.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lusardi, A., & Mitchell, O. S. (2007b). Financial literacy and retirement preparedness: Evidence and implications for financial education. Business Economics, 35–44.

  • Malester, J. (2004). Harvey reports slightly lower sales. Business News, 3/23/2004.

  • O’Brien, K. J. (2009). Google’s strength may be part of Microsoft defense strategy. New York Times, May 7, 2009. http://www.nytimes.com/2009/05/08/technology/companies/08soft.html.

  • Peters, E., Vastfjall, D., Slovic, P., Mertz, C. K., Mazzocco, K., & Dickert, S. (2006). Numeracy and decision making. Psychological Science, 17(5), 407–413.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rabin, M., & Thaler, R. H. (2001). Risk Version. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 15, 219–232.

  • Rottenstreich, Y., & Hsee, C. K. (2001). Money, kisses, and electric shocks: on the affective psychology of risk. Psychological Science, 12, 185–190.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Slovic, P., Finucane, M. L., Peters, E., & MacGregor, D. G. (2004). Risk as analysis and risk as feelings: some thoughts about affect, reason, risk, and rationality. Risk Analysis, 24(2), 311–322.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stanovich, R. E., & West, F. (1998). Cognitive ability and variation in selection task performance. Thinking and Reasoning, 4(3), 193–230.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sunstein, C. R. (2003). Terrorism and probability neglect. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 26(2/3), 121–136.

    Google Scholar 

  • Trumbull, G. (2006). Consumer capitalism: politics, product markets, and firm strategy in France and Germany. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Vandenborre (2007). http://www.vandenborre.be/web/app/web.vdb?Call=START.

  • Warranty Week. (2005). Extended warranty income. Warranty Week, October 25, 2005, http://www.warrantyweek.com/archive/ww20051025.html.

  • Warranty Week. (2006). Extended warranty pricing. Warranty Week, October 26, 2006. http://www.warrantyweek.com/archive/ww20061024.html.

  • Williamson, J., Ranyard, R., & Cuthbert, L. (2000). Risk management in everyday insurance decisions: evidence from a process tracing study. Risk Decision and Policy, 5, 19–38.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Marieke Huysentruyt.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Huysentruyt, M., Read, D. How do people value extended warranties? Evidence from two field surveys. J Risk Uncertain 40, 197–218 (2010). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11166-010-9094-9

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11166-010-9094-9

Keywords

JEL

Navigation